fbpx
Wikipedia

Cooperation (evolution)

In evolution, cooperation is the process where groups of organisms work or act together for common or mutual benefits. It is commonly defined as any adaptation that has evolved, at least in part, to increase the reproductive success of the actor's social partners.[1] For example, territorial choruses by male lions discourage intruders and are likely to benefit all contributors.[2]

This process contrasts with intragroup competition where individuals work against each other for selfish reasons. Cooperation exists not only in humans but in other animals as well. The diversity of taxa that exhibits cooperation is quite large, ranging from zebra herds to pied babblers to African elephants. Many animal and plant species cooperate with both members of their own species and with members of other species.

In animals Edit

Cooperation in animals appears to occur mostly for direct benefit or between relatives. Spending time and resources assisting a related individual may at first seem destructive to an organism's chances of survival but is actually beneficial over the long-term. Since relatives share part of the helper's genetic make-up, enhancing each individual's chance of survival may actually increase the likelihood that the helper's genetic traits will be passed on to future generations.[3]

However, some researchers, such as ecology professor Tim Clutton-Brock, assert that cooperation is a more complex process. They state that helpers may receive more direct, and less indirect, gains from assisting others than is commonly reported. These gains include protection from predation and increased reproductive fitness. Furthermore, they insist that cooperation may not solely be an interaction between two individuals but may be part of the broader goal of unifying populations.[4]

Prominent biologists, such as Charles Darwin, E. O. Wilson, and W. D. Hamilton, have found the evolution of cooperation fascinating because natural selection favors those who achieve the greatest reproductive success while cooperative behavior often decreases the reproductive success of the actor (the individual performing the cooperative behavior). Hence, cooperation seemed to pose a challenging problem to the theory of natural selection, which rests on the assumption that individuals compete to survive and maximize their reproductive successes.[2] Additionally, some species have been found to perform cooperative behaviors that may at first sight seem detrimental to their own evolutionary fitness. For example, when a ground squirrel sounds an alarm call to warn other group members of a nearby coyote, it draws attention to itself and increases its own odds of being eaten.[5] There have been multiple hypotheses for the evolution of cooperation, all of which are rooted in Hamilton's models based on inclusive fitness. These models hypothesize that cooperation is favored by natural selection due to either direct fitness benefits (mutually beneficial cooperation) or indirect fitness benefits (altruistic cooperation).[6] As explained below, direct benefits encompass by-product benefits and enforced reciprocity, while indirect benefits (kin selection) encompass limited dispersal, kin discrimination and the greenbeard effect.

Kin selection Edit

One specific form of cooperation in animals is kin selection, which involves animals promoting the reproductive success of their kin, thereby promoting their own fitness.[4][nb 1]

Different theories explaining kin selection have been proposed, including the "pay-to-stay" and "territory inheritance" hypotheses. The "pay-to-stay" theory suggests that individuals help others rear offspring in order to return the favor of the breeders allowing them to live on their land. The "territory inheritance" theory contends that individuals help in order to have improved access to breeding areas once the breeders depart.[9]

Studies conducted on red wolves support previous researchers' contention that helpers obtain both immediate and long-term gains from cooperative breeding.[4] Researchers evaluated the consequences of red wolves' decisions to stay with their packs for extended periods of time after birth. While delayed dispersal helped other wolves' offspring, studies also found that it extended male helper wolves' life spans. This suggests that kin selection may not only benefit an individual in the long-term through increased fitness but also in the short-term through increased survival chances.[10]

Some research suggests that individuals provide more help to closer relatives. This phenomenon is known as kin discrimination.[11] In their meta-analysis, researchers compiled data on kin selection as mediated by genetic relatedness in 18 species, including the western bluebird, pied kingfisher, Australian magpie, and dwarf mongoose. They found that different species exhibited varying degrees of kin discrimination, with the largest frequencies occurring among those who have the most to gain from cooperative interactions.[11]

In plants Edit

Cooperation exists not only in animals but also in plants. In a greenhouse experiment with Ipomoea hederacea, a climbing plant, results show that kin groups have higher efficiency rates in growth than non-kin groups do. This is expected to rise out of reduced competition within the kin groups.[12]

Explanation Edit

The inclusive fitness theory provides a good overview of possible solutions to the fundamental problem of cooperation. The theory is based on the hypothesis that cooperation helps in transmitting underlying genes to future generations either through increasing the reproductive successes of the individual (direct fitness) or of other individuals who carry the same genes (indirect fitness). Direct benefits can result from simple by-product of cooperation or enforcement mechanisms, while indirect benefits can result from cooperation with genetically similar individuals.[3]

Direct fitness benefits Edit

This is also called mutually beneficial cooperation as both actor and recipient depend on direct fitness benefits, which are broken down into two different types: by-product benefit and enforcement.

By-product benefit arises as a consequence of social partners having a shared interest in cooperation. For example, in meerkats, larger group size provides a benefit to all the members of that group by increasing survival rates, foraging success and conflict wins.[13] This is because living in groups is better than living alone, and cooperation arises passively as a result of many animals doing the same thing. By-product benefit can also arise as a consequence of subordinate animals staying and helping a nest that is dominated by leaders who often suffer high mortality rates. It has been shown that cooperation would be most advantageous for the sex that is more likely to remain and breed in the natal group. This is because the subordinate will have a higher chance to become dominant in the group as time passes. Cooperation in this scenario is often seen between non-related members of the same species, such as the wasp Polistes dominula.[14]

Prisoner's Delight, another term to describe by-product benefit, is a term coined by Kenneth Binmore in 2007 after he found that benefits can result as an automatic consequence of an otherwise "self-interested" act in cooperative hunting. He illustrated this with a scenario having two hunters, each hunter having the choice of hunting (cooperate) or not hunting (free-riding). Assuming that cooperative hunting results in greater rewards than just a one-player hunt, when hunting is not rare, both hunters and non-hunters benefit because either player is likely to be with other hunters, and thus likely to reap the rewards of a successful hunt. This situation demonstrates "Prisoner's Delight" because the food of a successful hunt is shared between the two players regardless of whether or not they participated.[15]

It has been shown that free riding, or reaping the benefits without any effort, is often a problem in collective action. Examples of free riding would be if an employee in a labor union pays no dues, but still benefits from union representation. In a study published in 1995, scientists found that female lions showed individual differences in the extent to which they participated in group-territorial conflict. Some lions consistently 'cooperated' by approaching intruders, while others 'lagged' behind to avoid the risk of fighting. Although the lead female recognized the laggards, she failed to punish them, suggesting that cooperation is not maintained by reciprocity.[16]

Cooperation is maintained in situations where free-riding is a problem through enforcement, which is the mechanism where the actor is rewarded for cooperating or punished for not cooperating. This happens when cooperation is favored in aiding those who have helped the actors in the past. Punishment for noncooperation has been documented in meerkats, where dominant females will attack and evict subordinate females who become pregnant. The pregnancy is seen as a failure to cooperate because only the dominant females are allowed to bear offspring. Dominant females will attack and kill the offspring of subordinate females if they evade eviction and eviction often leads to increased stress and decreased survival.[17]

Enforcement can also be mutually beneficial, and is often called reciprocal cooperation because the act of cooperation is preferentially directed at individuals who have helped the actor in the past (directly), or helped those who have helped the actor in the past (indirectly).[18]

Indirect fitness benefits Edit

The second class of explanations for cooperation is indirect fitness benefits, or altruistic cooperation. There are three major mechanisms that generate this type of fitness benefit: limited dispersal, kin discrimination and the green-beard effect.

Hamilton originally suggested that high relatedness could arise in two ways: direct kin recognition between individuals or limited dispersal, or population viscosity, which can keep relatives together.[19] The easiest way to generate relatedness between social partners is limited dispersal, a mechanism in which genetic similarity correlates with spatial proximity. If individuals do not move far, then kin usually surrounds them. Hence, any act of altruism would be directed primarily towards kin. This mechanism has been shown in Pseudomonas aeruginosa bacteria, where cooperation is disfavored when populations are well mixed, but favored when there is high local relatedness.[20]

Kin discrimination also influences cooperation because the actor can give aid preferentially towards related partners. Since kin usually share common genes, it is thought that this nepotism can lead to genetic relatedness between the actor and the partner's offspring, which affects the cooperation an actor might give.

This mechanism is similar to what happens with the green-beard effect, but with the green-beard effect, the actor has to instead identify which of its social partners share the gene for cooperation. A green-beard system must always co-occur within individuals and alleles to produce a perceptible trait, recognition of this trait in others, and preferential treatment to those recognized. Examples of green-beard behavior have been found in hydrozoans, slime molds, yeast, and ants. An example is in side-blotch lizards, where blue-throated males preferentially establish territories next to each other. Results show that neighboring blue-throats are more successful at mate guarding. However, blue males next to larger, more aggressive orange males suffer a cost.[21] This strategy blue has evolutionary cycles of altruism alternating with mutualism tied to the RPS game.

Multi-level selection Edit

Multi-level selection theory suggests that selection operates on more than one level: for example, it may operate at an atomic and molecular level in cells, at the level of cells in the body, and then again at the whole organism level, and the community level, and the species level. Any level which is not competitive with others of the same level will be eliminated, even if the level below is highly competitive. A classic example is that of genes which prevent cancer. Cancer cells divide uncontrollably, and at the cellular level, they are very successful, because they are (in the short term) reproducing very well and out competing other cells in the body. However, at the whole organism level, cancer is often fatal, and so may prevent reproduction. Therefore, changes to the genome which prevent cancer (for example, by causing damaged cells to act co-operatively by destroying themselves) are favoured. Multi-level selection theory contends that similar effects can occur, for example, to cause individuals to co-operate to avoid behaviours which favour themselves short-term, but destroy the community (and their descendants) long term.

