fbpx
Wikipedia

Friedrich List

Georg Friedrich List (6 August 1789 – 30 November 1846) was a German-American economist and political theorist who developed the nationalist theory of political economy in both Europe and the United States.[1][2][3][4] He was a forefather of the German historical school of economics and argued for the Zollverein (a pan-German customs union) from a nationalist standpoint.[5] He advocated raising tariffs on imported goods while supporting free trade of domestic goods and stated the cost of a tariff should be seen as an investment in a nation's future productivity.[4]

Friedrich List
Lithography of List by Josef Kriehuber, 1845
Born(1789-08-06)6 August 1789
Died30 November 1846(1846-11-30) (aged 57)
NationalityGerman
American
Academic career
FieldEconomics
School or
tradition
Historical School
InfluencesJean-Antoine Chaptal · Alexander Hamilton · Daniel Raymond · Adolphe Thiers
ContributionsNational System of Innovation
Historical school of economics
Signature

List was a political liberal[6] who collaborated with Karl von Rotteck and Carl Theodor Welcker on the Rotteck-Welckersches Staatslexikon [de], an encyclopedia of political science that advocated constitutional liberalism and which influenced the Vormärz.[7] At the time in Europe, liberal and nationalist ideas were almost inseparably linked, and political liberalism was not yet attached to what was later considered "economic liberalism."[6][8] Emmanuel Todd considers List a forerunner to John Maynard Keynes as a theorist of "moderate or regulated capitalism."[9]

Biography edit

Early life edit

List was born in the free imperial city of Reutlingen in the Duchy of Württemberg on August 6, 1789.[10] His father, Johannes, was a prosperous master tanner and a city official, and Georg Friedrich was the second son and youngest child in his family.[11] He was educated at the town's Latin School. In an apprenticeship at his father's tanning business, List showed little interest in manual labor. He was apprenticed as a bureaucratic clerk at Blaubeuren.[11] After passing his examination, he became Taxes and Warehouses Commissioner in Schelklingen.[11]

University of Tübingen edit

At age 23, List was promoted to a post at Tübingen. While there, he regularly attended lectures at the University of Tübingen and expanded his reading. He also made the acquaintance of the future minister Johannes von Schlayer [de].[11] In 1816, List's position in the bureaucracy was improved as the succession of King William I of Württemberg ushered in a period of reform. Under minister Karl August von Wangenheim [de], List rose quickly through the bureaucracy and was made the first Professor of Administration and Politics at the University. List had been an advocate for establishing such a position, arguing in 1817:

"No one in our University has any conception of a national economy. No one teaches the science of agriculture, forestry, mining, industry, or trade. ... [T]he forms of government are in such a truly barbarous state, that if an official of the seventeenth century rose again from the dead he could at once take up his old work, though he would assuredly be astonished to find the advances that had been made during the interval in the simplest process of manufacture."[12]

As a deputy to the Württemberg chamber, he was active in advocating administrative reforms. He was eventually expelled from the chamber and in April 1822 sentenced to ten months' imprisonment with hard labor in the fortress of Asperg. He escaped to Alsace, and after visiting France and England returned in 1824 to finish his sentence, and was released on undertaking to emigrate to America.

Move to United States: 1825–1830 edit

Arriving in the United States in 1825, he settled in Pennsylvania, where he became an extensive landholder.[13] He first engaged in farming, but soon switched to journalism and edited a German paper in Reading.[14] He was active in the establishment of railroads.[13] Some argue (e.g. Chang, 2002) that it was in America that he gathered from a study of Alexander Hamilton's work the inspiration which made him an economist of his pronounced "National System" views which found realization in Henry Clay's American System. Others deny this (Daastøl, 2011), since he argued for a German customs union already in 1819, when he established the first German union for industry and trade. List's ideas on protectionism predate his American sojourn, and were influenced by liberal protectionists such as Adolphe Thiers.[15] The main theoretical reference approvingly cited by List in his 1827 pamphlet Outlines of American Political Economy, in which he defended the doctrine of pragmatic protection and free trade, was Jean-Antoine Chaptal's De l’industrie française (1819).[14][15] The discovery of coal on some land which he had acquired made him financially independent.

