fbpx
Wikipedia

Protectionism

Protectionism, sometimes referred to as trade protectionism, is the economic policy of restricting imports from other countries through methods such as tariffs on imported goods, import quotas, and a variety of other government regulations. Proponents argue that protectionist policies shield the producers, businesses, and workers of the import-competing sector in the country from foreign competitors. Opponents argue that protectionist policies reduce trade and adversely affect consumers in general (by raising the cost of imported goods) as well as the producers and workers in export sectors, both in the country implementing protectionist policies and in the countries protected against.[citation needed]

Political poster by the British Liberal Party presenting their view of the differences between an economy based on free trade versus one based on protectionism. The free trade shop is shown as full with customers due to its low prices. The shop based on protectionism shows higher prices and a lack of customers, and with animosity between the business owner and the regulator.
Anti-free trade postcard from 1910

Protectionism is advocated mainly by parties that hold economic nationalist or left-wing positions, while economically right-wing political parties generally support free trade.[1][2][3][4][5]

There is a consensus among economists that protectionism has a negative effect on economic growth and economic welfare,[6][7][8][9] while free trade and the reduction of trade barriers have a significantly positive effect on economic growth.[7][10][11][12][13][14] Some scholars, such as Douglas Irwin, have implicated protectionism as the cause of some economic crises, most notably the Great Depression.[15] Although trade liberalization can sometimes result in large and unequally distributed losses and gains, and can, in the short run, cause significant economic dislocation of workers in import-competing sectors,[16] free trade has advantages of lowering costs of goods and services for both producers and consumers.[17]

Protectionist policies

 
Logo of Belgium's National League for the Franc's Defense, 1924

A variety of policies have been used to achieve protectionist goals. These include:

  • Tariffs and import quotas are the most common types of protectionist policies.[18] A tariff is an excise tax levied on imported goods. Originally imposed to raise government revenue, modern tariffs are now used primarily to protect domestic producers and wage rates from lower-priced importers. An import quota is a limit on the volume of a good that may be legally imported, usually established through an import licensing regime.[18]
  • Protection of technologies, patents, technical and scientific knowledge [19][20][21]
  • Restrictions on foreign direct investment,[22] such as restrictions on the acquisition of domestic firms by foreign investors.[23]
  • Administrative barriers: Countries are sometimes accused of using their various administrative rules (e.g. regarding food safety, environmental standards, electrical safety, etc.) as a way to introduce barriers to imports.
  • Anti-dumping legislation: "Dumping" is the practice of firms selling to export markets at lower prices than are charged in domestic markets. Supporters of anti-dumping laws argue that they prevent the import of cheaper foreign goods that would cause local firms to close down. However, in practice, anti-dumping laws are usually used to impose trade tariffs on foreign exporters.
  • Direct subsidies: Government subsidies (in the form of lump-sum payments or cheap loans) are sometimes given to local firms that cannot compete well against imports. These subsidies are purported to "protect" local jobs and to help local firms adjust to the world markets.
  • Export subsidies: Export subsidies are often used by governments to increase exports. Export subsidies have the opposite effect of export tariffs because exporters get payment, which is a percentage or proportion of the value of exported. Export subsidies increase the amount of trade, and in a country with floating exchange rates, have effects similar to import subsidies.
  • Exchange rate control: A government may intervene in the foreign exchange market to lower the value of its currency by selling its currency in the foreign exchange market. Doing so will raise the cost of imports and lower the cost of exports, leading to an improvement in its trade balance. However, such a policy is only effective in the short run, as it will lead to higher inflation in the country in the long run, which will, in turn, raise the real cost of exports, and reduce the relative price of imports.
  • International patent systems: There is an argument for viewing national patent systems as a cloak for protectionist trade policies at a national level. Two strands of this argument exist: one when patents held by one country form part of a system of exploitable relative advantage in trade negotiations against another, and a second where adhering to a worldwide system of patents confers "good citizenship" status despite 'de facto protectionism'. Peter Drahos explains that "States realized that patent systems could be used to cloak protectionist strategies. There were also reputational advantages for states to be seen to be sticking to intellectual property systems. One could attend the various revisions of the Paris and Berne conventions, participate in the cosmopolitan moral dialogue about the need to protect the fruits of authorial labor and inventive genius...knowing all the while that one's domestic intellectual property system was a handy protectionist weapon."[24]
  • Political campaigns advocating domestic consumption (e.g. the "Buy American" campaign in the United States, which could be seen as an extra-legal promotion of protectionism.)
  • Preferential governmental spending, such as the Buy American Act, federal legislation which called upon the United States government to prefer US-made products in its purchases.

In the modern trade arena, many other initiatives besides tariffs have been called protectionist. For example, some commentators, such as Jagdish Bhagwati, see developed countries' efforts in imposing their own labor or environmental standards as protectionism. Also, the imposition of restrictive certification procedures on imports is seen in this light.

Further, others point out that free trade agreements often have protectionist provisions such as intellectual property, copyright, and patent restrictions that benefit large corporations. These provisions restrict trade in music, movies, pharmaceuticals, software, and other manufactured items to high-cost producers with quotas from low-cost producers set to zero.[25]

History

 
Tariff Rates in Japan (1870–1960)
 
Tariff Rates in Spain and Italy (1860–1910)

Historically, protectionism was associated with economic theories such as mercantilism (which focused on achieving positive trade balance and accumulating gold), and import substitution.[citation needed]

In the 18th century, Adam Smith famously warned against the "interested sophistry" of industry, seeking to gain an advantage at the cost of the consumers.[26] Friedrich List saw Adam Smith's views on free trade as disingenuous, believing that Smith advocated for free trade so that British industry could lock out underdeveloped foreign competition.[27]

Some have argued that no major country has ever successfully industrialized without some form of economic protection.[28][29] Economic historian Paul Bairoch wrote that "historically, free trade is the exception and protectionism the rule".[30]

According to economic historians Douglas Irwin and Kevin O'Rourke, "shocks that emanate from brief financial crises tend to be transitory and have a little long-run effect on trade policy, whereas those that play out over longer periods (the early 1890s, early 1930s) may give rise to protectionism that is difficult to reverse. Regional wars also produce transitory shocks that have little impact on long-run trade policy, while global wars give rise to extensive government trade restrictions that can be difficult to reverse."[31]

One paper notes that sudden shifts in comparative advantage for specific countries have led some countries to become protectionist: "The shift in comparative advantage associated with the opening up of New World frontiers, and the subsequent “grain invasion” of Europe, led to higher agricultural tariffs from the late 1870s onwards, which as we have seen reversed the move toward freer trade that had characterized mid-nineteenth-century Europe. In the decades after World War II, Japan's rapid rise led to trade friction with other countries. Japan's recovery was accompanied by a sharp increase in its exports of certain product categories: cotton textiles in the 1950s, steel in the 1960s, automobiles in the 1970s, and electronics in the 1980s. In each case, the rapid expansion in Japan's exports created difficulties for its trading partners and the use of protectionism as a shock absorber."[31]

In the United States

 
Tariff rates (France, UK, and US)
 
Average tariff rates in US (1821–2016)
 
US trade balance (1895–2015)

According to economic historian Douglas Irwin, a common myth about US trade policy is that low tariffs harmed American manufacturers in the early 19th century and then that high tariffs made the United States into a great industrial power in the late 19th century.[32] A review by The Economist of Irwin's 2017 book Clashing over Commerce: A History of US Trade Policy states:[32]

Political dynamics would lead people to see a link between tariffs and the economic cycle that was not there. A boom would generate enough revenue for tariffs to fall, and when the bust came pressure would build to raise them again. By the time that happened, the economy would be recovering, giving the impression that tariff cuts caused the crash and the reverse generated the recovery. 'Mr. Irwin' also attempts to debunk the idea that protectionism made America a great industrial power, a notion believed by some to offer lessons for developing countries today. As its share of global manufacturing powered from 23% in 1870 to 36% in 1913, the admittedly high tariffs of the time came with a cost, estimated at around 0.5% of GDP in the mid-1870s. In some industries, they might have sped up development by a few years. But American growth during its protectionist period was more to do with its abundant resources and openness to people and ideas.