Market effect Edit

One theory suggesting a mechanism that could lead to the evolution of co-operation is the "market effect" as suggested by Noe and Hammerstein.[22] The mechanism relies on the fact that in many situations there exists a trade-off between efficiency obtaining a desired resource and the amount of resources one can actively obtain. In that case, each partner in a system could benefit from specializing in producing one specific resource and obtaining the other resource by trade. When only two partners exist, each can specialize in one resource, and trade for the other. Trading for the resource requires co-operation with the other partner and includes a process of bidding and bargaining.

This mechanism can be relied to both within a species or social group and within species systems. It can also be applied to a multi-partner system, in which the owner of a resource has the power to choose its co-operation partner. This model can be applied in natural systems (examples exist in the world of apes, cleaner fish, and more). Easy for exemplifying, though, are systems from international trading. Arabic countries control vast amounts of oil, but seek technologies from western countries. These in turn are in need of Arab oil. The solution is co-operation by trade.

Symbiosis Edit

Symbiosis refers to two or more biological species that interact closely, often over a long period of time. Symbiosis includes three types of interactions—mutualism, commensalism, and parasitism—of which only mutualism can sometimes qualify as cooperation. Mutualism involves a close, mutually beneficial interaction between two different biological species, whereas "cooperation" is a more general term that can involve looser interactions and can be interspecific (between species) or intraspecific (within a species). In commensalism, one of the two participating species benefits, while the other is neither harmed nor benefitted. In parasitism, one of the two participating species benefits at the expense of the other.

Symbiosis may be obligate or facultative. In obligate symbiosis, one or both species depends on the other for survival. In facultative symbiosis, the symbiotic interaction is not necessary for the survival of either species.

Two special types of symbiosis include endosymbiosis, in which one species lives inside of another, and ectosymbiosis, in which one species lives on another.

Mutualism Edit

 
Rhizobia nodules on Vigna unguiculata

Mutualism is a form of symbiosis in which both participating species benefit.

A classic example of mutualism is the interaction between rhizobia soil bacteria and legumes (Fabaceae). In this interaction, rhizobia bacteria induce root nodule formation in legume plants via an exchange of molecular signals.[23] Within the root nodules, rhizobia fix atmospheric nitrogen into ammonia using the nitrogenase enzyme. The legume benefits from a new supply of usable nitrogen from the rhizobia, and the rhizobia benefits from organic acid energy sources from the plant as well as the protection provided by the root nodule. Since the rhizobia live within the legume, this is an example of endosymbiosis, and since both the bacteria and the plant can survive independently, it is also an example of facultative symbiosis.

Lichens are another example of mutualism. Lichens consist of a fungus (the mycobiont) and a photosynthetic partner (the photobiont), which is usually a green alga or a cyanobacteria. The mycobiont benefits from the sugar products of photosynthesis generated by the photobiont, and the photobiont benefits from the increased water retention and increased surface area to capture water and mineral nutrients conferred by the mycobiont. Many lichens are examples of obligate symbiosis. In fact, one-fifth of all known extant fungal species form obligate symbiotic associations with green algae, cyanobacteria or both.[24]

Not all examples of mutualism are also examples of cooperation. Specifically, in by-product mutualism, both participants benefit, but cooperation is not involved. For example, when an elephant defecates, this is beneficial to the elephant as a way to empty waste, and it is also beneficial to a dung beetle that uses the elephant's dung. However, neither participant's behavior yields a benefit from the other, and thus cooperation is not taking place.[25]

Hidden benefits Edit

Hidden benefits are benefits from cooperation that are not obvious because they are obscure or delayed. (For example, a hidden benefit would not involve an increase in the number of offspring or offspring viability.)

One example of a hidden benefit involves Malarus cyaneus, the superb fairy-wren. In M. cyaneus, the presence of helpers at the nest does not lead to an increase in chick mass. However, the presence of helpers does confer a hidden benefit: it increases the chance that a mother will survive to breed in the next year.[15]

Another example of a hidden benefit is indirect reciprocity, in which a donor individual helps a beneficiary to increase the probability that observers will invest in the donor in the future, even when the donor will have no further interaction with the beneficiary.

In a study of 79 students, participants played a game in which they could repeatedly give money to others and receive from others. They were told that they would never interact with the same person in the reciprocal role. A player's history of donating was displayed at each anonymous interaction, and donations were significantly more frequent to receivers who had been generous to others in earlier interactions.[26] Indirect reciprocity has only been shown to occur in humans.[27]

Prisoner's dilemma Edit

 
Cooperative hunting by wolves allows them to tackle much larger and more nutritious prey than any individual wolf could handle. However, such cooperation could, potentially, be exploited by selfish individuals who do not expose themselves to the dangers of the hunt, but nevertheless share in the spoils.

Even if all members of a group benefit from cooperation, individual self-interest may not favor cooperation. The prisoner's dilemma codifies this problem and has been the subject of much research, both theoretical and experimental. In its original form the prisoner's dilemma game (PDG) described two awaiting trial prisoners, A and B, each faced with the choice of betraying the other or remaining silent. The "game" has four possible outcomes: (a) they both betray each other, and are both sentenced to two years in prison; (b) A betrays B, which sets A free and B is sentenced to four years in prison; (c) B betrays A, with the same result as (b) except that it is B who is set free and the other spends four years in jail; (d) both remain silent, resulting in a six-month sentence each. Clearly (d) ("cooperation") is the best mutual strategy, but from the point of view of the individual betrayal is unbeatable (resulting in being set free, or getting only a two-year sentence). Remaining silent results in a four-year or six-month sentence. This is exemplified by a further example of the PDG: two strangers attend a restaurant together and decide to split the bill. The mutually best ploy would be for both parties to order the cheapest items on the menu (mutual cooperation). But if one member of the party exploits the situation by ordering the most expensive items, then it is best for the other member to do likewise. In fact, if the fellow diner's personality is completely unknown, and the two diners are unlikely ever to meet again, it is always in one's own best interests to eat as expensively as possible. Situations in nature that are subject to the same dynamics (rewards and penalties) as the PDG define cooperative behavior: it is never in the individual's fitness interests to cooperate, even though mutual cooperation rewards the two contestants (together) more highly than any other strategy.[28] Cooperation cannot evolve under these circumstances.

However, in 1981 Axelrod and Hamilton[29] noted that if the same contestants in the PDG meet repeatedly (in the so-called iterated prisoner's dilemma game, IPD) then tit-for-tat (foreshadowed by Robert Trivers' 1971 reciprocal altruism theory[30]) is a robust strategy which promotes altruism.[28][29][31] In "tit-for-tat" both players' opening moves are cooperation. Thereafter each contestant repeats the other player's last move, resulting in a seemingly endless sequence of mutually cooperative moves. However, mistakes severely undermine tit-for-tat's effectiveness, giving rise to prolonged sequences of betrayal, which can only be rectified by another mistake. Since these initial discoveries, all the other possible IPD game strategies have been identified (16 possibilities in all, including, for instance, "generous tit-for-tat", which behaves like "tit-for-tat", except that it cooperates with a small probability when the opponent's last move was "betray".[32]), but all can be outperformed by at least one of the other strategies, should one of the players switch to such a strategy. The result is that none is evolutionarily stable, and any prolonged series of the iterated prisoner's dilemma game, in which alternative strategies arise at random, gives rise to a chaotic sequence of strategy changes that never ends.[28][33][34]

Results from experimental economics show, however, that humans often act more cooperatively than strict self-interest would dictate.[35]

Evolutionary mechanisms suggesting that reciprocity is the result, not the cause, of the evolution of cooperation Edit

In the light of the iterated prisoner's dilemma game and the reciprocal altruism theory failing to provide full answers to the evolutionary stability of cooperation, several alternative explanations have been proposed.

 
A male peacock with its beautiful but clumsy, aerodynamically unsound erectile tail, which Amotz Zahavi believes is a handicap, comparable to a race horse's handicap. The larger the handicap the more intrinsically fit the individual (see text).
 
The best horses in a handicap race carry the largest weights, so the size of the handicap is a measure of the animal's quality.

There are striking parallels between cooperative behavior and exaggerated sexual ornaments displayed by some animals, particularly certain birds, such as, amongst others, the peacock. Both are costly in fitness terms, and both are generally conspicuous to other members of the population or species. This led Amotz Zahavi to suggest that both might be fitness signals rendered evolutionarily stable by his handicap principle.[36][37][38] If a signal is to remain reliable, and generally resistant to falsification, the signal has to be evolutionarily costly.[39] Thus, if a (low fitness) liar were to use the highly costly signal, which seriously eroded its real fitness, it would find it difficult to maintain a semblance or normality.[40] Zahavi borrowed the term "handicap principle" from sports handicapping systems. These systems are aimed at reducing disparities in performance, thereby making the outcome of contests less predictable. In a horse handicap race, provenly faster horses are given heavier weights to carry under their saddles than inherently slower horses. Similarly, in amateur golf, better golfers have fewer strokes subtracted from their raw scores than the less talented players. The handicap therefore correlates with unhandicapped performance, making it possible, if one knows nothing about the horses, to predict which unhandicapped horse would win an open race. It would be the one handicapped with the greatest weight in the saddle. The handicaps in nature are highly visible, and therefore a peahen, for instance, would be able to deduce the health of a potential mate by comparing its handicap (the size of the peacock's tail) with those of the other males. The loss of the male's fitness caused by the handicap is offset by his increased access to females, which is as much of a fitness concern as is his health. A cooperative act is, by definition, similarly costly (e.g. helping raise the young at the nest of an unrelated pair of birds versus producing and raising one's own offspring). It would therefore also signal fitness, and is probably as attractive to females as a physical handicap. If this is the case, cooperation is evolutionarily stabilized by sexual selection.[37]

 
An African pygmy kingfisher, showing details of appearance and coloration that are shared by all African pygmy kingfishers to a high degree of fidelity.[41]

There is an alternate strategy for identifying fit mates which does not rely on one gender having exaggerated sexual ornaments or other handicaps, but is probably generally applicable to most, if not all sexual creatures. It derives from the concept that the change in appearance and functionality caused by a non-silent mutation will generally stand out in a population. This is because that altered appearance and functionality will be unusual, peculiar, and different from the norm within that population. The norm against which these unusual features are judged is made up of fit attributes that have attained their plurality through natural selection, while less well adapted attributes will be in the minority or frankly rare.[42] Since the overwhelming majority of mutant features are maladaptive, and it is impossible to predict evolution's future direction, sexual creatures would be expected to prefer mates with the fewest unusual or minority features.[42][43][44][45][46] This will have the effect of a sexual population rapidly shedding peripheral phenotypic features, thereby canalizing the entire outward appearance and behavior of all of its members. They will all very quickly begin to look remarkably similar to one another in every detail, as illustrated in the accompanying photograph of the African pygmy kingfisher, Ispidina picta. Once a population has become as homogeneous in appearance as is typical of most species, its entire repertoire of behaviors will also be rendered evolutionarily stable, including any cooperative, altruistic and social interactions. Thus, in the example above of the selfish individual who hangs back from the rest of the hunting pack, but who nevertheless joins in the spoils, that individual will be recognized as being different from the norm, and will therefore find it difficult to attract a mate (koinophilia).[45] Its genes will therefore have only a very small probability of being passed on to the next generation, thus evolutionarily stabilizing cooperation and social interactions at whatever level of complexity is the norm in that population.[34][47]

History of cooperation research Edit

One of the first references to animal cooperation was made by Charles Darwin, who noted it as a potential problem for his theory of natural selection.[48] In most of the 19th century, intellectuals like Thomas Henry Huxley and Peter Kropotkin debated fervently on whether animals cooperate with one another and whether animals displayed altruistic behaviors.[49]

In the late 1900s, some early research in animal cooperation focused on the benefits of group-living. While living in a group produces costs in the form of increased frequency of predator attacks and greater mating competition, some animals find that the benefits outweigh the costs. Animals that practice group-living often benefit from assistance in parasite removal, access to more mates, and conservation of energy in foraging.[50] Initially, the most obvious form of animal cooperation was kin selection, but more recent studies focus on non-kin cooperation, where benefits may seem less obvious. Non-kin cooperation often involves many strategies that include manipulation and coercion, making these interactions more complicated to study.[2] An example of manipulation is presented by the cuckoo, a brood parasite, which lays its eggs in the nest of a bird of another species.[15] That bird then is tricked into feeding and caring for the cuckoo offspring. Although this phenomenon may look like cooperation at first glance, it only presents benefits to one recipient.

In the past, simple game theory models, such as the classic cooperative hunting and Prisoner's dilemma models, were used to determine decisions made by animals in cooperative relationships. However, complicated interactions between animals have required the use of more complex economic models such as the Nash equilibrium. The Nash equilibrium is a type of non-cooperative game theory that assumes an individual's decision is influenced by its knowledge of the strategies of other individuals. This theory was novel because it took into consideration the higher cognitive capabilities of animals.[51][52] The evolutionarily stable strategy is a refined version of the Nash equilibrium in that it assumes strategies are heritable and are subject to natural selection. Economic models are useful for analyzing cooperative relationships because they provide predictions on how individuals act when cooperation is an option. Economic models are not perfect, but they provide a general idea of how cooperative relationships work.

Contrary to the mainstream dogma, a recently published article.[53] using agent-based models demonstrates that several crucial mechanisms, such as kin selection, punishment, multilevel selection, and spatial structure, cannot rescue the evolution of cooperation. The new findings revive a long-standing puzzle in the evolution theory. In addition, the work has potential therapeutic benefits for numerous incurable diseases.

See also Edit

Notes Edit

  1. ^ An individual's gene complement (or genome) can be represented by the letters of the alphabet. Each letter is represented twice: A1 and A2. This individual's genome therefore consists of 52 genes. The subscript indicates from which parent that copy of A has come. Mostly the two copies are identical, but occasionally they differ slightly. When this individual reproduces sexually, one or other copy of A (chosen randomly) is passed on to offspring-1, who gets its other copy of A from the sexual partner. The same happens with genes B, C, D, ..., Z. If we denote the two sexual partners by means of subscripts "m" and "f", then the genome of the offspring they produce might consist of Am2/Af1, Bm2/Bf2, Cm1/Cf1, Dm1/Df1 ... Zm1/Zf2. Each parent has contributed exactly half of the offspring's genome. So individual "m" shares only half of its genome with its offspring. Suppose individuals "m" and "f" produce a second offspring (offspring-2), whose genome is determined in exactly the same manner. There is a coin-flip 50% probability that offspring-2 will inherit the same copy of A from "m" as offspring-1 did (i.e. Am2). This also applies to gene B and so on through the alphabet. If a coin-flip "heads" means that gene X is the same in offspring-1 as it is in offspring-2, then in 26 flips of the coin approximately half are going to be "heads" and the rest "tails", i.e. half the genes inherited from parent "m" will be the same in the two offspring. The same will happen to the genes inherited from parent "f". Thus of the 52 genes inherited from the two parents, on average, 13 +  13 =  26 (or half) will be identical in the two sibs. Thus sibs are genetically as similar to one another as a parent is to an offspring.[7][8] From a evolutionary genetic point of view it is therefore as advantageous to help with the upbringing of full sibs as it is to produce and raise one's own offspring.