Return to Europe: 1831–1846 edit

In 1830, he was appointed United States consul at Hamburg, but on his arrival in Europe he found that the Senate had failed to confirm his appointment.[14] After residing for some time in Paris, he returned to Pennsylvania. He next settled in Leipzig in 1833, where for some time he was U.S. consul. He was a journalist in Paris from 1837 to 1843, where he wrote articles for Thiers's centre-left paper Le Constitutionnel.[15] He wrote several letters for the Augsburg Allgemeine Zeitung, which were published in 1841 in a volume under the title of Das nationale System der politischen Oekonomie.[14]

In 1841, his ill health had led him to decline an offer to edit the Rheinische Zeitung, a new Cologne paper of liberal views, and Karl Marx took the post.[16] In 1843, he established the Zollvereinsblatt in Augsburg, a newspaper in which he advocated the enlargement of the customs union (German: Zollverein), and the organization of a national commercial system.[13] He strongly advocated the extension of the railway system in Germany. The development of the Zollverein to where it unified Germany economically was due largely to his enthusiasm and ardour.

He visited Austria and Hungary in 1844.[14]

In 1846, he visited England with a view to forming a commercial alliance between that country and Germany but was unsuccessful.[13] His last days were darkened by many misfortunes; he lost much of his American property in a financial crisis, ill-health also overtook him, and he killed himself in Kufstein on 30 November 1846.[4]

Views edit

Nationalist view of political economy edit

 
Das nationale System der politischen Ökonomie, 1930.[17]

List's theory of "national economics" differed from the doctrines of "individual economics" and "cosmopolitan economics" by Adam Smith and J.B. Say. List argued that Smithian critiques of mercantilism were "partly correct", but argued for the need for temporary tariff protection targeted to protect specific infant industries that were critical to economic growth.[18]

List contrasted the economic behaviour of an individual with that of a nation.[18] An individual promotes only his own personal interests but a state fosters the welfare of all its citizens. An individual may prosper from activities which harm the interests of a nation. "Slavery may be a public calamity for a country, nevertheless some people may do very well in carrying on the slave trade and in holding slaves." Likewise, activities beneficial to society may injure the interests of certain individuals. "Canals and railroads may do great good to a nation, but all waggoners will complain of this improvement. Every new invention has some inconvenience for a number of individuals, and is nevertheless a public blessing". List argued that although some government action was essential to stimulate the economy, an overzealous government might do more harm than good. "It is bad policy to regulate everything and to promote everything by employing social powers, where things may better regulate themselves and can be better promoted by private exertions; but it is no less bad policy to let those things alone which can only be promoted by interfering social power."

Due to the "universal union" that nations have with their populace, List stated that "from this political union originates their commercial union, and it is in consequence of the perpetual peace thus maintained that commercial union has become so beneficial to them. ... The result of a general free trade would not be a universal republic, but, on the contrary, a universal subjection of the less advanced nations to the predominant manufacturing, commercial and naval power, is a conclusion for which the reasons are very strong. ... A universal republic ... , i.e. a union of the nations of the earth whereby they recognise the same conditions of right among themselves and renounce self-redress, can only be realised if a large number of nationalities attain to as nearly the same degree as possible of industry and civilisation, political cultivation and power. Only with the gradual formation of this union can free trade be developed; only as a result of this union can it confer on all nations the same great advantages which are now experienced by those provinces and states which are politically united. The system of protection, inasmuch as it forms the only means of placing those nations which are far behind in civilisation on equal terms with the one predominating nation, appears to be the most efficient means of furthering the final union of nations, and hence also of promoting true freedom of trade."[19]

In his seventh letter List repeated his assertion that economists should realise that since the human race is divided into independent states, "a nation would act unwisely to endeavour to promote the welfare of the whole human race at the expense of its particular strength, welfare, and independence. It is a dictate of the law of self-preservation to make its particular advancement in power and strength the first principles of its policy". A country should not count the cost of defending the overseas trade of its merchants. And "the manufacturing and agricultural interest must be promoted and protected even by sacrifices of the majority of the individuals, if it can be proved that the nation would never acquire the necessary perfection ... without such protective measures."[20]