According to Irwin, tariffs have serve three primary purposes in the United States: "to raise revenue for the government, to restrict imports and protect domestic producers from foreign competition, and to reach reciprocity agreements that reduce trade barriers."[33] From 1790 to 1860, average tariffs increased from 20 percent to 60 percent before declining again to 20 percent.[33] From 1861 to 1933, which Irwin characterizes as the "restriction period", the average tariffs increased to 50 percent and remained at that level for several decades. From 1934 onwards, which Irwin characterizes as the "reciprocity period", the average tariff declined substantially until it leveled off at 5 percent.[33]

Economist Paul Bairoch documented that the United States imposed among the highest rates in the world from around the founding of the country until the World War II period, describing the United States as "the mother country and bastion of modern protectionism" since the end of the 18th century and until the post-World War II period.[34] Alexander Hamilton, the first United States Secretary of the Treasury, was of the view, as articulated most famously in his "Report on Manufactures", that developing an industrialized economy was impossible without protectionism because import duties are necessary to shelter domestic "infant industries" until they could achieve economies of scale.[35] The industrial takeoff of the United States occurred under protectionist policies 1816–1848 and under moderate protectionism 1846–1861, and continued under strict protectionist policies 1861–1945.[36] In the late 19th century, higher tariffs were introduced on the grounds that they were needed to protect American wages and to protect American farmers.[37] Between 1824 and the 1940s, the U.S. imposed much higher average tariff rates on manufactured products than did Britain or any other European country, with the exception for a period of time of Spain and Russia.[38] Up until the end of World War II, the United States had the most protectionist economy on Earth.[39]

The Bush administration implemented tariffs on Chinese steel in 2002; according to a 2005 review of existing research on the tariff, all studies found that the tariffs caused more harm than gains to the US economy and employment.[40] The Obama administration implemented tariffs on Chinese tires between 2009 and 2012 as an anti-dumping measure; a 2016 study found that these tariffs had no impact on employment and wages in the US tire industry.[41]

In 2018, EU Trade Commissioner Cecilia Malmström stated that the US was "playing a dangerous game" in applying tariffs on steel and aluminum imports from most countries, and stated that she saw the Trump administration's decision to do so as both "pure protectionist" and "illegal".[42]

The tariffs imposed by the Trump administration during the China-United States trade war led to a minor reduction in the United States trade deficit with China.[43]

In Europe

Europe became increasingly protectionist during the eighteenth century.[44] Economic historians Findlay and O'Rourke write that in "the immediate aftermath of the Napoleonic Wars, European trade policies were almost universally protectionist," with the exceptions being smaller countries such as the Netherlands and Denmark.[44]

Europe increasingly liberalized its trade during the 19th century.[45] Countries such as Britain, the Netherlands, Denmark, Portugal and Switzerland, and arguably Sweden and Belgium, had fully moved towards free trade prior to 1860.[45] Economic historians see the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846 as the decisive shift toward free trade in Britain.[45][46] A 1990 study by the Harvard economic historian Jeffrey Williamson showed that the Corn Laws (which imposed restrictions and tariffs on imported grain) substantially increased the cost of living for British workers, and hampered the British manufacturing sector by reducing the disposable incomes that British workers could have spent on manufactured goods.[47] The shift towards liberalization in Britain occurred in part due to "the influence of economists like David Ricardo", but also due to "the growing power of urban interests".[45]

Findlay and O'Rourke characterize 1860 Cobden Chevalier treaty between France and the United Kingdom as "a decisive shift toward European free trade."[45] This treaty was followed by numerous free trade agreements: "France and Belgium signed a treaty in 1861; a Franco-Prussian treaty was signed in 1862; Italy entered the “network of Cobden-Chevalier treaties” in 1863 (Bairoch 1989, 40); Switzerland in 1864; Sweden, Norway, Spain, the Netherlands, and the Hanseatic towns in 1865; and Austria in 1866. By 1877, less than two decades after the Cobden Chevalier treaty and three decades after British Repeal, Germany “had virtually become a free trade country” (Bairoch, 41). Average duties on manufactured products had declined to 9–12% on the Continent, a far cry from the 50% British tariffs, and numerous prohibitions elsewhere, of the immediate post-Waterloo era (Bairoch, table 3, p. 6, and table 5, p. 42)."[45]

Some European powers did not liberalize during the 19th century, such as the Russian Empire and Austro-Hungarian Empire which remained highly protectionist. The Ottoman Empire also became increasingly protectionist.[48] In the Ottoman Empire's case, however, it previously had liberal free trade policies during the 18th to early 19th centuries, which British prime minister Benjamin Disraeli cited as "an instance of the injury done by unrestrained competition" in the 1846 Corn Laws debate, arguing that it destroyed what had been "some of the finest manufacturers of the world" in 1812.[34]

The countries of Western Europe began to steadily liberalize their economies after World War II and the protectionism of the interwar period.[44]

In Canada

Since 1971 Canada has protected producers of eggs, milk, cheese, chicken, and turkey with a system of supply management. Though prices for these foods in Canada exceed global prices, the farmers and processors have had the security of a stable market to finance their operations.[citation needed] Doubts about the safety of bovine growth hormone, sometimes used to boost dairy production, led to hearings before the Senate of Canada, resulting in a ban in Canada. Thus supply management of milk products is consumer protection of Canadians.[49]

In Quebec, the Federation of Quebec Maple Syrup Producers manages the supply of maple syrup.[citation needed]

In Latin America

Most Latin American Countries became independent in the early 19th century. They revolted against their colonizers (primarily Spain, France, and Portugal) and set off on their own. Following the achievement of their independence, most of the Latin American countries adopted protectionism. They both feared that any foreign competition would stomp out their newly created state and figured that lack of outside resources would drive domestic production.[50]

Another reason for protectionism was that Latin America was frequently attacked by outsiders. Spain, the United States of America, France, and Texas had all invaded or attempted to invade Latin America by the year 1880. It could be said that Latin America was essentially hiding in its shell trying just to survive in the 19th century.

Yet the protectionist behavior continued up until and during the World Wars. No Latin American countries got seriously involved with either side. Rather, they just kept harvesting their crops (mostly fruits, tobacco, and sugar) and increasing their exports under an ever-growing tariff rate. During World War 2, Latin America had, on average, the highest tariffs in the world.[51]

There was a slight decrease in Latin American tariffs after World War 2, when Asia started to become very protectionist in order to rebuild yet the Latin Americans were still there. To this day, there are countries that only trade freely with other Latin American countries.[52]

Impact

There is a broad consensus among economists that protectionism has a negative effect on economic growth and economic welfare, while free trade and the reduction of trade barriers has a positive effect on economic growth.[10][11][12][7][53][54]

Protectionism is frequently criticized by economists as harming the people it is meant to help. Mainstream economists instead support free trade.[26][55] The principle of comparative advantage shows that the gains from free trade outweigh any losses as free trade creates more jobs than it destroys because it allows countries to specialize in the production of goods and services in which they have a comparative advantage.[56] Protectionism results in deadweight loss; this loss to overall welfare gives no-one any benefit, unlike in a free market, where there is no such total loss. According to economist Stephen P. Magee, the benefits of free trade outweigh the losses by as much as 100 to 1.[57]

Living standards

A 2016 study found that "trade typically favors the poor", as they spend a greater share of their earnings on goods, as free trade reduces the costs of goods.[58] Other research found that China's entry to the WTO benefitted US consumers, as the price of Chinese goods were substantially reduced.[59] Harvard economist Dani Rodrik argues that while globalization and free trade does contribute to social problems, "a serious retreat into protectionism would hurt the many groups that benefit from trade and would result in the same kind of social conflicts that globalization itself generates. We have to recognize that erecting trade barriers will help in only a limited set of circumstances and that trade policy will rarely be the best response to the problems [of globalization]".[60]

Growth

According to economic historians Findlay and O'Rourke, there is a consensus in the economics literature that protectionist policies in the interwar period "hurt the world economy overall, although there is a debate about whether the effect was large or small."[44]

Economic historian Paul Bairoch argued that economic protection was positively correlated with economic and industrial growth during the 19th century. For example, GNP growth during Europe's "liberal period" in the middle of the century (where tariffs were at their lowest), averaged 1.7% per year, while industrial growth averaged 1.8% per year. However, during the protectionist era of the 1870s and 1890s, GNP growth averaged 2.6% per year, while industrial output grew at 3.8% per year, roughly twice as fast as it had during the liberal era of low tariffs and free trade.[61] One study found that tariffs imposed on manufactured goods increase economic growth in developing countries, and this growth impact remains even after the tariffs are repealed.[62]

According to Dartmouth economist Douglas Irwin, "that there is a correlation between high tariffs and growth in the late nineteenth century cannot be denied. But correlation is not causation... there is no reason for necessarily thinking that import protection was a good policy just because the economic outcome was good: the outcome could have been driven by factors completely unrelated to the tariff, or perhaps could have been even better in the absence of protection."[63] Irwin furthermore writes that "few observers have argued outright that the high tariffs caused such growth."[63]

According to Oxford economic historian Kevin O'Rourke, "It seems clear that protection was important for the growth of US manufacturing in the first half of the 19th century; but this does not necessarily imply that the tariff was beneficial for GDP growth. Protectionists have often pointed to German and American industrialization during this period as evidence in favor of their position, but economic growth is influenced by many factors other than trade policy, and it is important to control for these when assessing the links between tariffs and growth."[64]

A prominent 1999 study by Jeffrey A. Frankel and David H. Romer found, contrary to free trade skeptics' claims, while controlling for relevant factors, that trade does indeed have a positive impact on growth and incomes.[65]

Developing world

There is broad consensus among economists that free trade helps workers in developing countries, even though they are not subject to the stringent health and labor standards of developed countries. This is because "the growth of manufacturing—and of the myriad other jobs that the new export sector creates—has a ripple effect throughout the economy" that creates competition among producers, lifting wages and living conditions.[66] The Nobel laureates, Milton Friedman and Paul Krugman, have argued for free trade as a model for economic development.[10] Alan Greenspan, former chair of the American Federal Reserve, has criticized protectionist proposals as leading "to an atrophy of our competitive ability. ... If the protectionist route is followed, newer, more efficient industries will have less scope to expand, and overall output and economic welfare will suffer."[67]

Protectionists postulate that new industries may require protection from entrenched foreign competition in order to develop. This was Alexander Hamilton's argument in his "Report on Manufactures",[citation needed] and the primary reason why George Washington signed the Tariff Act of 1789.[citation needed] Mainstream economists do concede that tariffs can in the short-term help domestic industries to develop, but are contingent on the short-term nature of the protective tariffs and the ability of the government to pick the winners.[68][69] The problems are that protective tariffs will not be reduced after the infant industry reaches a foothold, and that governments will not pick industries that are likely to succeed.[69] Economists have identified a number of cases across different countries and industries where attempts to shelter infant industries failed.[70][71][72][73][74]

Economists such as Paul Krugman have speculated that those who support protectionism ostensibly to further the interests of workers in the least developed countries are in fact being disingenuous, seeking only to protect jobs in developed countries.[75] Additionally, workers in the least developed countries only accept jobs if they are the best on offer, as all mutually consensual exchanges must be of benefit to both sides, or else they wouldn't be entered into freely. That they accept low-paying jobs from companies in developed countries shows that their other employment prospects are worse. A letter reprinted in the May 2010 edition of Econ Journal Watch identifies a similar sentiment against protectionism from 16 British economists at the beginning of the 20th century.[76]

Conflict

Protectionism has also been accused of being one of the major causes of war. Proponents of this theory point to the constant warfare in the 17th and 18th centuries among European countries whose governments were predominantly mercantilist and protectionist, the American Revolution, which came about ostensibly due to British tariffs and taxes, as well as the protective policies preceding both World War I and World War II. According to a slogan of Frédéric Bastiat (1801–1850), "When goods cannot cross borders, armies will."[77]

Current world trends

 
Protectionist measures taken since 2008 according to Global Trade Alert[78]

Since the end of World War II, it has been the stated policy of most First World countries to eliminate protectionism through free trade policies enforced by international treaties and organizations such as the World Trade Organization.[citation needed] Certain policies of First World governments have been criticized as protectionist, however, such as the Common Agricultural Policy[79] in the European Union, longstanding agricultural subsidies and proposed "Buy American" provisions[80] in economic recovery packages in the United States.

Heads of the G20 meeting in London on 2 April 2009 pledged "We will not repeat the historic mistakes of protectionism of previous eras". Adherence to this pledge is monitored by the Global Trade Alert,[81] providing up-to-date information and informed commentary to help ensure that the G20 pledge is met by maintaining confidence in the world trading system, deterring beggar-thy-neighbor acts and preserving the contribution that exports could play in the future recovery of the world economy.

Although they were reiterating what they had already committed to, last November in Washington, 17 of these 20 countries were reported by the World Bank as having imposed trade restrictive measures since then. In its report, the World Bank says most of the world's major economies are resorting to protectionist measures as the global economic slowdown begins to bite. Economists who have examined the impact of new trade-restrictive measures using detailed bilaterally monthly trade statistics estimated that new measures taken through late 2009 were distorting global merchandise trade by 0.25% to 0.5% (about $50 billion a year).[82]

Since then, however, President Donald Trump announced in January 2017 the U.S. was abandoning the TPP (Trans-Pacific Partnership) deal, saying, “We’re going to stop the ridiculous trade deals that have taken everybody out of our country and taken companies out of our country, and it’s going to be reversed.”[83]

See also

Further reading

  • Milner, Helen V. (1988). Resisting protectionism: global industries and the politics of international trade. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0691010748.
  • Hudson, Michael (2010). America's Protectionist Takeoff, 1815–1914: The Neglected American School of Political Economy. ISLET. ISBN 978-3980846684.

References

  1. ^ Murschetz, Paul (2013). State Aid for Newspapers: Theories, Cases, Actions. Springer Science+Business Media. p. 64. ISBN 978-3642356902. Parties of the left in government adopt protectionist policies for ideological reasons and because they wish to save worker jobs. Conversely, right-wing parties are predisposed toward free trade policies.
  2. ^ Peláez, Carlos (2008). Globalization and the State: Volume II: Trade Agreements, Inequality, the Environment, Financial Globalization, International Law and Vulnerabilities. United States: Palgrave MacMillan. p. 68. ISBN 978-0230205314. Left-wing parties tend to support more protectionist policies than right-wing parties.
  3. ^ Mansfield, Edward (2012). Votes, Vetoes, and the Political Economy of International Trade Agreements. Princeton University Press. p. 128. ISBN 978-0691135304. Left-wing governments are considered more likely than others to intervene in the economy and to enact protectionist trade policies.
  4. ^ Warren, Kenneth (2008). Encyclopedia of U.S. Campaigns, Elections, and Electoral Behavior: A–M, Volume 1. Sage. p. 680. ISBN 9781412954891. Yet, certain national interests, regional trading blocks, and left-wing anti-globalization forces still favor protectionist practices, making protectionism a continuing issue for both American political parties.
  5. ^ "Trump Repeats Nixon's Folly". The Atlantic. 2 March 2018. Retrieved 3 March 2018.
  6. ^ Fairbrother, Malcolm (1 March 2014). "Economists, Capitalists, and the Making of Globalization: North American Free Trade in Comparative-Historical Perspective". American Journal of Sociology. 119 (5): 1324–1379. doi:10.1086/675410. ISSN 0002-9602. PMID 25097930. S2CID 38027389.
  7. ^ a b c Mankiw, N. Gregory (24 April 2015). "Economists Actually Agree on This: The Wisdom of Free Trade" 14 May 2019 at the Wayback Machine. The New York Times. Retrieved 10 August 2021. "Economists are famous for disagreeing with one another.... But economists reach near unanimity on some topics, including international trade."
  8. ^ "Economic Consensus On Free Trade". PIIE. 25 May 2017. Retrieved 27 February 2018.
  9. ^ Poole, William (2004). "Free Trade: Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart?". Review. 86 (5). doi:10.20955/r.86.1-6.
  10. ^ a b c See P. Krugman, "The Narrow and Broad Arguments for Free Trade", American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 83(3), 1993 ; and P. Krugman, Peddling Prosperity: Economic Sense and Nonsense in the Age of Diminished Expectations, New York, W.W. Norton & Company, 1994.
  11. ^ a b "Free Trade". IGM Forum. 13 March 2012. Retrieved 24 June 2017.
  12. ^ a b "Import Duties". IGM Forum. 4 October 2016. Retrieved 24 June 2017.
  13. ^ "Trade Within Europe". IGM Forum. Retrieved 24 June 2017.
  14. ^ Poole, William (September/October 2004). "Free Trade: Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart" 7 November 2017 at the Wayback Machine. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review. 86 (5): pp. 1–6. "... most observers agree that '[t]he consensus among mainstream economists on the desirability of free trade remains almost universal.'" Quote at p. 1.
  15. ^ Irwin, Douglas (2017). Peddling Protectionism: Smoot-Hawley and the Great Depression. Princeton University Press. pp. vii–xviii. ISBN 978-1400888429.
  16. ^ Poole, William (2004). "Free Trade: Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart?". Review. 86 (5). doi:10.20955/r.86.1-6. One set of reservations concerns distributional effects of trade. Workers are not seen as benefiting from trade. Strong evidence exists indicating a perception that the benefits of trade flow to businesses and the wealthy, rather than to workers, and to those abroad rather than to those in the United States.
  17. ^ Rosenfeld, Everett (11 March 2016). "Here's why everyone is arguing about free trade". CNBC. Retrieved 10 August 2021.
  18. ^ a b Paul Krugman, Robin Wells & Martha L. Olney, Essentials of Economics (Worth Publishers, 2007), pp. 342–345.
  19. ^ Wong, Edward; Tatlow, Didi Kirsten (5 June 2013). "China Seen in Push to Gain Technology Insights". The New York Times. Retrieved 16 October 2017.
  20. ^ Markoff, John; Rosenberg, Matthew (3 February 2017). "China's Intelligent Weaponry Gets Smarter". The New York Times. Retrieved 16 October 2017.
  21. ^ "The Unpleasant Truth About Chinese Espionage". Observer.com. 22 April 2016. Retrieved 16 October 2017.
  22. ^ Ippei Yamazawa, "Restructuring the Japanese Economy: Policies and Performance" in Global Protectionism (eds. Robert C. Hine, Anthony P. O'Brien, David Greenaway & Robert J. Thornton: St. Martin's Press, 1991), pp. 55–56.
  23. ^ Crispin Weymouth, "Is 'Protectionism' a Useful Concept for Company Law and Foreign Investment Policy? An EU Perspective" in Company Law and Economic Protectionism: New Challenges to European Integration (eds. Ulf Bernitz & Wolf-Georg Ringe: Oxford University Press, 2010), pp. 44–76.
  24. ^ Peter Drahos; John Braithwaite (2002). Information Feudalism: Who Owns the Knowledge Economy?. London: Earthscan. p. 36. ISBN 978-1853839177.
  25. ^ [1] 17 October 2006 at the Wayback Machine
  26. ^ a b Free to Choose, Milton Friedman
  27. ^ The National System of Political Economy, by Friedrich List, 1841, translated by Sampson S. Lloyd M.P., 1885 edition, Fourth Book, "The Politics", Chapter 33.
  28. ^ Shafaeddin, Mehdi (1998). "How did Developed Countries Industrialize? The History of Trade and Industrial Policy: the Cases of Great Britain and the USA". United Nations Conference on Trade and Development.
  29. ^ Reinert, Eric (2007). How Rich Countries got Rich and Why Poor Countries Stay Poor. New York: Carroll & Graf.
  30. ^ "Trade Policy and Economic Development". A Trading Nation: Canadian Trade Policy from Colonialism to Globalization. ISBN 978-0774808941.
  31. ^ a b C, Feenstra, Robert; M, Taylor, Alan (23 December 2013). "Globalization in an Age of Crisis: Multilateral Economic Cooperation in the Twenty-First Century". NBER. doi:10.7208/chicago/9780226030890.001.0001. ISBN 978-0226030753.
  32. ^ a b "A historian on the myths of American trade". The Economist. Retrieved 26 November 2017.
  33. ^ a b c Irwin, Douglas A. (2 August 2020). "Trade Policy in American Economic History". Annual Review of Economics. 12 (1): 23–44. doi:10.1146/annurev-economics-070119-024409. ISSN 1941-1383. S2CID 241740782.
  34. ^ a b Paul Bairoch (1995). . University of Chicago Press. pp. 31–32. Archived from the original on 12 October 2017. Retrieved 16 August 2017.
  35. ^ Paul Bairoch (1995). Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes. University of Chicago Press. p. 33.
  36. ^ Paul Bairoch (1995). Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes. University of Chicago Press. p. 34.
  37. ^ Paul Bairoch (1995). Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes. University of Chicago Press. p. 36.
  38. ^ Paul Bairoch (1995). Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes. University of Chicago Press. pp. 34, 40.
  39. ^ Santosh Mehrotra; Sylvie Guichard (2020). Planning in the 20th Century and Beyond: India's Planning Commission and the NITI Aayog. Cambridge University Press. p. 285. ISBN 978-1108494625. Most importantly, the United States was the birthplace of the idea of infant industry protection, and indeed was the most heavily protected economy in the world for about a century, until the Second World War
  40. ^ Read, Robert (1 August 2005). "The Political Economy of Trade Protection: The Determinants and Welfare Impact of the 2002 US Emergency Steel Safeguard Measures" (PDF). World Economy. 28 (8): 1119–1137. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9701.2005.00722.x. ISSN 1467-9701. S2CID 154520390.
  41. ^ Chung, Sunghoon; Lee, Joonhyung; Osang, Thomas (1 June 2016). "Did China tire safeguard save U.S. workers?" (PDF). European Economic Review. 85: 22–38. doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.12.009. ISSN 0014-2921.
  42. ^ "Why American allies are angry". Gulfnews.com.
  43. ^ "Foreign Trade - U.S. Trade with China". United States Census Bureau.
  44. ^ a b c d Findlay, Ronald; O'Rourke, Kevin H. (2009). Power and Plenty. Press.princeton.edu. ISBN 978-0691143279. Retrieved 16 October 2017.
  45. ^ a b c d e f Findlay, Ronald; O'Rourke, Kevin H. (1 January 2003). "Commodity Market Integration, 1500–2000". NBER: 13–64.
  46. ^ Harley, C. Knick (2004). "7 – Trade: discovery, mercantilism and technology". The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain. Cambridge Core. pp. 175–203. doi:10.1017/CHOL9780521820363.008. ISBN 978-1139053853. Retrieved 27 June 2017.
  47. ^ Williamson, Jeffrey G (1 April 1990). "The impact of the Corn Laws just prior to repeal". Explorations in Economic History. 27 (2): 123–156. doi:10.1016/0014-4983(90)90007-L.
  48. ^ Daudin, Guillaume; O’Rourke, Kevin H.; Escosura, Leandro Prados de la (2008). "Trade and Empire, 1700–1870". Documents de Travail de l'Ofce.
  49. ^ Richard Wolfson (1999) How Bovine Growth Hormone Was Rejected in Canada 7 January 2023 at the Wayback Machine, from Consumerhealth.org 22(9)
  50. ^ Gallas, Daniel (August 2018). "The Country Built on Trade Barriers". BBC News. Retrieved 10 November 2021.
  51. ^ Coatsworth, John; Williamson, Jeffrey (June 2002). "HE ROOTS OF LATIN AMERICAN PROTECTIONISM: LOOKING BEFORE THE GREAT DEPRESSION". NBER Working Paper Series.
  52. ^ "Mercosur in Brief". mercosur.
  53. ^ William Poole, Free Trade: Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart 7 December 2017 at the Wayback Machine, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, September/October 2004, 86(5), pp. 1: "most observers agree that '[t]he consensus among mainstream economists on the desirability of free trade remains almost universal.'"
  54. ^ "Trade Within Europe | IGM Forum". Igmchicago.org. Retrieved 24 June 2017.
  55. ^ Krugman, Paul R. (1987). "Is Free Trade Passe?". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 1 (2): 131–44. doi:10.1257/jep.1.2.131. JSTOR 1942985.
  56. ^ Krugman, Paul (24 January 1997). The Accidental Theorist 20 September 2011 at the Wayback Machine. Slate.
  57. ^ Magee, Stephen P. (1976). International Trade and Distortions In Factor Markets. New York: Marcel-Dekker.
  58. ^ Fajgelbaum, Pablo D.; Khandelwal, Amit K. (1 August 2016). "Measuring the Unequal Gains from Trade" (PDF). The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 131 (3): 1113–80. doi:10.1093/qje/qjw013. ISSN 0033-5533. S2CID 9094432.
  59. ^ Amiti, Mary; Dai, Mi; Feenstra, Robert; Romalis, John (28 June 2017). "China's WTO entry benefits US consumers". VoxEU.org. Retrieved 28 June 2017.
  60. ^ Rodrik, Dani. "Has Globalization Gone Too Far?" (PDF). Institute for International Economics.
  61. ^ Bairoch, Paul (1993). Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. p. 47.
  62. ^ DeJong, David (2006). "Tariffs and Growth: an empirical exploration of contingent relationships". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 88 (4): 625–40. doi:10.1162/rest.88.4.625. S2CID 197260.
  63. ^ a b Irwin, Douglas A. (1 January 2001). "Tariffs and Growth in Late Nineteenth-Century America". World Economy. 24 (1): 15–30. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.200.5492. doi:10.1111/1467-9701.00341. ISSN 1467-9701. S2CID 153647738.
  64. ^ H. O'Rourke, Kevin (1 November 2000). "British trade policy in the 19th century: a review article". European Journal of Political Economy. 16 (4): 829–42. doi:10.1016/S0176-2680(99)00043-9.
  65. ^ Frankel, Jeffrey A; Romer, David (June 1999). "Does Trade Cause Growth?". American Economic Review. 89 (3): 379–99. doi:10.1257/aer.89.3.379. ISSN 0002-8282.
  66. ^ Krugman, Paul (21 March 1997). In Praise of Cheap Labor 7 September 2011 at the Wayback Machine. Slate.
  67. ^ Sicilia, David B. & Cruikshank, Jeffrey L. (2000). The Greenspan Effect, p. 131. New York: McGraw-Hill. ISBN 0071349197.
  68. ^ "The Case for Protecting Infant Industries". Bloomberg.com. 22 December 2016. Retrieved 24 June 2017.
  69. ^ a b Baldwin, Robert E. (1969). "The Case against Infant-Industry Tariff Protection". Journal of Political Economy. 77 (3): 295–305. doi:10.1086/259517. JSTOR 1828905. S2CID 154784307.
  70. ^ O, Krueger, Anne; Baran, Tuncer (1982). "An Empirical Test of the Infant Industry Argument". American Economic Review. 72 (5).
  71. ^ Choudhri, Ehsan U.; Hakura, Dalia S. (2000). "International Trade and Productivity Growth: Exploring the Sectoral Effects for Developing Countries". IMF Staff Papers. 47 (1): 30–53. JSTOR 3867624.
  72. ^ Baldwin, Richard E.; Krugman, Paul (June 1986). "Market Access and International Competition: A Simulation Study of 16K Random Access Memories". NBER Working Paper No. 1936. doi:10.3386/w1936.
  73. ^ Luzio, Eduardo; Greenstein, Shane (1995). "Measuring the Performance of a Protected Infant Industry: The Case of Brazilian Microcomputers" (PDF). The Review of Economics and Statistics. 77 (4): 622–633. doi:10.2307/2109811. hdl:2142/29917. JSTOR 2109811.
  74. ^ "US Tire Tariffs: Saving Few Jobs at High Cost". PIIE. 2 March 2016. Retrieved 24 June 2017.
  75. ^ Krugman, Paul (21 November 1997). A Raspberry for Free Trade 1 October 2007 at the Wayback Machine. Slate.
  76. ^ "Convictions Opposed to Certain Popular Opinions: The 1903 Anti-Protectionism Letter Supported by 16 British Economists". Econ Journal Watch 7(2): 157–61, May 2010. econjwatch.org 14 May 2019 at the Wayback Machine
  77. ^ DiLorenzo, T. J., Frederic Bastiat (1801–1850): Between the French and Marginalist Revolutions. accessed at [Ludwig Von Mises Institute] 2012-04-13 13 September 2014 at the Wayback Machine
  78. ^ "Independent monitoring of policies that affect world trade". Global Trade Alert. Retrieved 16 December 2016.
  79. ^ "A French Roadblock to Free Trade". The New York Times. 31 August 2003. Retrieved 22 May 2010.
  80. ^ "Brussels Warns US on Protectionism". Dw-world.de. 30 January 2009. Retrieved 16 October 2017.
  81. ^ "Global Trade Alert". Globaltradealert.org. Retrieved 16 October 2017.
  82. ^ "Trade and the Crisis: Protect or Recover" (PDF). Imf.org. Retrieved 16 October 2017.
  83. ^ Baker, Peter (23 January 2017). "Trump Abandons Trans-Pacific Partnership, Obama's Signature Trade Deal". The New York Times. Retrieved 1 July 2018.

External links

  •   Media related to Protectionism at Wikimedia Commons

protectionism, protectionist, redirects, here, other, uses, protectionist, disambiguation, sometimes, referred, trade, protectionism, economic, policy, restricting, imports, from, other, countries, through, methods, such, tariffs, imported, goods, import, quot. Protectionist redirects here For other uses see Protectionist disambiguation Protectionism sometimes referred to as trade protectionism is the economic policy of restricting imports from other countries through methods such as tariffs on imported goods import quotas and a variety of other government regulations Proponents argue that protectionist policies shield the producers businesses and workers of the import competing sector in the country from foreign competitors Opponents argue that protectionist policies reduce trade and adversely affect consumers in general by raising the cost of imported goods as well as the producers and workers in export sectors both in the country implementing protectionist policies and in the countries protected against citation needed Political poster by the British Liberal Party presenting their view of the differences between an economy based on free trade versus one based on protectionism The free trade shop is shown as full with customers due to its low prices The shop based on protectionism shows higher prices and a lack of customers and with animosity between the business owner and the regulator Anti free trade postcard from 1910 Protectionism is advocated mainly by parties that hold economic nationalist or left wing positions while economically right wing political parties generally support free trade 1 2 3 4 5 There is a consensus among economists that protectionism has a negative effect on economic growth and economic welfare 6 7 8 9 while free trade and the reduction of trade barriers have a significantly positive effect on economic growth 7 10 11 12 13 14 Some scholars such as Douglas Irwin have implicated protectionism as the cause of some economic crises most notably the Great Depression 15 Although trade liberalization can sometimes result in large and unequally distributed losses and gains and can in the short run cause significant economic dislocation of workers in import competing sectors 16 free trade has advantages of lowering costs of goods and services for both producers and consumers 17 Contents 1 Protectionist policies 2 History 2 1 In the United States 2 2 In Europe 2 3 In Canada 2 4 In Latin America 3 Impact 3 1 Living standards 3 2 Growth 3 3 Developing world 3 4 Conflict 4 Current world trends 5 See also 6 Further reading 7 References 8 External linksProtectionist policies EditMain article Tariff Logo of Belgium s National League for the Franc s Defense 1924 A variety of policies have been used to achieve protectionist goals These include Tariffs and import quotas are the most common types of protectionist policies 18 A tariff is an excise tax levied on imported goods Originally imposed to raise government revenue modern tariffs are now used primarily to protect domestic producers and wage rates from lower priced importers An import quota is a limit on the volume of a good that may be legally imported usually established through an import licensing regime 18 Protection of technologies patents technical and scientific knowledge 19 20 21 Restrictions on foreign direct investment 22 such as restrictions on the acquisition of domestic firms by foreign investors 23 Administrative barriers Countries are sometimes accused of using their various administrative rules e g regarding food safety environmental standards electrical safety etc as a way to introduce barriers to imports Anti dumping legislation Dumping is the practice of firms selling to export markets at lower prices than are charged in domestic markets Supporters of anti dumping laws argue that they prevent the import of cheaper foreign goods that would cause local firms to close down However in practice anti dumping laws are usually used to impose trade tariffs on foreign exporters Direct subsidies Government subsidies in the form of lump sum payments or cheap loans are sometimes given to local firms that cannot compete well against imports These subsidies are purported to protect local jobs and to help local firms adjust to the world markets Export subsidies Export subsidies are often used by governments to increase exports Export subsidies have the opposite effect of export tariffs because exporters get payment which is a percentage or proportion of the value of exported Export subsidies increase the amount of trade and in a country with floating exchange rates have effects similar to import subsidies Exchange rate control A government may intervene in the foreign exchange market to lower the value of its currency by selling its currency in the foreign exchange market Doing so will raise the cost of imports and lower the cost of exports leading to an improvement in its trade balance However such a policy is only effective in the short run as it will lead to higher inflation in the country in the long run which will in turn raise the real cost of exports and reduce the relative price of imports International patent systems There is an argument for viewing national patent systems as a cloak for protectionist trade policies at a national level Two strands of this argument exist one when patents held by one country form part of a system of exploitable relative advantage in trade negotiations against another and a second where adhering to a worldwide system of patents confers good citizenship status despite de facto protectionism Peter Drahos explains that States realized that patent systems could be used to cloak protectionist strategies There were also reputational advantages for states to be seen to be sticking to intellectual property systems One could attend the various revisions of the Paris and Berne conventions participate in the cosmopolitan moral dialogue about the need to protect the fruits of authorial labor and inventive genius knowing all the while that one s domestic intellectual property system was a handy protectionist weapon 24 Political campaigns advocating domestic consumption e g the Buy American campaign in the United States which could be seen as an extra legal promotion of protectionism Preferential governmental spending such as the Buy American Act federal legislation which called upon the United States government to prefer US made products in its purchases In the modern trade arena many other initiatives besides tariffs have been called protectionist For example some commentators such as Jagdish Bhagwati see developed countries efforts in imposing their own labor or environmental standards as protectionism Also the imposition of restrictive certification procedures on imports is seen in this light Further others point out that free trade agreements often have protectionist provisions such as intellectual property copyright and patent restrictions that benefit large corporations These provisions restrict trade in music movies pharmaceuticals software and other manufactured items to high cost producers with quotas from low cost producers set to zero 25 History Edit Tariff Rates in Japan 1870 1960 Tariff Rates in Spain and Italy 1860 1910 Historically protectionism was associated with economic theories such as mercantilism which focused on achieving positive trade balance and accumulating gold and import substitution citation needed In the 18th century Adam Smith famously warned against the interested sophistry of industry seeking to gain an advantage at the cost of the consumers 26 Friedrich List saw Adam Smith s views on free trade as disingenuous believing that Smith advocated for free trade so that British industry could lock out underdeveloped foreign competition 27 Some have argued that no major country has ever successfully industrialized without some form of economic protection 28 29 Economic historian Paul Bairoch wrote that historically free trade is the exception and protectionism the rule 30 According to economic historians Douglas Irwin and Kevin O Rourke shocks that emanate from brief financial crises tend to be transitory and have a little long run effect on trade policy whereas those that play out over longer periods the early 1890s early 1930s may give rise to protectionism that is difficult to reverse Regional wars also produce transitory shocks that have little impact on long run trade policy while global wars give rise to extensive government trade restrictions that can be difficult to reverse 31 One paper notes that sudden shifts in comparative advantage for specific countries have led some countries to become protectionist The shift in comparative advantage associated with the opening up of New World frontiers and the subsequent grain invasion of Europe led to higher agricultural tariffs from the late 1870s onwards which as we have seen reversed the move toward freer trade that had characterized mid nineteenth century Europe In the decades after World War II Japan s rapid rise led to trade friction with other countries Japan s recovery was accompanied by a sharp increase in its exports of certain product categories cotton textiles in the 1950s steel in the 1960s automobiles in the 1970s and electronics in the 1980s In each case the rapid expansion in Japan s exports created difficulties for its trading partners and the use of protectionism as a shock absorber 31 In the United States Edit Main articles Protectionism in the United States and Tariffs in United States history Tariff rates France UK and US Average tariff rates in US 1821 2016 US trade balance 1895 2015 According to economic historian Douglas Irwin a common myth about US trade policy is that low tariffs harmed American manufacturers in the early 19th century and then that high tariffs made the United States into a great industrial power in the late 19th century 32 A review by The Economist of Irwin s 2017 book Clashing over Commerce A History of US Trade Policy states 32 Political dynamics would lead people to see a link between tariffs and the economic cycle that was not there A boom would generate enough revenue for tariffs to fall and when the bust came pressure would build to raise them again By the time that happened the economy would be recovering giving the impression that tariff cuts caused the crash and the reverse generated the recovery Mr Irwin also attempts to debunk the idea that protectionism made America a great industrial power a notion believed by some to offer lessons for developing countries today As its share of global manufacturing powered from 23 in 1870 to 36 in 1913 the admittedly high tariffs of the time came with a cost estimated at around 0 5 of GDP in the mid 1870s In some industries they might have sped up development by a few years But American growth during its protectionist period was more to do with its abundant resources and openness to people and ideas According to Irwin tariffs have serve three primary purposes in the United States to raise revenue for the government to restrict imports and protect domestic producers from foreign competition and to reach reciprocity agreements that reduce trade barriers 33 From 1790 to 1860 average tariffs increased from 20 percent to 60 percent before declining again to 20 percent 33 From 1861 to 1933 which Irwin characterizes as the restriction period the average tariffs increased to 50 percent and remained at that level for several decades From 1934 onwards which Irwin characterizes as the reciprocity period the average tariff declined substantially until it leveled off at 5 percent 33 Economist Paul Bairoch documented that the United States imposed among the highest rates in the world from around the founding of the country until the World War II period describing the United States as the mother country and bastion of modern protectionism since the end of the 18th century and until the post World War II period 34 Alexander Hamilton the first United States Secretary of the Treasury was of the view as articulated most famously in his Report on Manufactures that developing an industrialized economy was impossible without protectionism because import duties are necessary to shelter domestic infant industries until they could achieve economies of scale 35 The industrial takeoff of the United States occurred under protectionist policies 1816 1848 and under moderate protectionism 1846 1861 and continued under strict protectionist policies 1861 1945 36 In the late 19th century higher tariffs were introduced on the grounds that they were needed to protect American wages and to protect American farmers 37 Between 1824 and the 1940s the U S imposed much higher average tariff rates on manufactured products than did Britain or any other European country with the exception for a period of time of Spain and Russia 38 Up until the end of World War II the United States had the most protectionist economy on Earth 39 The Bush administration implemented tariffs on Chinese steel in 2002 according to a 2005 review of existing research on the tariff all studies found that the tariffs caused more harm than gains to the US economy and employment 40 The Obama administration implemented tariffs on Chinese tires between 2009 and 2012 as an anti dumping measure a 2016 study found that these tariffs had no impact on employment and wages in the US tire industry 41 In 2018 EU Trade Commissioner Cecilia Malmstrom stated that the US was playing a dangerous game in applying tariffs on steel and aluminum imports from most countries and stated that she saw the Trump administration s decision to do so as both pure protectionist and illegal 42 The tariffs imposed by the Trump administration during the China United States trade war led to a minor reduction in the United States trade deficit with China 43 In Europe Edit Europe became increasingly protectionist during the eighteenth century 44 Economic historians Findlay and O Rourke write that in the immediate aftermath of the Napoleonic Wars European trade policies were almost universally protectionist with the exceptions being smaller countries such as the Netherlands and Denmark 44 Europe increasingly liberalized its trade during the 19th century 45 Countries such as Britain the Netherlands Denmark Portugal and Switzerland and arguably Sweden and Belgium had fully moved towards free trade prior to 1860 45 Economic historians see the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846 as the decisive shift toward free trade in Britain 45 46 A 1990 study by the Harvard economic historian Jeffrey Williamson showed that the Corn Laws which imposed restrictions and tariffs on imported grain substantially increased the cost of living for British workers and hampered the British manufacturing sector by reducing the disposable incomes that British workers could have spent on manufactured goods 47 The shift towards liberalization in Britain occurred in part due to the influence of economists like David Ricardo but also due to the growing power of urban interests 45 Findlay and O Rourke characterize 1860 Cobden Chevalier treaty between France and the United Kingdom as a decisive shift toward European free trade 45 This treaty was followed by numerous free trade agreements France and Belgium signed a treaty in 1861 a Franco Prussian treaty was signed in 1862 Italy entered the network of Cobden Chevalier treaties in 1863 Bairoch 1989 40 Switzerland in 1864 Sweden Norway Spain the Netherlands and the Hanseatic towns in 1865 and Austria in 1866 By 1877 less than two decades after the Cobden Chevalier treaty and three decades after British Repeal Germany had virtually become a free trade country Bairoch 41 Average duties on manufactured products had declined to 9 12 on the Continent a far cry from the 50 British tariffs and numerous prohibitions elsewhere of the immediate post Waterloo era Bairoch table 3 p 6 and table 5 p 42 45 Some European powers did not liberalize during the 19th century such as the Russian Empire and Austro Hungarian Empire which remained highly protectionist The Ottoman Empire also became increasingly protectionist 48 In the Ottoman Empire s case however it previously had liberal free trade policies during the 18th to early 19th centuries which British prime minister Benjamin Disraeli cited as an instance of the injury done by unrestrained competition in the 1846 Corn Laws debate arguing that it destroyed what had been some of the finest manufacturers of the world in 1812 34 The countries of Western Europe began to steadily liberalize their economies after World War II and the protectionism of the interwar period 44 In Canada Edit Main article National Policy Since 1971 Canada has protected producers of eggs milk cheese chicken and turkey with a system of supply management Though prices for these foods in Canada exceed global prices the farmers and processors have had the security of a stable market to finance their operations citation needed Doubts about the safety of bovine growth hormone sometimes used to boost dairy production led to hearings before the Senate of Canada resulting in a ban in Canada Thus supply management of milk products is consumer protection of Canadians 49 In Quebec the Federation of Quebec Maple Syrup Producers manages the supply of maple syrup citation needed In Latin America Edit Most Latin American Countries became independent in the early 19th century They revolted against their colonizers primarily Spain France and Portugal and set off on their own Following the achievement of their independence most of the Latin American countries adopted protectionism They both feared that any foreign competition would stomp out their newly created state and figured that lack of outside resources would drive domestic production 50 Another reason for protectionism was that Latin America was frequently attacked by outsiders Spain the United States of America France and Texas had all invaded or attempted to invade Latin America by the year 1880 It could be said that Latin America was essentially hiding in its shell trying just to survive in the 19th century Yet the protectionist behavior continued up until and during the World Wars No Latin American countries got seriously involved with either side Rather they just kept harvesting their crops mostly fruits tobacco and sugar and increasing their exports under an ever growing tariff rate During World War 2 Latin America had on average the highest tariffs in the world 51 There was a slight decrease in Latin American tariffs after World War 2 when Asia started to become very protectionist in order to rebuild yet the Latin Americans were still there To this day there are countries that only trade freely with other Latin American countries 52 Impact EditThere is a broad consensus among economists that protectionism has a negative effect on economic growth and economic welfare while free trade and the reduction of trade barriers has a positive effect on economic growth 10 11 12 7 53 54 Protectionism is frequently criticized by economists as harming the people it is meant to help Mainstream economists instead support free trade 26 55 The principle of comparative advantage shows that the gains from free trade outweigh any losses as free trade creates more jobs than it destroys because it allows countries to specialize in the production of goods and services in which they have a comparative advantage 56 Protectionism results in deadweight loss this loss to overall welfare gives no one any benefit unlike in a free market where there is no such total loss According to economist Stephen P Magee the benefits of free trade outweigh the losses by as much as 100 to 1 57 Living standards Edit A 2016 study found that trade typically favors the poor as they spend a greater share of their earnings on goods as free trade reduces the costs of goods 58 Other research found that China s entry to the WTO benefitted US consumers as the price of Chinese goods were substantially reduced 59 Harvard economist Dani Rodrik argues that while globalization and free trade does contribute to social problems a serious retreat into protectionism would hurt the many groups that benefit from trade and would result in the same kind of social conflicts that globalization itself generates We have to recognize that erecting trade barriers will help in only a limited set of circumstances and that trade policy will rarely be the best response to the problems of globalization 60 Growth Edit According to economic historians Findlay and O Rourke there is a consensus in the economics literature that protectionist policies in the interwar period hurt the world economy overall although there is a debate about whether the effect was large or small 44 Economic historian Paul Bairoch argued that economic protection was positively correlated with economic and industrial growth during the 19th century For example GNP growth during Europe s liberal period in the middle of the century where tariffs were at their lowest averaged 1 7 per year while industrial growth averaged 1 8 per year However during the protectionist era of the 1870s and 1890s GNP growth averaged 2 6 per year while industrial output grew at 3 8 per year roughly twice as fast as it had during the liberal era of low tariffs and free trade 61 One study found that tariffs imposed on manufactured goods increase economic growth in developing countries and this growth impact remains even after the tariffs are repealed 62 According to Dartmouth economist Douglas Irwin that there is a correlation between high tariffs and growth in the late nineteenth century cannot be denied But correlation is not causation there is no reason for necessarily thinking that import protection was a good policy just because the economic outcome was good the outcome could have been driven by factors completely unrelated to the tariff or perhaps could have been even better in the absence of protection 63 Irwin furthermore writes that few observers have argued outright that the high tariffs caused such growth 63 According to Oxford economic historian Kevin O Rourke It seems clear that protection was important for the growth of US manufacturing in the first half of the 19th century but this does not necessarily imply that the tariff was beneficial for GDP growth Protectionists have often pointed to German and American industrialization during this period as evidence in favor of their position but economic growth is influenced by many factors other than trade policy and it is important to control for these when assessing the links between tariffs and growth 64 A prominent 1999 study by Jeffrey A Frankel and David H Romer found contrary to free trade skeptics claims while controlling for relevant factors that trade does indeed have a positive impact on growth and incomes 65 Developing world Edit See also Infant industry argument There is broad consensus among economists that free trade helps workers in developing countries even though they are not subject to the stringent health and labor standards of developed countries This is because the growth of manufacturing and of the myriad other jobs that the new export sector creates has a ripple effect throughout the economy that creates competition among producers lifting wages and living conditions 66 The Nobel laureates Milton Friedman and Paul Krugman have argued for free trade as a model for economic development 10 Alan Greenspan former chair of the American Federal Reserve has criticized protectionist proposals as leading to an atrophy of our competitive ability If the protectionist route is followed newer more efficient industries will have less scope to expand and overall output and economic welfare will suffer 67 Protectionists postulate that new industries may require protection from entrenched foreign competition in order to develop This was Alexander Hamilton s argument in his Report on Manufactures citation needed and the primary reason why George Washington signed the Tariff Act of 1789 citation needed Mainstream economists do concede that tariffs can in the short term help domestic industries to develop but are contingent on the short term nature of the protective tariffs and the ability of the government to pick the winners 68 69 The problems are that protective tariffs will not be reduced after the infant industry reaches a foothold and that governments will not pick industries that are likely to succeed 69 Economists have identified a number of cases across different countries and industries where attempts to shelter infant industries failed 70 71 72 73 74 Economists such as Paul Krugman have speculated that those who support protectionism ostensibly to further the interests of workers in the least developed countries are in fact being disingenuous seeking only to protect jobs in developed countries 75 Additionally workers in the least developed countries only accept jobs if they are the best on offer as all mutually consensual exchanges must be of benefit to both sides or else they wouldn t be entered into freely That they accept low paying jobs from companies in developed countries shows that their other employment prospects are worse A letter reprinted in the May 2010 edition of Econ Journal Watch identifies a similar sentiment against protectionism from 16 British economists at the beginning of the 20th century 76 Conflict Edit Protectionism has also been accused of being one of the major causes of war Proponents of this theory point to the constant warfare in the 17th and 18th centuries among European countries whose governments were predominantly mercantilist and protectionist the American Revolution which came about ostensibly due to British tariffs and taxes as well as the protective policies preceding both World War I and World War II According to a slogan of Frederic Bastiat 1801 1850 When goods cannot cross borders armies will 77 Current world trends Edit Protectionist measures taken since 2008 according to Global Trade Alert 78 Since the end of World War II it has been the stated policy of most First World countries to eliminate protectionism through free trade policies enforced by international treaties and organizations such as the World Trade Organization citation needed Certain policies of First World governments have been criticized as protectionist however such as the Common Agricultural Policy 79 in the European Union longstanding agricultural subsidies and proposed Buy American provisions 80 in economic recovery packages in the United States Heads of the G20 meeting in London on 2 April 2009 pledged We will not repeat the historic mistakes of protectionism of previous eras Adherence to this pledge is monitored by the Global Trade Alert 81 providing up to date information and informed commentary to help ensure that the G20 pledge is met by maintaining confidence in the world trading system deterring beggar thy neighbor acts and preserving the contribution that exports could play in the future recovery of the world economy Although they were reiterating what they had already committed to last November in Washington 17 of these 20 countries were reported by the World Bank as having imposed trade restrictive measures since then In its report the World Bank says most of the world s major economies are resorting to protectionist measures as the global economic slowdown begins to bite Economists who have examined the impact of new trade restrictive measures using detailed bilaterally monthly trade statistics estimated that new measures taken through late 2009 were distorting global merchandise trade by 0 25 to 0 5 about 50 billion a year 82 Since then however President Donald Trump announced in January 2017 the U S was abandoning the TPP Trans Pacific Partnership deal saying We re going to stop the ridiculous trade deals that have taken everybody out of our country and taken companies out of our country and it s going to be reversed 83 See also EditAmerican System economic plan Autarky Brexit Currency War Developmentalism Digital Millennium Copyright Act Economic nationalism Free trade debate Globalization Henry C Carey Historiography of the fall of the Western Roman Empire Imperial Preference International trade Market preserving federalism National Policy Not Invented Here Project Labor Agreement Protected Geographical Status Protection or Free Trade Protectionism in the United States Protective tariff Rent seeking Resistive economy Smoot Hawley Act Tariff Reform League 1923 United Kingdom general election Voluntary export restraint Washington ConsensusFurther reading EditMilner Helen V 1988 Resisting protectionism global industries and the politics of international trade Princeton New Jersey Princeton University Press ISBN 978 0691010748 Hudson Michael 2010 America s Protectionist Takeoff 1815 1914 The Neglected American School of Political Economy ISLET ISBN 978 3980846684 References Edit Murschetz Paul 2013 State Aid for Newspapers Theories Cases Actions Springer Science Business Media p 64 ISBN 978 3642356902 Parties of the left in government adopt protectionist policies for ideological reasons and because they wish to save worker jobs Conversely right wing parties are predisposed toward free trade policies Pelaez Carlos 2008 Globalization and the State Volume II Trade Agreements Inequality the Environment Financial Globalization International Law and Vulnerabilities United States Palgrave MacMillan p 68 ISBN 978 0230205314 Left wing parties tend to support more protectionist policies than right wing parties Mansfield Edward 2012 Votes Vetoes and the Political Economy of International Trade Agreements Princeton University Press p 128 ISBN 978 0691135304 Left wing governments are considered more likely than others to intervene in the economy and to enact protectionist trade policies Warren Kenneth 2008 Encyclopedia of U S Campaigns Elections and Electoral Behavior A M Volume 1 Sage p 680 ISBN 9781412954891 Yet certain national interests regional trading blocks and left wing anti globalization forces still favor protectionist practices making protectionism a continuing issue for both American political parties Trump Repeats Nixon s Folly The Atlantic 2 March 2018 Retrieved 3 March 2018 Fairbrother Malcolm 1 March 2014 Economists Capitalists and the Making of Globalization North American Free Trade in Comparative Historical Perspective American Journal of Sociology 119 5 1324 1379 doi 10 1086 675410 ISSN 0002 9602 PMID 25097930 S2CID 38027389 a b c Mankiw N Gregory 24 April 2015 Economists Actually Agree on This The Wisdom of Free Trade Archived 14 May 2019 at the Wayback Machine The New York Times Retrieved 10 August 2021 Economists are famous for disagreeing with one another But economists reach near unanimity on some topics including international trade Economic Consensus On Free Trade PIIE 25 May 2017 Retrieved 27 February 2018 Poole William 2004 Free Trade Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart Review 86 5 doi 10 20955 r 86 1 6 a b c See P Krugman The Narrow and Broad Arguments for Free Trade American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 83 3 1993 and P Krugman Peddling Prosperity Economic Sense and Nonsense in the Age of Diminished Expectations New York W W Norton amp Company 1994 a b Free Trade IGM Forum 13 March 2012 Retrieved 24 June 2017 a b Import Duties IGM Forum 4 October 2016 Retrieved 24 June 2017 Trade Within Europe IGM Forum Retrieved 24 June 2017 Poole William September October 2004 Free Trade Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart Archived 7 November 2017 at the Wayback Machine Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review 86 5 pp 1 6 most observers agree that t he consensus among mainstream economists on the desirability of free trade remains almost universal Quote at p 1 Irwin Douglas 2017 Peddling Protectionism Smoot Hawley and the Great Depression Princeton University Press pp vii xviii ISBN 978 1400888429 Poole William 2004 Free Trade Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart Review 86 5 doi 10 20955 r 86 1 6 One set of reservations concerns distributional effects of trade Workers are not seen as benefiting from trade Strong evidence exists indicating a perception that the benefits of trade flow to businesses and the wealthy rather than to workers and to those abroad rather than to those in the United States Rosenfeld Everett 11 March 2016 Here s why everyone is arguing about free trade CNBC Retrieved 10 August 2021 a b Paul Krugman Robin Wells amp Martha L Olney Essentials of Economics Worth Publishers 2007 pp 342 345 Wong Edward Tatlow Didi Kirsten 5 June 2013 China Seen in Push to Gain Technology Insights The New York Times Retrieved 16 October 2017 Markoff John Rosenberg Matthew 3 February 2017 China s Intelligent Weaponry Gets Smarter The New York Times Retrieved 16 October 2017 The Unpleasant Truth About Chinese Espionage Observer com 22 April 2016 Retrieved 16 October 2017 Ippei Yamazawa Restructuring the Japanese Economy Policies and Performance in Global Protectionism eds Robert C Hine Anthony P O Brien David Greenaway amp Robert J Thornton St Martin s Press 1991 pp 55 56 Crispin Weymouth Is Protectionism a Useful Concept for Company Law and Foreign Investment Policy An EU Perspective in Company Law and Economic Protectionism New Challenges to European Integration eds Ulf Bernitz amp Wolf Georg Ringe Oxford University Press 2010 pp 44 76 Peter Drahos John Braithwaite 2002 Information Feudalism Who Owns the Knowledge Economy London Earthscan p 36 ISBN 978 1853839177 1 Archived 17 October 2006 at the Wayback Machine a b Free to Choose Milton Friedman The National System of Political Economy by Friedrich List 1841 translated by Sampson S Lloyd M P 1885 edition Fourth Book The Politics Chapter 33 Shafaeddin Mehdi 1998 How did Developed Countries Industrialize The History of Trade and Industrial Policy the Cases of Great Britain and the USA United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Reinert Eric 2007 How Rich Countries got Rich and Why Poor Countries Stay Poor New York Carroll amp Graf Trade Policy and Economic Development A Trading Nation Canadian Trade Policy from Colonialism to Globalization ISBN 978 0774808941 a b C Feenstra Robert M Taylor Alan 23 December 2013 Globalization in an Age of Crisis Multilateral Economic Cooperation in the Twenty First Century NBER doi 10 7208 chicago 9780226030890 001 0001 ISBN 978 0226030753 a b A historian on the myths of American trade The Economist Retrieved 26 November 2017 a b c Irwin Douglas A 2 August 2020 Trade Policy in American Economic History Annual Review of Economics 12 1 23 44 doi 10 1146 annurev economics 070119 024409 ISSN 1941 1383 S2CID 241740782 a b Paul Bairoch 1995 Economics and World History Myths and Paradoxes University of Chicago Press pp 31 32 Archived from the original on 12 October 2017 Retrieved 16 August 2017 Paul Bairoch 1995 Economics and World History Myths and Paradoxes University of Chicago Press p 33 Paul Bairoch 1995 Economics and World History Myths and Paradoxes University of Chicago Press p 34 Paul Bairoch 1995 Economics and World History Myths and Paradoxes University of Chicago Press p 36 Paul Bairoch 1995 Economics and World History Myths and Paradoxes University of Chicago Press pp 34 40 Santosh Mehrotra Sylvie Guichard 2020 Planning in the 20th Century and Beyond India s Planning Commission and the NITI Aayog Cambridge University Press p 285 ISBN 978 1108494625 Most importantly the United States was the birthplace of the idea of infant industry protection and indeed was the most heavily protected economy in the world for about a century until the Second World War Read Robert 1 August 2005 The Political Economy of Trade Protection The Determinants and Welfare Impact of the 2002 US Emergency Steel Safeguard Measures PDF World Economy 28 8 1119 1137 doi 10 1111 j 1467 9701 2005 00722 x ISSN 1467 9701 S2CID 154520390 Chung Sunghoon Lee Joonhyung Osang Thomas 1 June 2016 Did China tire safeguard save U S workers PDF European Economic Review 85 22 38 doi 10 1016 j euroecorev 2015 12 009 ISSN 0014 2921 Why American allies are angry Gulfnews com Foreign Trade U S Trade with China United States Census Bureau a b c d Findlay Ronald O Rourke Kevin H 2009 Power and Plenty Press princeton edu ISBN 978 0691143279 Retrieved 16 October 2017 a b c d e f Findlay Ronald O Rourke Kevin H 1 January 2003 Commodity Market Integration 1500 2000 NBER 13 64 Harley C Knick 2004 7 Trade discovery mercantilism and technology The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain Cambridge Core pp 175 203 doi 10 1017 CHOL9780521820363 008 ISBN 978 1139053853 Retrieved 27 June 2017 Williamson Jeffrey G 1 April 1990 The impact of the Corn Laws just prior to repeal Explorations in Economic History 27 2 123 156 doi 10 1016 0014 4983 90 90007 L Daudin Guillaume O Rourke Kevin H Escosura Leandro Prados de la 2008 Trade and Empire 1700 1870 Documents de Travail de l Ofce Richard Wolfson 1999 How Bovine Growth Hormone Was Rejected in Canada Archived 7 January 2023 at the Wayback Machine from Consumerhealth org 22 9 Gallas Daniel August 2018 The Country Built on Trade Barriers BBC News Retrieved 10 November 2021 Coatsworth John Williamson Jeffrey June 2002 HE ROOTS OF LATIN AMERICAN PROTECTIONISM LOOKING BEFORE THE GREAT DEPRESSION NBER Working Paper Series Mercosur in Brief mercosur William Poole Free Trade Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart Archived 7 December 2017 at the Wayback Machine Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review September October 2004 86 5 pp 1 most observers agree that t he consensus among mainstream economists on the desirability of free trade remains almost universal Trade Within Europe IGM Forum Igmchicago org Retrieved 24 June 2017 Krugman Paul R 1987 Is Free Trade Passe The Journal of Economic Perspectives 1 2 131 44 doi 10 1257 jep 1 2 131 JSTOR 1942985 Krugman Paul 24 January 1997 The Accidental Theorist Archived 20 September 2011 at the Wayback Machine Slate Magee Stephen P 1976 International Trade and Distortions In Factor Markets New York Marcel Dekker Fajgelbaum Pablo D Khandelwal Amit K 1 August 2016 Measuring the Unequal Gains from Trade PDF The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131 3 1113 80 doi 10 1093 qje qjw013 ISSN 0033 5533 S2CID 9094432 Amiti Mary Dai Mi Feenstra Robert Romalis John 28 June 2017 China s WTO entry benefits US consumers VoxEU org Retrieved 28 June 2017 Rodrik Dani Has Globalization Gone Too Far PDF Institute for International Economics Bairoch Paul 1993 Economics and World History Myths and Paradoxes Chicago University of Chicago Press p 47 DeJong David 2006 Tariffs and Growth an empirical exploration of contingent relationships The Review of Economics and Statistics 88 4 625 40 doi 10 1162 rest 88 4 625 S2CID 197260 a b Irwin Douglas A 1 January 2001 Tariffs and Growth in Late Nineteenth Century America World Economy 24 1 15 30 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 200 5492 doi 10 1111 1467 9701 00341 ISSN 1467 9701 S2CID 153647738 H O Rourke Kevin 1 November 2000 British trade policy in the 19th century a review article European Journal of Political Economy 16 4 829 42 doi 10 1016 S0176 2680 99 00043 9 Frankel Jeffrey A Romer David June 1999 Does Trade Cause Growth American Economic Review 89 3 379 99 doi 10 1257 aer 89 3 379 ISSN 0002 8282 Krugman Paul 21 March 1997 In Praise of Cheap Labor Archived 7 September 2011 at the Wayback Machine Slate Sicilia David B amp Cruikshank Jeffrey L 2000 The Greenspan Effect p 131 New York McGraw Hill ISBN 0071349197 The Case for Protecting Infant Industries Bloomberg com 22 December 2016 Retrieved 24 June 2017 a b Baldwin Robert E 1969 The Case against Infant Industry Tariff Protection Journal of Political Economy 77 3 295 305 doi 10 1086 259517 JSTOR 1828905 S2CID 154784307 O Krueger Anne Baran Tuncer 1982 An Empirical Test of the Infant Industry Argument American Economic Review 72 5 Choudhri Ehsan U Hakura Dalia S 2000 International Trade and Productivity Growth Exploring the Sectoral Effects for Developing Countries IMF Staff Papers 47 1 30 53 JSTOR 3867624 Baldwin Richard E Krugman Paul June 1986 Market Access and International Competition A Simulation Study of 16K Random Access Memories NBER Working Paper No 1936 doi 10 3386 w1936 Luzio Eduardo Greenstein Shane 1995 Measuring the Performance of a Protected Infant Industry The Case of Brazilian Microcomputers PDF The Review of Economics and Statistics 77 4 622 633 doi 10 2307 2109811 hdl 2142 29917 JSTOR 2109811 US Tire Tariffs Saving Few Jobs at High Cost PIIE 2 March 2016 Retrieved 24 June 2017 Krugman Paul 21 November 1997 A Raspberry for Free Trade Archived 1 October 2007 at the Wayback Machine Slate Convictions Opposed to Certain Popular Opinions The 1903 Anti Protectionism Letter Supported by 16 British Economists Econ Journal Watch 7 2 157 61 May 2010 econjwatch org Archived 14 May 2019 at the Wayback Machine DiLorenzo T J Frederic Bastiat 1801 1850 Between the French and Marginalist Revolutions accessed at Ludwig Von Mises Institute 2012 04 13 Archived 13 September 2014 at the Wayback Machine Independent monitoring of policies that affect world trade Global Trade Alert Retrieved 16 December 2016 A French Roadblock to Free Trade The New York Times 31 August 2003 Retrieved 22 May 2010 Brussels Warns US on Protectionism Dw world de 30 January 2009 Retrieved 16 October 2017 Global Trade Alert Globaltradealert org Retrieved 16 October 2017 Trade and the Crisis Protect or Recover PDF Imf org Retrieved 16 October 2017 Baker Peter 23 January 2017 Trump Abandons Trans Pacific Partnership Obama s Signature Trade Deal The New York Times Retrieved 1 July 2018 External links Edit Media related to Protectionism at Wikimedia Commons Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Protectionism amp oldid 1146792148, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.