References Edit

  1. ^ Gardner, Andy; Griffin, Ashleigh; West, Stuart (December 2009). Theory of Cooperation. doi:10.1002/9780470015902.a0021910. ISBN 978-0470016176. {{cite book}}: |journal= ignored (help)
  2. ^ a b c Clutton-Brock, T (5 November 2009). "Cooperation between non-kin in animal societies". Nature. 462 (7269): 51–57. Bibcode:2009Natur.462...51C. doi:10.1038/nature08366. PMID 19890322. S2CID 205218102.
  3. ^ a b Hamilton, W. D. (1964). "The genetical evolution of social behaviour. I". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 7 (1): 1–16. Bibcode:1964JThBi...7....1H. doi:10.1016/0022-5193(64)90038-4. PMID 5875341.
  4. ^ a b c Clutton-Brock, T. (2002). "Breeding together: Kin selection and mutualism in cooperative vertebrates". Science. 296 (5565): 69–72. Bibcode:2002Sci...296...69C. doi:10.1126/science.296.5565.69. PMID 11935014.
  5. ^ Sherman, P (23 September 1977). "Nepotism and the evolution of alarm calls". Science. 197 (4310): 1246–1253. Bibcode:1977Sci...197.1246S. doi:10.1126/science.197.4310.1246. PMID 17781971.
  6. ^ Hamilton, W (1 July 1964). "The genetical evolution of social behaviour. II". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 7 (1): 17–52. Bibcode:1964JThBi...7...17H. doi:10.1016/0022-5193(64)90039-6. PMID 5875340.
  7. ^ Grafen, A. (1984) Natural selection, kin selection and group selection. In Krebs, J. R. & Davies, N. B. (Eds.) Behavioural Ecology. An Evolutionary Approach. (pp. 70–71). Oxford: Blackwell Scientific Publications. ISBN 0632009985
  8. ^ Maynard Smith, J. (1989). "Evolution in structured populations". Evolutionary Genetics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 173–175. ISBN 978-0198542155.
  9. ^ Balshine-Earn, S.; Neat, F.C.; Reid, H.; Taborsky, M. (1998). "Paying to stay or paying to breed? Field evidence for direct benefits of helping behavior in a cooperatively breeding fish". Behavioral Ecology. 9 (5): 432–438. doi:10.1093/beheco/9.5.432.
  10. ^ Sparkman, A. M.; Adams, J. R.; Steury, T. D.; Waits, L. P.; Murray, D. L. (2011). "Direct fitness benefits of delayed dispersal in the cooperatively breeding red wolf (Canis rufus)". Behavioral Ecology. 22 (1): 199–205. doi:10.1093/beheco/arq194.
  11. ^ a b Griffin, A. S.; West, S. A. (2003). "Kin Discrimination and the Benefit of Helping in Cooperatively Breeding Vertebrates". Science. 302 (5645): 634–636. Bibcode:2003Sci...302..634G. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.561.819. doi:10.1126/science.1089402. PMID 14576431. S2CID 8338275.
  12. ^ Biernaskie, J. M. (2011). "Evidence for competition and cooperation among climbing plants". Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences. 278 (1714): 1989–96. doi:10.1098/rspb.2010.1771. PMC 3107641. PMID 21147795.
  13. ^ Clutton-Brock, T; Brotherton, P. N.; Russell, A. F.; O'Riain, M. J.; Gaynor, D.; Kansky, R.; Griffin, A.; Manser, M.; Sharpe, L.; McIlrath, G. M.; Small, T.; Moss, A.; Monfort, S. (2001). "Cooperation, control, and concession in meerkat groups". Science. 291 (5503): 478–481. Bibcode:2001Sci...291..478C. doi:10.1126/science.291.5503.478. PMID 11161200.
  14. ^ Strassmann, J; Seppa, P.; Queller, D. C. (10 August 2000). "Absence of within-colony kin discrimination: foundresses of the social wasp, Polistes carolina, do not prefer their own larvae". Naturwissenschaften. 87 (6): 266–269. Bibcode:2000NW.....87..266S. doi:10.1007/s001140050718. PMID 10929290. S2CID 12637238.
  15. ^ a b c An Introduction to Behavioral Ecology. Davies, Nicholas B., John R. Krebs, and Stuart A. West. 2012.
  16. ^ Heinsohn, R; Packer, C. (1 September 1995). "Complex cooperative strategies in group-territorial African lions". Science. 269 (5228): 1260–1262. Bibcode:1995Sci...269.1260H. doi:10.1126/science.7652573. PMID 7652573. S2CID 35849910.
  17. ^ Norris, Scott (15 March 2006). "Murderous Meerkat Moms Contradict Caring Image, Study Finds". National Geographic News. Retrieved 20 November 2013.
  18. ^ Gardner, Andy; Ashleigh S Griffin; Stuart A West (2009). "Theory of Cooperation". Encyclopedia of Life Sciences: 1–8.
  19. ^ Kummerli, Rolf; Andy Gardner; Stuart A. West; Ashleigh S. Griffin (April 2009). "Limited Dispersal, Budding Dispersal, and Cooperation: An Experimental Study". Evolution. 63 (4): 939–949. doi:10.1111/j.1558-5646.2008.00548.x. PMID 19154373. S2CID 13882735.
  20. ^ Griffin, A; West, S. A.; Buckling, A. (28 August 2004). "Cooperation and competition in pathogenic bacteria". Nature. 430 (7003): 1024–1027. Bibcode:2004Natur.430.1024G. doi:10.1038/nature02744. hdl:1842/698. PMID 15329720. S2CID 4429250.
  21. ^ Sinervo, Barry; Alexis Chaine; Jean Clobert; Ryan Calsbeek; Lisa Hazard; Lesley Lancaster; Andrew G. McAdam; Suzanne Alonzo; Gwynne Corrigan; Michael E. Hochberg (1 May 2006). "Self-recognition, color signals, and cycles of greenbeard mutualism and altruism". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America. 103 (19): 7372–7377. Bibcode:2006PNAS..103.7372S. doi:10.1073/pnas.0510260103. PMC 1564281. PMID 16651531.
  22. ^ Noe, R.; Hammerstein, P. (1994). "Biological markets: supply and demand determine the effect of partner choice in cooperation, mutualism and mating". Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology. 35: 1–11. doi:10.1007/BF00167053. S2CID 37085820.
  23. ^ Zhang, F; Smith, D. L (2002). Interorganismal signaling in suboptimum environments: The legume-rhizobia symbiosis. pp. 125–161. doi:10.1016/S0065-2113(02)76004-5. ISBN 9780120007943. {{cite book}}: |journal= ignored (help)
  24. ^ Lutzoni, François; Pagel, Mark; Reeb, Valérie (2001). "Major fungal lineages are derived from lichen symbiotic ancestors". Nature. 411 (6840): 937–940. Bibcode:2001Natur.411..937L. doi:10.1038/35082053. PMID 11418855. S2CID 4414913.
  25. ^ Connor, R. C. (2010). "Cooperation beyond the dyad: on simple models and a complex society". Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences. 365 (1553): 2687–2697. doi:10.1098/rstb.2010.0150. PMC 2936175. PMID 20679112.
  26. ^ Wedekind, C. (2000). "Cooperation Through Image Scoring in Humans". Science. 288 (5467): 850–852. Bibcode:2000Sci...288..850W. doi:10.1126/science.288.5467.850. PMID 10797005.
  27. ^ Bergmüller, Ralph; Johnstone, Rufus A.; Russell, Andrew F.; Bshary, Redouan (2007). "Integrating cooperative breeding into theoretical concepts of cooperation" (PDF). Behavioural Processes. 76 (2): 61–72. doi:10.1016/j.beproc.2007.07.001. PMID 17703898. S2CID 15044219.
  28. ^ a b c Sigmund, K. (1993). Games of Life. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 180–206.
  29. ^ a b Axelrod, R.; Hamilton, W.D. (1981). "The evolution of cooperation". Science. 211 (4489): 1390–1396. Bibcode:1981Sci...211.1390A. doi:10.1126/science.7466396. PMID 7466396.
  30. ^ Trivers, R.L. (1971). "The evolution of reciprocal altruism". Quarterly Review of Biology. 46: 35–57. doi:10.1086/406755. S2CID 19027999.
  31. ^ Maynard Smith, J. (1989). "Evolution in structured populations". Evolutionary Genetics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 168–169, 181–183. ISBN 978-0198542155.
  32. ^ Godfray, H. C. J. (1992). "The evolution of forgiveness". Nature. 355 (6357): 206–207. Bibcode:1992Natur.355..206G. doi:10.1038/355206a0. S2CID 4335611.
  33. ^ Novak, M.; Sigmund, K. (1993). "Chaos and the evolution of cooperation". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America. 90 (11): 5091–5094. Bibcode:1993PNAS...90.5091N. doi:10.1073/pnas.90.11.5091. PMC 46660. PMID 8506355.
  34. ^ a b Koeslag, J.H. (1997). "Sex, the Prisoner's Dilemma Game, and the evolutionary inevitability of cooperation". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 189 (1): 53–61. Bibcode:1997JThBi.189...53K. doi:10.1006/jtbi.1997.0496. PMID 9398503.
  35. ^ van den Assem; van Dolder; Thaler (2012). "Split or Steal? Cooperative Behavior when the Stakes are Large". SSRN 1592456. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  36. ^ Zahavi, Amotz (1975). "Mate selection—a selection for a handicap". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 53 (1): 205–214. Bibcode:1975JThBi..53..205Z. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.586.3819. doi:10.1016/0022-5193(75)90111-3. PMID 1195756.
  37. ^ a b Zahavi, Amotz (1977). "The cost of honesty (Further remarks on the handicap principle)". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 67 (3): 603–605. Bibcode:1977JThBi..67..603Z. doi:10.1016/0022-5193(77)90061-3. PMID 904334.
  38. ^ Zahavi, Amotz (1997). The handicap principle: a missing piece of Darwin's puzzle. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-510035-8.
  39. ^ Grafen, A. (1990). "Biological signals as handicaps". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 144 (4): 517–546. Bibcode:1990JThBi.144..517G. doi:10.1016/S0022-5193(05)80088-8. PMID 2402153.
  40. ^ Johnstone, RA; Grafen, A (1993). "Dishonesty and the handicap principle". Animal Behaviour. 46 (4): 759–764. doi:10.1006/anbe.1993.1253. S2CID 53191998.
  41. ^ Hockey, P.A.R., Dean, W.R.J., Ryan, P.G. (2005) Roberts Birds of Southern Africa, p. 176, 193. Trustees of the John Voelcker Bird Book Fund, Cape Town.
  42. ^ a b Fisher R. (1930) The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection.
  43. ^ Symons, D. (1979) The Evolution of Human Sexuality. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  44. ^ Langlois, J. H.; Roggman, L. (1990). "Attractive faces are only average". Psychological Science. 1 (2): 115–121. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9280.1990.tb00079.x. S2CID 18557871.
  45. ^ a b Koeslag, J. H. (1990). "Koinophilia groups sexual creatures into species, promotes stasis, and stabilizes social behaviour". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 144 (1): 15–35. Bibcode:1990JThBi.144...15K. doi:10.1016/s0022-5193(05)80297-8. PMID 2200930.
  46. ^ Unnikrishnan, M. K.; Akhila, H. S. (2014). . Science. 344: 1410–1414. Archived from the original on 4 March 2016. Retrieved 10 March 2015.
  47. ^ Koeslag, J.H. (2003). "Evolution of cooperation: cooperation defeats defection in the cornfield model". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 224 (3): 399–410. Bibcode:2003JThBi.224..399K. doi:10.1016/s0022-5193(03)00188-7. PMID 12941597.
  48. ^ Darwin, C. The Origin of Species Ch VIII (The Modern Library, 1859/1958)
  49. ^ Dugatkin, L. A. (2002). "Animal cooperation among unrelated individuals". Naturwissenschaften. 89 (12): 533–41. Bibcode:2002NW.....89..533D. doi:10.1007/s00114-002-0379-y. PMID 12536274. S2CID 11639874.
  50. ^ Alexander, R. (1974). "The evolution of social behavior". Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics. 5: 325–83. doi:10.1146/annurev.es.05.110174.001545.
  51. ^ Noë, R., van Hooff, J., and Hammerstein, P. Economics in Nature: Social Dilemmas, Mate Choice and Biological Markets Cambridge University Press (2001)
  52. ^ Mesterton-Gibbons, M.; Adams, E.S. (2002). "The Economics of Animal Cooperation". Science. 298 (5601): 2146–7. doi:10.1126/science.1080051. PMID 12481126. S2CID 146590101.
  53. ^ Ibrahim, Ahmed (2022). "The conditional defector strategies can violate the most crucial supporting mechanisms of cooperation". Scientific Reports. 12 (1): 15157. doi:10.1038/s41598-022-18797-2. PMC 9449918. PMID 36071078.
  • Nowak, MA (2006). (PDF). Science. 314 (5805): 1560–1563. Bibcode:2006Sci...314.1560N. doi:10.1126/science.1133755. PMC 3279745. PMID 17158317. Archived from the original (PDF) on 18 May 2011.
  • Burtsev, Mikhail; Turchin, Peter (2006). "Evolution of cooperative strategies from first principles". Nature. 440 (7087): 1041–1044. Bibcode:2006Natur.440.1041B. doi:10.1038/nature04470. PMID 16625195. S2CID 4340926.
  • West, S. A.; Griffin, A. S.; Gardner, A. (2007). "Evolutionary explanations for cooperation". Current Biology. 17 (16): R661–R672. doi:10.1016/j.cub.2007.06.004. PMID 17714660. S2CID 14869430.