List argued that international trade reduced the security of the states who took part in it.[21]

List argued that statesmen had two responsibilities: "one to contemporary society and one to future generations". Normally, the attention of most leaders is occupied by urgent matters, leaving little time to consider future problems. But when a country had reached a turning point in its development, its leaders were morally obliged to deal with issues that would affect the next generation. "On the threshold of a new phase in the development of their country, statesmen should be prepared to take the long view, despite the need to deal also with matters of immediate urgency."[22]

List's fundamental doctrine was that a nation's true wealth is the full and many-sided development of its productive power, rather than its current exchange values. For example, its economic education should be more important than immediate production of value, and it might be right that one generation should sacrifice its gain and enjoyment to secure the strength and skill of the future. Under normal conditions, an economically mature nation should also develop agriculture, manufacture and commerce. However, the last two factors were more important since they better influenced the nation's culture and independence and were especially connected to navigation, railways and high technology, and a purely-agricultural state tended to stagnate

However, List claimed that only countries in temperate regions were adapted to grow higher forms of industry. On the other hand, tropical regions had a natural monopoly in the production of certain raw materials. Thus, there were a spontaneous division of labor and a confederation of powers between both groups of countries.

List contended that Smith's economic system is not an industrial system but a mercantile system, and he called it "the exchange-value system". Contrary to Smith, he argued that the immediate private interest of individuals would not lead to the highest good of society. The nation stood between the individual and humanity, and was defined by its language, manners, historical development, culture and constitution. The unity must be the first condition of the security, well-being, progress and civilization of the individual. Private economic interests, like all others, must be subordinated to the maintenance, completion and strengthening of the nation.

Stages of economic development edit

List theorised that nations of the temperate zone (which are furnished with all the necessary conditions) naturally pass through stages of economic development in advancing to their normal economic state. These are:

  1. Pastoral life
  2. Agriculture
  3. Agriculture united with manufactures
  4. Agriculture, manufactures and commerce are combined

The progress of the nation through these stages is the task of the state, which must create the required conditions for the progress by using legislation and administrative action. This view leads to List's scheme of industrial politics. Every nation should begin with free trade, stimulating and improving its agriculture by trade with richer and more cultivated nations, importing foreign manufactures and exporting raw products. When it is economically so far advanced that it can manufacture for itself, then protection should be used to allow the home industries to develop, and save them from being overpowered by the competition of stronger foreign industries in the home market. When the national industries have grown strong enough that this competition is not a threat, then the highest stage of progress has been reached; free trade should again become the rule, and the nation be thus thoroughly incorporated with the universal industrial union. What a nation loses in exchange during the protective period, it more than gains in the long run in productive power. The temporary expenditure is analogous to the cost of the industrial education of the individual.

In a thousand cases the power of the State is compelled to impose restrictions on private industry. It prevents the ship owner from taking on board slaves on the west coast of Africa, and taking them over to America. It imposes regulations as to the building of steamers and the rules of navigation at sea, in order that passengers and sailors may not be sacrificed to the avarice and caprice of the captains. [...] Everywhere does the State consider it to be its duty to guard the public against danger and loss, as in the sale of the necessaries of life, so also in the sale of medicines, etc.[23]

Railways edit

List was the leading promoter of railways in Germany. His proposals on how to start up a system were widely adopted.[24] He summed up the advantages to be derived from the development of the railway system in 1841:[25]

  1. It is a means of national defence: it facilitates the concentration, distribution and direction of the army.
  2. It is a means to the improvement of the culture of the nation. It brings talent, knowledge and skill of every kind readily to market.
  3. It secures the community against dearth and famine, and against excessive fluctuation in the prices of the necessaries of life.
  4. It promotes the spirit of the nation, as it has a tendency to destroy the Philistine spirit arising from isolation and provincial prejudice and vanity. It binds nations by ligaments, and promotes an interchange of food and of commodities, thus making it feel to be a unit. The iron rails become a nerve system, which, on the one hand, strengthens public opinion, and, on the other hand, strengthens the power of the state for police and governmental purposes.

List drew up proposals for a national railway network before the first steam locomotive ran between Nuremberg and Fürth. He suggested construction of a railway between Leipzig and Dresden which would soon become Germany's first long distance railway. He is honored for his early promotion of the importance of railways with a bust in Leipzig main station as well as several streets named after him adjacent to railway stations (e.g. Friedrich-List-Platz). When the Swiss-German architect de:Martin Mächler first proposed what is today Berlin main station in 1917, he suggested the new central interchange station of the German rail network be named in honor of List.

Britain and world trade edit

While List once had urged Germany to join other 'manufacturing nations of the second rank' to check Britain's 'insular supremacy', by 1841 he considered that the United States and Russia would become the most powerful countries[citation needed]—a view also expressed by Alexis de Tocqueville the previous year. List hoped to persuade political leaders in England to co-operate with Germany to ward off this danger. His proposal was perhaps not so far-fetched as might appear at first sight. In 1844, the writer of an article in a leading review had declared that 'in every point of view, whether politically or commercially, we can have no better alliance than that of the German nation, spreading as it does, its 42 millions of souls without interruption over the surface of central Europe'.[26]

The practical conclusion which List drew for Germany was that it needed for its economic progress an extended and conveniently bounded territory reaching to the seacoast both on north and south, and a vigorous expansion of manufacture and trade, and that the way to the latter lay through judicious protective legislation with a customs union comprising all German lands, and a German marine with a Navigation Act. The national German spirit, striving after independence and power through union, and the national industry, awaking from its lethargy and eager to recover lost ground, were favorable to the success of List's book, and it produced a great sensation. He ably represented the tendencies and demands of his time in his own country; his work had the effect of fixing the attention, not merely of the speculative and official classes, but of practical men generally, on questions of political economy; and his ideas were undoubtedly the economic foundation of modern Germany as applied by the practical genius of Bismarck.

List considered that Napoleon's 'Continental System', aimed just at damaging Britain during a bitter long-term war, had in fact been quite good for German industry. This was the direct opposite of what was believed by the followers of Adam Smith. As List put it:

I perceived that the popular theory took no account of nations, but simply of the entire human race on the one hand, or of the single individual on the other. I saw clearly that free competition between two nations which are highly civilised can only be mutually beneficial in case both of them are in a nearly equal position of industrial development, and that any nation which owing to misfortunes is behind others in industry, commerce, and navigation ... must first of all strengthen her own individual powers, in order to fit herself to enter into free competition with more advanced nations. In a word, I perceived the distinction between cosmopolitical and political economy.[27]

List's argument was that Germany should follow actual English practice rather than the abstractions of Smith's doctrines:

Had the English left everything to itself—'Laissez faire, laissez aller', as the popular economical school recommends—the [German] merchants of the Steelyard would be still carrying on their trade in London, the Belgians would be still manufacturing cloth for the English, England would have still continued to be the sheep-farm of the Hansards, just as Portugal became the vineyard of England, and has remained so till our days, owing to the stratagem of a cunning diplomatist. Indeed, it is more than probable that without her [highly protectionist] commercial policy England would never have attained to such a large measure of municipal and individual freedom as she now possesses, for such freedom is the daughter of industry and wealth.

Influences edit

List's hostility to free trade was first decisively shaped by the ideas of his friend Adolphe Thiers and other liberal protectionists in France.[15] He was also later influenced by Alexander Hamilton and the American School rooted in Hamilton's economic principles, including Daniel Raymond,[28] but also by the general mode of thinking of America's first Treasury Secretary, and by his strictures on the doctrine of Adam Smith. He opposed the cosmopolitan principle in the contemporary economical system and the absolute doctrine of free trade which was in harmony with that principle, and instead developed the infant industry argument, to which he had been exposed by Hamilton and Raymond.[28] He gave prominence to the national idea and insisted on the special requirements of each nation according to its circumstances and especially to the degree of its development. He famously doubted the sincerity of calls to free trade from developed nations, in particular Britain:

Any nation which by means of protective duties and restrictions on navigation has raised her manufacturing power and her navigation to such a degree of development that no other nation can sustain free competition with her, can do nothing wiser than to throw away these ladders of her greatness, to preach to other nations the benefits of free trade, and to declare in penitent tones that she has hitherto wandered in the paths of error, and has now for the first time succeeded in discovering the truth.[29]

His idea of productive powers was influenced by the philosophy of productivity of Friedrich Wilhelm Joseph Schelling.[30][31] He was acquainted with Robert Schumann and Heinrich Heine.[30]

Legacy edit

 
Memorial statue at the main railway station of Leipzig

List's principal work is entitled Das Nationale System der Politischen Ökonomie (1841) and was translated into English as The National System of Political Economy.

Before 1914, List and Marx were the two best-known German economists and theorists of development, although Marx, unlike List, devised no policies to promote economic development.

This book has been more frequently translated than the works of any other German economist, except Karl Marx.[32]

He is credited with influencing Nazism in Germany, and his ideas are credited as forming the basis of the European Economic Community.[33]

In Ireland he influenced Arthur Griffith of Sinn Féin and these theories were used by the Fianna Fáil government in the 1930s to instigate protectionism with a view to developing Irish industry.

Among others he strongly influenced was Sergei Witte, the Imperial Russian Minister of Finance, 1892–1903. Witte's plan for rapid industrialisation was centred around railroad construction (the Trans-Siberian railroad for example) and a policy of protectionism. At the time, it was largely considered that Russia was a backward country with an under developed economy. The boom which was seen during the 1890s was largely credited to Witte's policy.

Angus Maddison noted that:

As Marx was not interested in the survival of the capitalist system, he was not really concerned with economic policy, except in so far as the labour movement was involved. There, his argument was concentrated on measures to limit the length of the working day, and to strengthen trade union bargaining power. His analysis was also largely confined to the situation in the leading capitalist country of his day—the UK—and he did not consider the policy problems of other Western countries in catching up with the lead country (as Friedrich List did). In so far as Marx was concerned with other countries, it was mainly with poor countries which were victims of Western imperialism in the merchant capitalist era.[34]

 
1989 Deutsche Bundespost stamp commemorating the 200th anniversary of List's birth

Heterodox economists, such as Ha-Joon Chang and Erik Reinert, refer to List often explicitly when writing about suitable economic policies for developing countries. List's influence among developing nations has been considerable. Japan has followed his model.[35]

The international economic policy of Meiji Japan was a combination of Hideyoshi's mercantilism and Friedrich List's Nationale System der Politischen Ökonomie.[36]

It has also been argued that Deng Xiaoping's post-Mao policies were inspired by List, as well as recent policies in India.[37][38]

China, under Deng, took on the clear features of a 'developmental dictatorship under single-party auspices.' The PRC would then belong to a class of regimes familiar to the 20th century that have their ideological sources in classical Marxism, but better reflect the developmental, nationalist views of Friedrich List.[39]

A 1943 German film The Endless Road portrayed List's life and achievements. He was played by Eugen Klöpfer.

See also edit

Works in English translation edit

  • —. The National System of Political Economy.

References edit

  1. ^ Freeman 1995.
  2. ^ Helleiner 2020.
  3. ^ Helleiner 2021.
  4. ^ a b c Friedrich List at the Encyclopædia Britannica
  5. ^ Tribe 2007, p. 36.
  6. ^ a b Hagemann & Wendler 2018, pp. 58–62.
  7. ^ Wendler 2014, pp. 12, 135–137.
  8. ^ Walther, Rudolf (1984). "Economic Liberalism". Economy and Society. 13 (2): 178–207. doi:10.1080/03085148300000019.
  9. ^ Wendler 2014, p. 220.
  10. ^ Hirst 1909, p. 1.
  11. ^ a b c d Hirst 1909, pp. 2–4.
  12. ^ Hirst 1909, p. 8.
  13. ^ a b c d Wilson, J. G.; Fiske, J., eds. (1892). "List, Friedrich" . Appletons' Cyclopædia of American Biography. New York: D. Appleton.
  14. ^ a b c d e Gilman, D. C.; Peck, H. T.; Colby, F. M., eds. (1905). "List, Friedrich" . New International Encyclopedia (1st ed.). New York: Dodd, Mead.
  15. ^ a b c d Todd 2015, pp. 15, 125, 146–153.
  16. ^ Henderson 1983, p. 85.
  17. ^ Originally published in 1841 at Stuttgart/Tübingen.
  18. ^ a b Helleiner, Eric (2023), Bukovansky, Mlada; Keene, Edward; Reus-Smit, Christian; Spanu, Maja (eds.), "Regulating Commerce", The Oxford Handbook of History and International Relations, Oxford University Press, pp. 334–C23P112, doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780198873457.013.22, ISBN 978-0-19-887345-7
  19. ^ National System of Political Economy, Friedrich List – p. 102–3
  20. ^ National System of Political Economy, Friedrich List—p. 150
  21. ^ Brooks 2005, pp. 1–2.
  22. ^ "The German Zollverein" in the Edinburgh Review, 1844, p. 117
  23. ^ Friedrich List. National System of Political Economy. p. 166.
  24. ^ Nipperdey 1996, p. 165.
  25. ^ List quoted in John J. Lalor, ed. Cyclopædia of Political Science (1881) 3:118
  26. ^ The German Zollverein in the Edinburgh Review, 1844, Vol. LXXIX, pp. 105 et seq.
  27. ^ The National System of Political Economy, by Friedrich List, 1841, translated by Sampson S. Lloyd M.P., 1885 edition, Author's Preface, Page xxvi.
  28. ^ a b Chang 2002.
  29. ^ The National System of Political Economy, by Friedrich List, 1841, translated by Sampson S. Lloyd M.P., 1885 edition, Fourth Book, "The Politics", Chapter 33.
  30. ^ a b Heuser 2008.
  31. ^ Heuser 1986.
  32. ^ Henderson (1983)
  33. ^ "Makes of nineteenth century culture: 1800–1914". Justin Wintle. Routledge. p. 367. Accessed January 27, 2010.
  34. ^ Dynamic forces in Capitalist Development: A Long-Run Comparative View, by Angus Maddison. Oxford University Press, 1991, page 19.
  35. ^ List's influence on Japanese economic policy: see "A contrary view: How the World Works 2006-01-17 at the Wayback Machine, by James Fallows"
  36. ^ Linebarger, Chu & Burks 1954, p. 326.
  37. ^ Clairmonte 1959.
  38. ^ Boianovsky 2011, p. 2.
  39. ^ A. James Gregor, , PS 137b - "Revolutionary Movements: Marxism and Fascism in East Asia" (Course Notes), 29 March 2005. Archived link, accessed 10 August 2014.

Bibliography edit

Books and book chapters edit

  • Anonymous (1877). Fr. List, ein Vorlaufer und ein Opfer für das Vaterland [Friederich List: a Forerunner and a Sacrifice for the Fatherland]. Vol. II. Stuttgart.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  • Boianovsky, Mauro (2011). Friedrich List and the Economic Fate of Tropical Countries (PDF). Universidade de Brasilia. (dissertation)
  • Bolsinger, Eckard (2004). (PDF). 54th Political Studies Association Annual Conference. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2008-06-26.
  • Brooks, Stephen G. (2005). Producing Security: Multinational Corporations, Globalization, and the Changing Calculus of Conflict. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-13031-6. JSTOR j.ctt7sjz7.
  • Borchardt, Knut; Schötz, Hans Otto, eds. (1991). Wirtschaftspolitik in der Krise. Die (Geheim-)Konferenz der Friedrich List-Gesellschaft im Sept.1931 über Möglichkeiten und Folgen einer Kreditausweitung [Economic Policy in Crisis: The (Secret) Conference of the Friedrich List Society in September 1931 on the Possibilities and Consequences of Credit Expansion]. Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft.
  • Brügelmann, Hermann (1956). Politische Ökonomie in kritischen Jahren. Die Friedrich List-Gesellschaft E.V., von 1925-1935 [Political Economy in Critical Years: The Friedrich List Society from 1925-1935]. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.
  • Daastøl, Arno Mong (2011). Friedrich List's Heart, Wit and Will: Mental Capital as the Productive Force of Progress (PDF). Erfurt.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) (doctoral dissertation)
  • Goldschmidt, Friedrich (1878). Friedrich List, Deutschlands grosser Volkswirth [Friedrich List, