fbpx
Wikipedia

Cameralism

Cameralism (German: Kameralismus) was a German science of public administration in the 18th and early 19th centuries that aimed at strong management of a centralized economy for the benefit mainly of the state.[1] The discipline in its most narrow definition concerned the management of the state's finances. Throughout the 18th and the first half of the 19th century, cameralism was influential in Northern European states — for example, in Prussia and Sweden — and its academics and practitioners were pioneers in economic, environmental, and administrative knowledge and technology; for example, cameralist accounting, still used in public finance today.[2][3]

The growing power of centralized state control necessitated centralized systematic information on the nation. A major renovation was the collection, use and interpretation of numerical and statistical data, ranging from trade statistics, harvest reports, and death notices to population censuses. Starting in the 1760s, officials in France and Germany began increasingly to rely on quantitative data for systematic planning, especially regarding long-term economic growth. It combined the utilitarian agenda of "enlightened absolutism" with the new ideas being developed in economics. In Germany and France, the trend was especially strong in cameralism and physiocracy.[4] According to David F. Lindenfeld, it was divided into three: public finance, Oeconomie and Polizei. Here Oeconomie did not exactly mean 'economics', nor did Polizei mean 'public policy' in the modern senses.[5][clarification needed]

Cameralism as a science is closely connected with the development of bureaucracy in the early modern period because it was a method aimed at increasing the efficiency of cameralists – not only referring to the academics devoted to the science but to those employed in the Kammer, the state administration.[6] Cameralism was associated with the early modern term oeconomics, which had a broader meaning than the modern term economics as it entailed the stewardship of households, both public, private and by extension the state itself. Thus, oeconomics was a broader domain in which the investigation of nature merged seamlessly with concerns for material and moral well-being, in which the inter-dependence of urban and rural productivity was appreciated and stewarded, in which "improvement" was simultaneously directed toward increasing the yields of agriculture, manufacturing and social responsibility.[7]

This further shaped cameralism as a wide discipline aimed at creating an overview of knowledge needed by an enlightened administrator. It also illustrates that practitioners of cameralism were a heterogeneous group that not only served the interest of the state but also that of the growing cadres of academics, scientists and technological experts striving for the favour of the state in order to further their own interests as well as being oeconomic patriots.[8][9][10]

There are some similarities between cameralism as an economic theory and the French mercantilist school of Jean-Baptiste Colbert, which has sometimes caused cameralism to be viewed as a German version of mercantilism, as both emphasised import substitution and a strong state-directed economic life.[11] However, cameralism was developed with regard to the landlocked nature of many of the German states of the 18th century and attempted to substitute the whole production process, whereas mercantilism relied on access to raw materials and goods from the colonial periphery.[12] Furthermore, defining cameralism as an early modern school of economy does not accurately portray the scope of the body of knowledge included in cameralism.[13]

Academic status

During the 18th century cameralism spread through the lands of Prussia, the Holy Roman Empire and beyond. Professorial chairs in Cameralism were also created in Sweden and Denmark–Norway[3][14] Foremost among the professors in cameralism was Johann Heinrich Gottlob Justi (1717-1771), who linked Cameralism and the idea of natural law with each other. However, most cameralists were practitioners, not academics, and worked in the burgeoning bureaucracies sometimes supporting and other times shunning the science.[15] Whether Cameralism was a technology that was applied to the different branches of the state and the economy decisively shaping it or whether it was a university science has been a major debate in modern research of Cameralism. Much debate has traditionally centered on exactly which writings classify as Cameralism.[16] However, the work of Keith Tribe, who holds cameralism to be a university science disconnected from the actual activities of the administrators, sparked a counter-reaction and shifted the debate to include the practitioners of Cameralism.[17][18] The shift is evident in the work of David Lindenfeld and Andre Wakefield, which illustrates the dynamics between theory and practice among cameralists.[8][19]

Although the precise legacy and nature of Cameralism remains disputed, it has affected modern public finance, not only by shaping the formation of state administration but also by giving rise to cameralistic accounting, a particular system predominately used in the German public sector which has outlived the rest of the science. The system has been deemed suitable for bookkeeping under conditions posed by public enterprises or services, such as constructing and maintaining infrastructure, and providing healthcare or education, since these services, if paid for, constitute a form of indirect taxation rather than a transaction on an open market.[20]