cooperation, evolution, evolution, cooperation, process, where, groups, organisms, work, together, common, mutual, benefits, commonly, defined, adaptation, that, evolved, least, part, increase, reproductive, success, actor, social, partners, example, territori. In evolution cooperation is the process where groups of organisms work or act together for common or mutual benefits It is commonly defined as any adaptation that has evolved at least in part to increase the reproductive success of the actor s social partners 1 For example territorial choruses by male lions discourage intruders and are likely to benefit all contributors 2 This process contrasts with intragroup competition where individuals work against each other for selfish reasons Cooperation exists not only in humans but in other animals as well The diversity of taxa that exhibits cooperation is quite large ranging from zebra herds to pied babblers to African elephants Many animal and plant species cooperate with both members of their own species and with members of other species Contents 1 In animals 1 1 Kin selection 2 In plants 3 Explanation 3 1 Direct fitness benefits 3 2 Indirect fitness benefits 4 Multi level selection 5 Market effect 6 Symbiosis 6 1 Mutualism 7 Hidden benefits 8 Prisoner s dilemma 9 Evolutionary mechanisms suggesting that reciprocity is the result not the cause of the evolution of cooperation 10 History of cooperation research 11 See also 12 Notes 13 ReferencesIn animals EditCooperation in animals appears to occur mostly for direct benefit or between relatives Spending time and resources assisting a related individual may at first seem destructive to an organism s chances of survival but is actually beneficial over the long term Since relatives share part of the helper s genetic make up enhancing each individual s chance of survival may actually increase the likelihood that the helper s genetic traits will be passed on to future generations 3 However some researchers such as ecology professor Tim Clutton Brock assert that cooperation is a more complex process They state that helpers may receive more direct and less indirect gains from assisting others than is commonly reported These gains include protection from predation and increased reproductive fitness Furthermore they insist that cooperation may not solely be an interaction between two individuals but may be part of the broader goal of unifying populations 4 Prominent biologists such as Charles Darwin E O Wilson and W D Hamilton have found the evolution of cooperation fascinating because natural selection favors those who achieve the greatest reproductive success while cooperative behavior often decreases the reproductive success of the actor the individual performing the cooperative behavior Hence cooperation seemed to pose a challenging problem to the theory of natural selection which rests on the assumption that individuals compete to survive and maximize their reproductive successes 2 Additionally some species have been found to perform cooperative behaviors that may at first sight seem detrimental to their own evolutionary fitness For example when a ground squirrel sounds an alarm call to warn other group members of a nearby coyote it draws attention to itself and increases its own odds of being eaten 5 There have been multiple hypotheses for the evolution of cooperation all of which are rooted in Hamilton s models based on inclusive fitness These models hypothesize that cooperation is favored by natural selection due to either direct fitness benefits mutually beneficial cooperation or indirect fitness benefits altruistic cooperation 6 As explained below direct benefits encompass by product benefits and enforced reciprocity while indirect benefits kin selection encompass limited dispersal kin discrimination and the greenbeard effect Kin selection Edit One specific form of cooperation in animals is kin selection which involves animals promoting the reproductive success of their kin thereby promoting their own fitness 4 nb 1 Different theories explaining kin selection have been proposed including the pay to stay and territory inheritance hypotheses The pay to stay theory suggests that individuals help others rear offspring in order to return the favor of the breeders allowing them to live on their land The territory inheritance theory contends that individuals help in order to have improved access to breeding areas once the breeders depart 9 Studies conducted on red wolves support previous researchers contention that helpers obtain both immediate and long term gains from cooperative breeding 4 Researchers evaluated the consequences of red wolves decisions to stay with their packs for extended periods of time after birth While delayed dispersal helped other wolves offspring studies also found that it extended male helper wolves life spans This suggests that kin selection may not only benefit an individual in the long term through increased fitness but also in the short term through increased survival chances 10 Some research suggests that individuals provide more help to closer relatives This phenomenon is known as kin discrimination 11 In their meta analysis researchers compiled data on kin selection as mediated by genetic relatedness in 18 species including the western bluebird pied kingfisher Australian magpie and dwarf mongoose They found that different species exhibited varying degrees of kin discrimination with the largest frequencies occurring among those who have the most to gain from cooperative interactions 11 In plants EditCooperation exists not only in animals but also in plants In a greenhouse experiment with Ipomoea hederacea a climbing plant results show that kin groups have higher efficiency rates in growth than non kin groups do This is expected to rise out of reduced competition within the kin groups 12 Explanation EditThe inclusive fitness theory provides a good overview of possible solutions to the fundamental problem of cooperation The theory is based on the hypothesis that cooperation helps in transmitting underlying genes to future generations either through increasing the reproductive successes of the individual direct fitness or of other individuals who carry the same genes indirect fitness Direct benefits can result from simple by product of cooperation or enforcement mechanisms while indirect benefits can result from cooperation with genetically similar individuals 3 Direct fitness benefits Edit This is also called mutually beneficial cooperation as both actor and recipient depend on direct fitness benefits which are broken down into two different types by product benefit and enforcement By product benefit arises as a consequence of social partners having a shared interest in cooperation For example in meerkats larger group size provides a benefit to all the members of that group by increasing survival rates foraging success and conflict wins 13 This is because living in groups is better than living alone and cooperation arises passively as a result of many animals doing the same thing By product benefit can also arise as a consequence of subordinate animals staying and helping a nest that is dominated by leaders who often suffer high mortality rates It has been shown that cooperation would be most advantageous for the sex that is more likely to remain and breed in the natal group This is because the subordinate will have a higher chance to become dominant in the group as time passes Cooperation in this scenario is often seen between non related members of the same species such as the wasp Polistes dominula 14 Prisoner s Delight another term to describe by product benefit is a term coined by Kenneth Binmore in 2007 after he found that benefits can result as an automatic consequence of an otherwise self interested act in cooperative hunting He illustrated this with a scenario having two hunters each hunter having the choice of hunting cooperate or not hunting free riding Assuming that cooperative hunting results in greater rewards than just a one player hunt when hunting is not rare both hunters and non hunters benefit because either player is likely to be with other hunters and thus likely to reap the rewards of a successful hunt This situation demonstrates Prisoner s Delight because the food of a successful hunt is shared between the two players regardless of whether or not they participated 15 It has been shown that free riding or reaping the benefits without any effort is often a problem in collective action Examples of free riding would be if an employee in a labor union pays no dues but still benefits from union representation In a study published in 1995 scientists found that female lions showed individual differences in the extent to which they participated in group territorial conflict Some lions consistently cooperated by approaching intruders while others lagged behind to avoid the risk of fighting Although the lead female recognized the laggards she failed to punish them suggesting that cooperation is not maintained by reciprocity 16 Cooperation is maintained in situations where free riding is a problem through enforcement which is the mechanism where the actor is rewarded for cooperating or punished for not cooperating This happens when cooperation is favored in aiding those who have helped the actors in the past Punishment for noncooperation has been documented in meerkats where dominant females will attack and evict subordinate females who become pregnant The pregnancy is seen as a failure to cooperate because only the dominant females are allowed to bear offspring Dominant females will attack and kill the offspring of subordinate females if they evade eviction and eviction often leads to increased stress and decreased survival 17 Enforcement can also be mutually beneficial and is often called reciprocal cooperation because the act of cooperation is preferentially directed at individuals who have helped the actor in the past directly or helped those who have helped the actor in the past indirectly 18 Indirect fitness benefits Edit The second class of explanations for cooperation is indirect fitness benefits or altruistic cooperation There are three major mechanisms that generate this type of fitness benefit limited dispersal kin discrimination and the green beard effect Hamilton originally suggested that high relatedness could arise in two ways direct kin recognition between individuals or limited dispersal or population viscosity which can keep relatives together 19 The easiest way to generate relatedness between social partners is limited dispersal a mechanism in which genetic similarity correlates with spatial proximity If individuals do not move far then kin usually surrounds them Hence any act of altruism would be directed primarily towards kin This mechanism has been shown in Pseudomonas aeruginosa bacteria where cooperation is disfavored when populations are well mixed but favored when there is high local relatedness 20 Kin discrimination also influences cooperation because the actor can give aid preferentially towards related partners Since kin usually share common genes it is thought that this nepotism can lead to genetic relatedness between the actor and the partner s offspring which affects the cooperation an actor might give This mechanism is similar to what happens with the green beard effect but with the green beard effect the actor has to instead identify which of its social partners share the gene for cooperation A green beard system must always co occur within individuals and alleles to produce a perceptible trait recognition of this trait in others and preferential treatment to those recognized Examples of green beard behavior have been found in hydrozoans slime molds yeast and ants An example is in side blotch lizards where blue throated males preferentially establish territories next to each other Results show that neighboring blue throats are more successful at mate guarding However blue males next to larger more aggressive orange males suffer a cost 21 This strategy blue has evolutionary cycles of altruism alternating with mutualism tied to the RPS game Multi level selection EditMain article Multi level selection Multi level selection theory suggests that selection operates on more than one level for example it may operate at an atomic and molecular level in cells at the level of cells in the body and then again at the whole organism level and the community level and the species level Any level which is not competitive with others of the same level will be eliminated even if the level below is highly competitive A classic example is that of genes which prevent cancer Cancer cells divide uncontrollably and at the cellular level they are very successful because they are in the short term reproducing very well and out competing other cells in the body However at the whole organism level cancer is often fatal and so may prevent reproduction Therefore changes to the genome which prevent cancer for example by causing damaged cells to act co operatively by destroying themselves are favoured Multi level selection theory contends that similar effects can occur for example to cause individuals to co operate to avoid behaviours which favour themselves short term but destroy the community and their descendants long term Market effect EditOne theory suggesting a mechanism that could lead to the evolution of co operation is the market effect as suggested by Noe and Hammerstein 22 The mechanism relies on the fact that in many situations there exists a trade off between efficiency obtaining a desired resource and the amount of resources one can actively obtain In that case each partner in a system could benefit from specializing in producing one specific resource and obtaining the other resource by trade When only two partners exist each can specialize in one resource and trade for the other Trading for the resource requires co operation with the other partner and includes a process of bidding and bargaining This mechanism can be relied to both within a species or social group and within species systems It can also be applied to a multi partner system in which the owner of a resource has the power to choose its co operation partner This model can be applied in natural systems examples exist in the world of apes cleaner fish and more Easy for exemplifying though are systems from international trading Arabic countries control vast amounts of oil but seek technologies from western countries These in turn are in need of Arab oil The solution is co operation by trade Symbiosis EditSymbiosis refers to two or more biological species that interact closely often over a long period of time Symbiosis includes three types of interactions mutualism commensalism and parasitism of which only mutualism can sometimes qualify as cooperation Mutualism involves a close mutually beneficial interaction between two different biological species whereas cooperation is a more general term that can involve looser interactions and can be interspecific between species or intraspecific within a species In commensalism one of the two participating species benefits while the other is neither harmed nor benefitted In parasitism one of the two participating species benefits at the expense of the other Symbiosis may be obligate or facultative In obligate symbiosis one or both species depends on the other for survival In facultative symbiosis the symbiotic interaction is not necessary for the survival of either species Two special types of symbiosis include endosymbiosis in which one species lives inside of another and ectosymbiosis in which one species lives on another Mutualism Edit nbsp Rhizobia nodules on Vigna unguiculataMutualism is a form of symbiosis in which both participating species benefit A classic example of mutualism is the interaction between rhizobia soil bacteria and legumes Fabaceae In this interaction rhizobia bacteria induce root nodule formation in legume plants via an exchange of molecular signals 23 Within the root nodules rhizobia fix atmospheric nitrogen into ammonia using the nitrogenase enzyme The legume benefits from a new supply of usable nitrogen from the rhizobia and the rhizobia benefits from organic acid energy sources from the plant as well as the protection provided by the root nodule Since the rhizobia live within the legume this is an example of endosymbiosis and since both the bacteria and the plant can survive independently it is also an example of facultative symbiosis Lichens are another example of mutualism Lichens consist of a fungus the mycobiont and a photosynthetic partner the photobiont which is usually a green alga or a cyanobacteria The mycobiont benefits from the sugar products of photosynthesis generated by the photobiont and the photobiont benefits from the increased water retention and increased surface area to capture water and mineral nutrients conferred by the mycobiont Many lichens are examples of obligate symbiosis In fact one fifth of all known extant fungal species form obligate symbiotic associations with green algae cyanobacteria or both 24 Not all examples of mutualism are also examples of cooperation Specifically in by product mutualism both participants benefit but cooperation is not involved For example when an elephant defecates this is beneficial to the elephant as a way to empty waste and it is also beneficial to a dung beetle that uses the elephant s dung However neither participant s behavior yields a benefit from the other and thus cooperation is not taking place 25 Hidden benefits EditHidden benefits are benefits from cooperation that are not obvious because they are obscure or delayed For example a hidden benefit would not involve an increase in the number of offspring or offspring viability One example of a hidden benefit involves Malarus cyaneus the superb fairy wren In M cyaneus the presence of helpers at the nest does not lead to an increase in chick mass However the presence of helpers does confer a hidden benefit it increases the chance that a mother will survive to breed in the next year 15 Another example of a hidden benefit is indirect reciprocity in which a donor individual helps a beneficiary to increase the probability that observers will invest in the donor in the future even when the donor will have no further interaction with the beneficiary In a study of 79 students participants played a game in which they could repeatedly give money to others and receive from others They were told that they would never interact with the same person in the reciprocal role A player s history of donating was displayed at each anonymous interaction and donations were significantly more frequent to receivers who had been generous to others in earlier interactions 26 Indirect reciprocity has only been shown to occur in humans 27 Prisoner s dilemma EditMain article Prisoner s dilemma nbsp Cooperative hunting by wolves allows them to tackle much larger and more nutritious prey than any individual wolf could handle However such cooperation could potentially be exploited by selfish individuals who do not expose themselves to the dangers of the hunt but nevertheless share in the spoils Even if all members of a group benefit from cooperation individual self interest may not favor cooperation The prisoner s dilemma codifies this problem and has been the subject of much research both theoretical and experimental In its original form the prisoner s dilemma game PDG described two awaiting trial prisoners A and B each faced with the choice of betraying the other or remaining silent The game has four possible outcomes a they both betray each other and are both sentenced to two years in prison b A betrays B which sets A free and B is sentenced to four years in prison c B betrays A with the same result as b except that it is B who is set free and the other spends four years in jail d both remain silent resulting in a six month sentence each Clearly d cooperation is the best mutual strategy but from the point of view of the individual betrayal is unbeatable resulting in being set free or getting only a two year sentence Remaining silent results in a four year or six month sentence This is exemplified by a further example of the PDG two strangers attend a restaurant together and decide to split the bill The mutually best ploy would be for both parties to order the cheapest items on the menu mutual cooperation But if one member of the party exploits the situation by ordering the most expensive items then it is best for the other member to do likewise In fact if the fellow diner s personality is completely unknown and the two diners are unlikely ever to meet again it is always in one s own best interests to eat as expensively as possible Situations in nature that are subject to the same dynamics rewards and penalties as the PDG define cooperative behavior it is never in the individual s fitness interests to cooperate even though mutual cooperation rewards the two contestants together more highly than any other strategy 28 Cooperation cannot evolve under these circumstances However in 1981 Axelrod and Hamilton 29 noted that if the same contestants in the PDG meet repeatedly in the so called iterated prisoner s dilemma game IPD then tit for tat foreshadowed by Robert Trivers 1971 reciprocal altruism theory 30 is a robust strategy which promotes altruism 28 29 31 In tit for tat both players opening moves are cooperation Thereafter each contestant repeats the other player s last move resulting in a seemingly endless sequence of mutually cooperative moves However mistakes severely undermine tit for tat s effectiveness giving rise to prolonged sequences of betrayal which can only be rectified by another mistake Since these initial discoveries all the other possible IPD game strategies have been identified 16 possibilities in all including for instance generous tit for tat which behaves like tit for tat except that it cooperates with a small probability when the opponent s last move was betray 32 but all can be outperformed by at least one of the other strategies should one of the players switch to such a strategy The result is that none is evolutionarily stable and any prolonged series of the iterated prisoner s dilemma game in which alternative strategies arise at random gives rise to a chaotic sequence of strategy changes that never ends 28 33 34 Results from experimental economics show however that humans often act more cooperatively than strict self interest would dictate 35 Evolutionary mechanisms suggesting that reciprocity is the result not the cause of the evolution of cooperation EditIn the light of the iterated prisoner s dilemma game and the reciprocal altruism theory failing to provide full answers to the evolutionary stability of cooperation several alternative explanations have been proposed nbsp A male peacock with its beautiful but clumsy aerodynamically unsound erectile tail which Amotz Zahavi believes is a handicap comparable to a race horse s handicap The larger the handicap the more intrinsically fit the individual see text nbsp The best horses in a handicap race carry the largest weights so the size of the handicap is a measure of the animal s quality There are striking parallels between cooperative behavior and exaggerated sexual ornaments displayed by some animals particularly certain birds such as amongst others the peacock Both are costly in fitness terms and both are generally conspicuous to other members of the population or species This led Amotz Zahavi to suggest that both might be fitness signals rendered evolutionarily stable by his handicap principle 36 37 38 If a signal is to remain reliable and generally resistant to falsification the signal has to be evolutionarily costly 39 Thus if a low fitness liar were to use the highly costly signal which seriously eroded its real fitness it would find it difficult to maintain a semblance or normality 40 Zahavi borrowed the term handicap principle from sports handicapping systems These systems are aimed at reducing disparities in performance thereby making the outcome of contests less predictable In a horse handicap race provenly faster horses are given heavier weights to carry under their saddles than inherently slower horses Similarly in amateur golf better golfers have fewer strokes subtracted from their raw scores than the less talented players The handicap therefore correlates with unhandicapped performance making it possible if one knows nothing about the horses to predict which unhandicapped horse would win an open race It would be the one handicapped with the greatest weight in the saddle The handicaps in nature are highly visible and therefore a peahen for instance would be able to deduce the health of a potential mate by comparing its handicap the size of the peacock s tail with those of the other males The loss of the male s fitness caused by the handicap is offset by his increased access to females which is as much of a fitness concern as is his health A cooperative act is by definition similarly costly e g helping raise the young at the nest of an unrelated pair of birds versus producing and raising one s own offspring It would therefore also signal fitness and is probably as attractive to females as a physical handicap If this is the case cooperation is evolutionarily stabilized by sexual selection 37 nbsp An African pygmy kingfisher showing details of appearance and coloration that are shared by all African pygmy kingfishers to a high degree of fidelity 41 There is an alternate strategy for identifying fit mates which does not rely on one gender having exaggerated sexual ornaments or other handicaps but is probably generally applicable to most if not all sexual creatures It derives from the concept that the change in appearance and functionality caused by a non silent mutation will generally stand out in a population This is because that altered appearance and functionality will be unusual peculiar and different from the norm within that population The norm against which these unusual features are judged is made up of fit attributes that have attained their plurality through natural selection while less well adapted attributes will be in the minority or frankly rare 42 Since the overwhelming majority of mutant features are maladaptive and it is impossible to predict evolution s future direction sexual creatures would be expected to prefer mates with the fewest unusual or minority features 42 43 44 45 46 This will have the effect of a sexual population rapidly shedding peripheral phenotypic features thereby canalizing the entire outward appearance and behavior of all of its members They will all very quickly begin to look remarkably similar to one another in every detail as illustrated in the accompanying photograph of the African pygmy kingfisher Ispidina picta Once a population has become as homogeneous in appearance as is typical of most species its entire repertoire of behaviors will also be rendered evolutionarily stable including any cooperative altruistic and social interactions Thus in the example above of the selfish individual who hangs back from the rest of the hunting pack but who nevertheless joins in the spoils that individual will be recognized as being different from the norm and will therefore find it difficult to attract a mate koinophilia 45 Its genes will therefore have only a very small probability of being passed on to the next generation thus evolutionarily stabilizing cooperation and social interactions at whatever level of complexity is the norm in that population 34 47 History of cooperation research EditOne of the first references to animal cooperation was made by Charles Darwin who noted it as a potential problem for his theory of natural selection 48 In most of the 19th century intellectuals like Thomas Henry Huxley and Peter Kropotkin debated fervently on whether animals cooperate with one another and whether animals displayed altruistic behaviors 49 In the late 1900s some early research in animal cooperation focused on the benefits of group living While living in a group produces costs in the form of increased frequency of predator attacks and greater mating competition some animals find that the benefits outweigh the costs Animals that practice group living often benefit from assistance in parasite removal access to more mates and conservation of energy in foraging 50 Initially the most obvious form of animal cooperation was kin selection but more recent studies focus on non kin cooperation where benefits may seem less obvious Non kin cooperation often involves many strategies that include manipulation and coercion making these interactions more complicated to study 2 An example of manipulation is presented by the cuckoo a brood parasite which lays its eggs in the nest of a bird of another species 15 That bird then is tricked into feeding and caring for the cuckoo offspring Although this phenomenon may look like cooperation at first glance it only presents benefits to one recipient In the past simple game theory models such as the classic cooperative hunting and Prisoner s dilemma models were used to determine decisions made by animals in cooperative relationships However complicated interactions between animals have required the use of more complex economic models such as the Nash equilibrium The Nash equilibrium is a type of non cooperative game theory that assumes an individual s decision is influenced by its knowledge of the strategies of other individuals This theory was novel because it took into consideration the higher cognitive capabilities of animals 51 52 The evolutionarily stable strategy is a refined version of the Nash equilibrium in that it assumes strategies are heritable and are subject to natural selection Economic models are useful for analyzing cooperative relationships because they provide predictions on how individuals act when cooperation is an option Economic models are not perfect but they provide a general idea of how cooperative relationships work Contrary to the mainstream dogma a recently published article 53 using agent based models demonstrates that several crucial mechanisms such as kin selection punishment multilevel selection and spatial structure cannot rescue the evolution of cooperation The new findings revive a long standing puzzle in the evolution theory In addition the work has potential therapeutic benefits for numerous incurable diseases See also EditAgreeableness Collaboration Dunbar s number Evolution of cooperation Management cybernetics Microbial Cooperation Mutual Aid A Factor of Evolution by Peter Kropotkin Noogenesis Polytely TeamworkNotes Edit An individual s gene complement or genome can be represented by the letters of the alphabet Each letter is represented twice A1 and A2 This individual s genome therefore consists of 52 genes The subscript indicates from which parent that copy of A has come Mostly the two copies are identical but occasionally they differ slightly When this individual reproduces sexually one or other copy of A chosen randomly is passed on to offspring 1 who gets its other copy of A from the sexual partner The same happens with genes B C D Z If we denote the two sexual partners by means of subscripts m and f then the genome of the offspring they produce might consist of Am2 Af1 Bm2 Bf2 Cm1 Cf1 Dm1 Df1 Zm1 Zf2 Each parent has contributed exactly half of the offspring s genome So individual m shares only half of its genome with its offspring Suppose individuals m and f produce a second offspring offspring 2 whose genome is determined in exactly the same manner There is a coin flip 50 probability that offspring 2 will inherit the same copy of A from m as offspring 1 did i e Am2 This also applies to gene B and so on through the alphabet If a coin flip heads means that gene X is the same in offspring 1 as it is in offspring 2 then in 26 flips of the coin approximately half are going to be heads and the rest tails i e half the genes inherited from parent m will be the same in the two offspring The same will happen to the genes inherited from parent f Thus of the 52 genes inherited from the two parents on average 13 13 26 or half will be identical in the two sibs Thus sibs are genetically as similar to one another as a parent is to an offspring 7 8 From a evolutionary genetic point of view it is therefore as advantageous to help with the upbringing of full sibs as it is to produce and raise one s own offspring References Edit Gardner Andy Griffin Ashleigh West Stuart December 2009 Theory of Cooperation doi 10 1002 9780470015902 a0021910 ISBN 978 0470016176 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a journal ignored help a b c Clutton Brock T 5 November 2009 Cooperation between non kin in animal societies Nature 462 7269 51 57 Bibcode 2009Natur 462 51C doi 10 1038 nature08366 PMID 19890322 S2CID 205218102 a b Hamilton W D 1964 The genetical evolution of social behaviour I Journal of Theoretical Biology 7 1 1 16 Bibcode 1964JThBi 7 1H doi 10 1016 0022 5193 64 90038 4 PMID 5875341 a b c Clutton Brock T 2002 Breeding together Kin selection and mutualism in cooperative vertebrates Science 296 5565 69 72 Bibcode 2002Sci 296 69C doi 10 1126 science 296 5565 69 PMID 11935014 Sherman P 23 September 1977 Nepotism and the evolution of alarm calls Science 197 4310 1246 1253 Bibcode 1977Sci 197 1246S doi 10 1126 science 197 4310 1246 PMID 17781971 Hamilton W 1 July 1964 The genetical evolution of social behaviour II Journal of Theoretical Biology 7 1 17 52 Bibcode 1964JThBi 7 17H doi 10 1016 0022 5193 64 90039 6 PMID 5875340 Grafen A 1984 Natural selection kin selection and group selection In Krebs J R amp Davies N B Eds Behavioural Ecology An Evolutionary Approach pp 70 71 Oxford Blackwell Scientific Publications ISBN 0632009985 Maynard Smith J 1989 Evolution in structured populations Evolutionary Genetics Oxford Oxford University Press pp 173 175 ISBN 978 0198542155 Balshine Earn S Neat F C Reid H Taborsky M 1998 Paying to stay or paying to breed Field evidence for direct benefits of helping behavior in a cooperatively breeding fish Behavioral Ecology 9 5 432 438 doi 10 1093 beheco 9 5 432 Sparkman A M Adams J R Steury T D Waits L P Murray D L 2011 Direct fitness benefits of delayed dispersal in the cooperatively breeding red wolf Canis rufus Behavioral Ecology 22 1 199 205 doi 10 1093 beheco arq194 a b Griffin A S West S A 2003 Kin Discrimination and the Benefit of Helping in Cooperatively Breeding Vertebrates Science 302 5645 634 636 Bibcode 2003Sci 302 634G CiteSeerX 10 1 1 561 819 doi 10 1126 science 1089402 PMID 14576431 S2CID 8338275 Biernaskie J M 2011 Evidence for competition and cooperation among climbing plants Proceedings of the Royal Society B Biological Sciences 278 1714 1989 96 doi 10 1098 rspb 2010 1771 PMC 3107641 PMID 21147795 Clutton Brock T Brotherton P N Russell A F O Riain M J Gaynor D Kansky R Griffin A Manser M Sharpe L McIlrath G M Small T Moss A Monfort S 2001 Cooperation control and concession in meerkat groups Science 291 5503 478 481 Bibcode 2001Sci 291 478C doi 10 1126 science 291 5503 478 PMID 11161200 Strassmann J Seppa P Queller D C 10 August 2000 Absence of within colony kin discrimination foundresses of the social wasp Polistes carolina do not prefer their own larvae Naturwissenschaften 87 6 266 269 Bibcode 2000NW 87 266S doi 10 1007 s001140050718 PMID 10929290 S2CID 12637238 a b c An Introduction to Behavioral Ecology Davies Nicholas B John R Krebs and Stuart A West 2012 Heinsohn R Packer C 1 September 1995 Complex cooperative strategies in group territorial African lions Science 269 5228 1260 1262 Bibcode 1995Sci 269 1260H doi 10 1126 science 7652573 PMID 7652573 S2CID 35849910 Norris Scott 15 March 2006 Murderous Meerkat Moms Contradict Caring Image Study Finds National Geographic News Retrieved 20 November 2013 Gardner Andy Ashleigh S Griffin Stuart A West 2009 Theory of Cooperation Encyclopedia of Life Sciences 1 8 Kummerli Rolf Andy Gardner Stuart A West Ashleigh S Griffin April 2009 Limited Dispersal Budding Dispersal and Cooperation An Experimental Study Evolution 63 4 939 949 doi 10 1111 j 1558 5646 2008 00548 x PMID 19154373 S2CID 13882735 Griffin A West S A Buckling A 28 August 2004 Cooperation and competition in pathogenic bacteria Nature 430 7003 1024 1027 Bibcode 2004Natur 430 1024G doi 10 1038 nature02744 hdl 1842 698 PMID 15329720 S2CID 4429250 Sinervo Barry Alexis Chaine Jean Clobert Ryan Calsbeek Lisa Hazard Lesley Lancaster Andrew G McAdam Suzanne Alonzo Gwynne Corrigan Michael E Hochberg 1 May 2006 Self recognition color signals and cycles of greenbeard mutualism and altruism Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 103 19 7372 7377 Bibcode 2006PNAS 103 7372S doi 10 1073 pnas 0510260103 PMC 1564281 PMID 16651531 Noe R Hammerstein P 1994 Biological markets supply and demand determine the effect of partner choice in cooperation mutualism and mating Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology 35 1 11 doi 10 1007 BF00167053 S2CID 37085820 Zhang F Smith D L 2002 Interorganismal signaling in suboptimum environments The legume rhizobia symbiosis pp 125 161 doi 10 1016 S0065 2113 02 76004 5 ISBN 9780120007943 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a journal ignored help Lutzoni Francois Pagel Mark Reeb Valerie 2001 Major fungal lineages are derived from lichen symbiotic ancestors Nature 411 6840 937 940 Bibcode 2001Natur 411 937L doi 10 1038 35082053 PMID 11418855 S2CID 4414913 Connor R C 2010 Cooperation beyond the dyad on simple models and a complex society Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B Biological Sciences 365 1553 2687 2697 doi 10 1098 rstb 2010 0150 PMC 2936175 PMID 20679112 Wedekind C 2000 Cooperation Through Image Scoring in Humans Science 288 5467 850 852 Bibcode 2000Sci 288 850W doi 10 1126 science 288 5467 850 PMID 10797005 Bergmuller Ralph Johnstone Rufus A Russell Andrew F Bshary Redouan 2007 Integrating cooperative breeding into theoretical concepts of cooperation PDF Behavioural Processes 76 2 61 72 doi 10 1016 j beproc 2007 07 001 PMID 17703898 S2CID 15044219 a b c Sigmund K 1993 Games of Life Oxford Oxford University Press pp 180 206 a b Axelrod R Hamilton W D 1981 The evolution of cooperation Science 211 4489 1390 1396 Bibcode 1981Sci 211 1390A doi 10 1126 science 7466396 PMID 7466396 Trivers R L 1971 The evolution of reciprocal altruism Quarterly Review of Biology 46 35 57 doi 10 1086 406755 S2CID 19027999 Maynard Smith J 1989 Evolution in structured populations Evolutionary Genetics Oxford Oxford University Press pp 168 169 181 183 ISBN 978 0198542155 Godfray H C J 1992 The evolution of forgiveness Nature 355 6357 206 207 Bibcode 1992Natur 355 206G doi 10 1038 355206a0 S2CID 4335611 Novak M Sigmund K 1993 Chaos and the evolution of cooperation Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 90 11 5091 5094 Bibcode 1993PNAS 90 5091N doi 10 1073 pnas 90 11 5091 PMC 46660 PMID 8506355 a b Koeslag J H 1997 Sex the Prisoner s Dilemma Game and the evolutionary inevitability of cooperation Journal of Theoretical Biology 189 1 53 61 Bibcode 1997JThBi 189 53K doi 10 1006 jtbi 1997 0496 PMID 9398503 van den Assem van Dolder Thaler 2012 Split or Steal Cooperative Behavior when the Stakes are Large SSRN 1592456 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Zahavi Amotz 1975 Mate selection a selection for a handicap Journal of Theoretical Biology 53 1 205 214 Bibcode 1975JThBi 53 205Z CiteSeerX 10 1 1 586 3819 doi 10 1016 0022 5193 75 90111 3 PMID 1195756 a b Zahavi Amotz 1977 The cost of honesty Further remarks on the handicap principle Journal of Theoretical Biology 67 3 603 605 Bibcode 1977JThBi 67 603Z doi 10 1016 0022 5193 77 90061 3 PMID 904334 Zahavi Amotz 1997 The handicap principle a missing piece of Darwin s puzzle Oxford Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 510035 8 Grafen A 1990 Biological signals as handicaps Journal of Theoretical Biology 144 4 517 546 Bibcode 1990JThBi 144 517G doi 10 1016 S0022 5193 05 80088 8 PMID 2402153 Johnstone RA Grafen A 1993 Dishonesty and the handicap principle Animal Behaviour 46 4 759 764 doi 10 1006 anbe 1993 1253 S2CID 53191998 Hockey P A R Dean W R J Ryan P G 2005 Roberts Birds of Southern Africa p 176 193 Trustees of the John Voelcker Bird Book Fund Cape Town a b Fisher R 1930 The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection Symons D 1979 The Evolution of Human Sexuality Oxford Oxford University Press Langlois J H Roggman L 1990 Attractive faces are only average Psychological Science 1 2 115 121 doi 10 1111 j 1467 9280 1990 tb00079 x S2CID 18557871 a b Koeslag J H 1990 Koinophilia groups sexual creatures into species promotes stasis and stabilizes social behaviour Journal of Theoretical Biology 144 1 15 35 Bibcode 1990JThBi 144 15K doi 10 1016 s0022 5193 05 80297 8 PMID 2200930 Unnikrishnan M K Akhila H S 2014 The phenotypic differences between carrion and hooded crows across the hybridization zone in Europe are unlikely to be due to assortative mating Comment on Poelstra J W et al 2014 The genomic landscape underlying phenotypic integrity in the face of gene flow in crows Science 344 1410 1414 Archived from the original on 4 March 2016 Retrieved 10 March 2015 Koeslag J H 2003 Evolution of cooperation cooperation defeats defection in the cornfield model Journal of Theoretical Biology 224 3 399 410 Bibcode 2003JThBi 224 399K doi 10 1016 s0022 5193 03 00188 7 PMID 12941597 Darwin C The Origin of Species Ch VIII The Modern Library 1859 1958 Dugatkin L A 2002 Animal cooperation among unrelated individuals Naturwissenschaften 89 12 533 41 Bibcode 2002NW 89 533D doi 10 1007 s00114 002 0379 y PMID 12536274 S2CID 11639874 Alexander R 1974 The evolution of social behavior Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics 5 325 83 doi 10 1146 annurev es 05 110174 001545 Noe R van Hooff J and Hammerstein P Economics in Nature Social Dilemmas Mate Choice and Biological Markets Cambridge University Press 2001 Mesterton Gibbons M Adams E S 2002 The Economics of Animal Cooperation Science 298 5601 2146 7 doi 10 1126 science 1080051 PMID 12481126 S2CID 146590101 Ibrahim Ahmed 2022 The conditional defector strategies can violate the most crucial supporting mechanisms of cooperation Scientific Reports 12 1 15157 doi 10 1038 s41598 022 18797 2 PMC 9449918 PMID 36071078 Nowak MA 2006 Five rules for the evolution of cooperation PDF Science 314 5805 1560 1563 Bibcode 2006Sci 314 1560N doi 10 1126 science 1133755 PMC 3279745 PMID 17158317 Archived from the original PDF on 18 May 2011 Burtsev Mikhail Turchin Peter 2006 Evolution of cooperative strategies from first principles Nature 440 7087 1041 1044 Bibcode 2006Natur 440 1041B doi 10 1038 nature04470 PMID 16625195 S2CID 4340926 West S A Griffin A S Gardner A 2007 Evolutionary explanations for cooperation Current Biology 17 16 R661 R672 doi 10 1016 j cub 2007 06 004 PMID 17714660 S2CID 14869430 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Cooperation evolution amp oldid 1171104624, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.