Justi based much of his inspiration for cameralistic studies to contemporary accounts of the Chinese imperial bureaucracy. The growth of cameralist studies, which played an important role in Prussian civil service training, may be traced to Justi's admiration for the Imperial examinations of China.[21] Justi, like other cameralists, also lauded many Chinese public policies apart from its administrative system.[22]

Cameralism in Prussia

The first academic chairs in the cameral sciences were created at the Prussian Universities of Halle and Frankfurt an der Oder, in 1727, by Frederick William I, who perceived a need for greater administrative skill in the growing Prussian bureaucracy.[8] Cameralist teachings departed from the traditional legal and experience-based education usually given to civil servants and focused instead on a broad overview of classical philosophy, natural sciences and economic practices such as husbandry, farming, mining and accounting.[23] However, provision of a cameralist education was also directed towards the gentry as a way to instill the values of thrift and prudence among landowners, thus increasing incomes from their estates.[24] Prussian cameralism was focused on the state, enhancing its efficiency and increasing its revenue through strengthening the power of the developing bureaucracy, by means of standardisation of both the bureaucracy’s own practices as well as the economy, enabling greater extraction of wealth.[25] There is, however, considerable debate about whether cameralist policy reflected the stated goals of academic cameralism.

Cameralism in Sweden

Cameralism gained traction in Sweden after the country had lost most of its possessions in Pomerania and the Baltic region after its defeat in the Great Northern War.[26] The Swedish example shows how cameralism, as a part of the early modern concept of economy, gave rise to a wide range of activity today associated with public and social policy. Around the highly developed Swedish bureaucracy coalesced a structure of entrepreneurs, educators and scientists that strove to mobilise the resources of the country for the betterment of the population and strengthening of the state.[27] Cameralism in this sense fostered a cadre of naturalists and administrators serving as experts engaging in economic activity, that were not necessarily administrative officials, although, associated with the state and utilising the well developed administration.[12] In Sweden, this is exemplified by the botanist Carl Linnaeus and his pupils, who were prominent advocates of cameralism and strove both to cultivate foreign cash crops such as tea and the Mulberry tree, on the leaves of which the silk worm feeds, and to find domestic substitute for imports such as coffee, projects that even though they were failures entrenched the role of the scientist and the expert as a useful instrument of state interests.[12]

Notes

  1. ^ . Oxford Dictionaries. Oxford University Press. Archived from the original on January 1, 2019. An economic theory prevalent in 18th-cent. Germany, which advocated a strong public administration managing a centralized economy primarily for the benefit of the state.
  2. ^ Koerner, Lisbet (1999). Linnaeus: Nature and Nation. Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674005655.
  3. ^ a b Monsen 2002, pp. 39–72.
  4. ^ Lars Behrisch, "Statistics and Politics in the 18th Century." Historical Social Research/Historische Sozialforschung (2016) 41#2: 238-257. online
  5. ^ Lindenfeld (1997), pp. 18–19.
  6. ^ Wakefield 2005, pp. 310–312, 318–319.
  7. ^ Roberts 2014, p. 134.
  8. ^ a b c Wakefield 2005, pp. 311–320.
  9. ^ Roberts 2014, p. 138.
  10. ^ Jonsson 2010, pp. 1342–1363.
  11. ^ Lindenfeld (1997), pp. 12–13.
  12. ^ a b c Koerner 1994, pp. 144–169.
  13. ^ Tribe 1995, pp. 10–11.
  14. ^ Lindenfeld 1997, pp. 22–25.
  15. ^ Wakefield 2005.
  16. ^ Wakefield 2005, pp. 313–316.
  17. ^ Tribe 1995, pp. 9–31.
  18. ^ Wakefield 2005, pp. 316–317.
  19. ^ Lindenfeld 1997.
  20. ^ Monsen 2002, pp. 47–49.
  21. ^ Johanna M. Menzel (1956). "The Sinophilism of J. H. G. Justi". Journal of the History of Ideas. 17 (3): 300–310. doi:10.2307/2707546. JSTOR 2707546.
  22. ^ Walter W. Davis (1983). "China, the Confucian Ideal, and the European Age of Enlightenment". Journal of the History of Ideas. 44 (4): 523–548. doi:10.2307/2709213. JSTOR 2709213.
  23. ^ Lindenfeld (1997), pp. 15–20, 22–23, 25.
  24. ^ Lindenfeld (1997), pp. 16–17.
  25. ^ Wakefield 2005, p. 318.
  26. ^ Koerner 1994, pp. 147–148.
  27. ^ Jonsson 2010, pp. 1346–1347.

References

  • Jonsson, Fredrik Albritton (2010-12-01). "Rival Ecologies of Global Commerce: Adam Smith and the Natural Historians". The American Historical Review. 115 (5): 1342–1363. doi:10.1086/ahr.115.5.1342. ISSN 0002-8762. PMID 21246886.
  • Koerner, Lisbet (1994-07-01). . Representations. 47 (47): 144–169. doi:10.2307/2928789. ISSN 0734-6018. JSTOR 2928789. Archived from the original on 2018-06-23. Retrieved 2016-11-02.
  • Lindenfeld, David (1997). The Practical Imagination: German Science of State in the 19th Century. Chicago University Press. ISBN 978-0-226-48241-5.
  • Monsen, Norvald (2002-02-01). "The Case for Cameral Accounting". Financial Accountability & Management. 18 (1): 39–72. doi:10.1111/1468-0408.00145. ISSN 1468-0408. S2CID 155034877.
  • Roberts, Lissa (2014-07-03). "Practicing economy during the second half of the long eighteenth century: an introduction". History and Technology. 30 (3): 133–148. doi:10.1080/07341512.2014.988423. ISSN 0734-1512. S2CID 143357129.
  • Tribe, Keith (1995). Strategies of Economic Order. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521462914.
  • Wakefield, Andre (2005-05-01). "Books, Bureaus, and the Historiography of Cameralism". European Journal of Law and Economics. 19 (3): 311–320. doi:10.1007/s10657-005-6640-z. ISSN 0929-1261. S2CID 144013696.

Further reading

  • Albion Small (1909), The Cameralists. The Pioneers of German Social Policy, Chicago: The University of Chicago
  • Andre Wakefield (2009), The Disordered Police State: German Cameralism as Science and Practice
  • J. Christiaens & J. Rommel, 2006. "Governmental Accounting Reforms: Going Back Where We Belong?," Working Papers of Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Ghent University, Belgium 06/398, Ghent University, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration.

External links

  •   The dictionary definition of cameralism at Wiktionary

cameralism, this, article, lead, section, long, length, article, please, help, moving, some, material, from, into, body, article, please, read, layout, guide, lead, section, guidelines, ensure, section, will, still, inclusive, essential, details, please, discu. This article s lead section may be too long for the length of the article Please help by moving some material from it into the body of the article Please read the layout guide and lead section guidelines to ensure the section will still be inclusive of all essential details Please discuss this issue on the article s talk page October 2022 For single chamber legislatures see Unicameralism For two chamber legislatures see Bicameralism For three chamber legislatures see Tricameralism Not to be confused with Neocameralism Cameralism German Kameralismus was a German science of public administration in the 18th and early 19th centuries that aimed at strong management of a centralized economy for the benefit mainly of the state 1 The discipline in its most narrow definition concerned the management of the state s finances Throughout the 18th and the first half of the 19th century cameralism was influential in Northern European states for example in Prussia and Sweden and its academics and practitioners were pioneers in economic environmental and administrative knowledge and technology for example cameralist accounting still used in public finance today 2 3 The growing power of centralized state control necessitated centralized systematic information on the nation A major renovation was the collection use and interpretation of numerical and statistical data ranging from trade statistics harvest reports and death notices to population censuses Starting in the 1760s officials in France and Germany began increasingly to rely on quantitative data for systematic planning especially regarding long term economic growth It combined the utilitarian agenda of enlightened absolutism with the new ideas being developed in economics In Germany and France the trend was especially strong in cameralism and physiocracy 4 According to David F Lindenfeld it was divided into three public finance Oeconomie and Polizei Here Oeconomie did not exactly mean economics nor did Polizei mean public policy in the modern senses 5 clarification needed Cameralism as a science is closely connected with the development of bureaucracy in the early modern period because it was a method aimed at increasing the efficiency of cameralists not only referring to the academics devoted to the science but to those employed in the Kammer the state administration 6 Cameralism was associated with the early modern term oeconomics which had a broader meaning than the modern term economics as it entailed the stewardship of households both public private and by extension the state itself Thus oeconomics was a broader domain in which the investigation of nature merged seamlessly with concerns for material and moral well being in which the inter dependence of urban and rural productivity was appreciated and stewarded in which improvement was simultaneously directed toward increasing the yields of agriculture manufacturing and social responsibility 7 This further shaped cameralism as a wide discipline aimed at creating an overview of knowledge needed by an enlightened administrator It also illustrates that practitioners of cameralism were a heterogeneous group that not only served the interest of the state but also that of the growing cadres of academics scientists and technological experts striving for the favour of the state in order to further their own interests as well as being oeconomic patriots 8 9 10 There are some similarities between cameralism as an economic theory and the French mercantilist school of Jean Baptiste Colbert which has sometimes caused cameralism to be viewed as a German version of mercantilism as both emphasised import substitution and a strong state directed economic life 11 However cameralism was developed with regard to the landlocked nature of many of the German states of the 18th century and attempted to substitute the whole production process whereas mercantilism relied on access to raw materials and goods from the colonial periphery 12 Furthermore defining cameralism as an early modern school of economy does not accurately portray the scope of the body of knowledge included in cameralism 13 Contents 1 Academic status 2 Cameralism in Prussia 3 Cameralism in Sweden 4 Notes 5 References 6 Further reading 7 External linksAcademic status EditDuring the 18th century cameralism spread through the lands of Prussia the Holy Roman Empire and beyond Professorial chairs in Cameralism were also created in Sweden and Denmark Norway 3 14 Foremost among the professors in cameralism was Johann Heinrich Gottlob Justi 1717 1771 who linked Cameralism and the idea of natural law with each other However most cameralists were practitioners not academics and worked in the burgeoning bureaucracies sometimes supporting and other times shunning the science 15 Whether Cameralism was a technology that was applied to the different branches of the state and the economy decisively shaping it or whether it was a university science has been a major debate in modern research of Cameralism Much debate has traditionally centered on exactly which writings classify as Cameralism 16 However the work of Keith Tribe who holds cameralism to be a university science disconnected from the actual activities of the administrators sparked a counter reaction and shifted the debate to include the practitioners of Cameralism 17 18 The shift is evident in the work of David Lindenfeld and Andre Wakefield which illustrates the dynamics between theory and practice among cameralists 8 19 Although the precise legacy and nature of Cameralism remains disputed it has affected modern public finance not only by shaping the formation of state administration but also by giving rise to cameralistic accounting a particular system predominately used in the German public sector which has outlived the rest of the science The system has been deemed suitable for bookkeeping under conditions posed by public enterprises or services such as constructing and maintaining infrastructure and providing healthcare or education since these services if paid for constitute a form of indirect taxation rather than a transaction on an open market 20 Justi based much of his inspiration for cameralistic studies to contemporary accounts of the Chinese imperial bureaucracy The growth of cameralist studies which played an important role in Prussian civil service training may be traced to Justi s admiration for the Imperial examinations of China 21 Justi like other cameralists also lauded many Chinese public policies apart from its administrative system 22 Cameralism in Prussia EditThe first academic chairs in the cameral sciences were created at the Prussian Universities of Halle and Frankfurt an der Oder in 1727 by Frederick William I who perceived a need for greater administrative skill in the growing Prussian bureaucracy 8 Cameralist teachings departed from the traditional legal and experience based education usually given to civil servants and focused instead on a broad overview of classical philosophy natural sciences and economic practices such as husbandry farming mining and accounting 23 However provision of a cameralist education was also directed towards the gentry as a way to instill the values of thrift and prudence among landowners thus increasing incomes from their estates 24 Prussian cameralism was focused on the state enhancing its efficiency and increasing its revenue through strengthening the power of the developing bureaucracy by means of standardisation of both the bureaucracy s own practices as well as the economy enabling greater extraction of wealth 25 There is however considerable debate about whether cameralist policy reflected the stated goals of academic cameralism Cameralism in Sweden EditCameralism gained traction in Sweden after the country had lost most of its possessions in Pomerania and the Baltic region after its defeat in the Great Northern War 26 The Swedish example shows how cameralism as a part of the early modern concept of economy gave rise to a wide range of activity today associated with public and social policy Around the highly developed Swedish bureaucracy coalesced a structure of entrepreneurs educators and scientists that strove to mobilise the resources of the country for the betterment of the population and strengthening of the state 27 Cameralism in this sense fostered a cadre of naturalists and administrators serving as experts engaging in economic activity that were not necessarily administrative officials although associated with the state and utilising the well developed administration 12 In Sweden this is exemplified by the botanist Carl Linnaeus and his pupils who were prominent advocates of cameralism and strove both to cultivate foreign cash crops such as tea and the Mulberry tree on the leaves of which the silk worm feeds and to find domestic substitute for imports such as coffee projects that even though they were failures entrenched the role of the scientist and the expert as a useful instrument of state interests 12 Notes Edit Definition of cameralism in English Oxford Dictionaries Oxford University Press Archived from the original on January 1 2019 An economic theory prevalent in 18th cent Germany which advocated a strong public administration managing a centralized economy primarily for the benefit of the state Koerner Lisbet 1999 Linnaeus Nature and Nation Harvard University Press ISBN 9780674005655 a b Monsen 2002 pp 39 72 Lars Behrisch Statistics and Politics in the 18th Century Historical Social Research Historische Sozialforschung 2016 41 2 238 257 online Lindenfeld 1997 pp 18 19 Wakefield 2005 pp 310 312 318 319 Roberts 2014 p 134 a b c Wakefield 2005 pp 311 320 Roberts 2014 p 138 Jonsson 2010 pp 1342 1363 Lindenfeld 1997 pp 12 13 a b c Koerner 1994 pp 144 169 Tribe 1995 pp 10 11 Lindenfeld 1997 pp 22 25 Wakefield 2005 Wakefield 2005 pp 313 316 Tribe 1995 pp 9 31 Wakefield 2005 pp 316 317 Lindenfeld 1997 Monsen 2002 pp 47 49 Johanna M Menzel 1956 The Sinophilism of J H G Justi Journal of the History of Ideas 17 3 300 310 doi 10 2307 2707546 JSTOR 2707546 Walter W Davis 1983 China the Confucian Ideal and the European Age of Enlightenment Journal of the History of Ideas 44 4 523 548 doi 10 2307 2709213 JSTOR 2709213 Lindenfeld 1997 pp 15 20 22 23 25 Lindenfeld 1997 pp 16 17 Wakefield 2005 p 318 Koerner 1994 pp 147 148 Jonsson 2010 pp 1346 1347 References EditJonsson Fredrik Albritton 2010 12 01 Rival Ecologies of Global Commerce Adam Smith and the Natural Historians The American Historical Review 115 5 1342 1363 doi 10 1086 ahr 115 5 1342 ISSN 0002 8762 PMID 21246886 Koerner Lisbet 1994 07 01 Linnaeus Floral Transplants Representations 47 47 144 169 doi 10 2307 2928789 ISSN 0734 6018 JSTOR 2928789 Archived from the original on 2018 06 23 Retrieved 2016 11 02 Lindenfeld David 1997 The Practical Imagination German Science of State in the 19th Century Chicago University Press ISBN 978 0 226 48241 5 Monsen Norvald 2002 02 01 The Case for Cameral Accounting Financial Accountability amp Management 18 1 39 72 doi 10 1111 1468 0408 00145 ISSN 1468 0408 S2CID 155034877 Roberts Lissa 2014 07 03 Practicing economy during the second half of the long eighteenth century an introduction History and Technology 30 3 133 148 doi 10 1080 07341512 2014 988423 ISSN 0734 1512 S2CID 143357129 Tribe Keith 1995 Strategies of Economic Order Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0521462914 Wakefield Andre 2005 05 01 Books Bureaus and the Historiography of Cameralism European Journal of Law and Economics 19 3 311 320 doi 10 1007 s10657 005 6640 z ISSN 0929 1261 S2CID 144013696 Further reading EditAlbion Small 1909 The Cameralists The Pioneers of German Social Policy Chicago The University of Chicago Andre Wakefield 2009 The Disordered Police State German Cameralism as Science and Practice J Christiaens amp J Rommel 2006 Governmental Accounting Reforms Going Back Where We Belong Working Papers of Faculty of Economics and Business Administration Ghent University Belgium 06 398 Ghent University Faculty of Economics and Business Administration External links Edit The dictionary definition of cameralism at Wiktionary Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Cameralism amp oldid 1136444470, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.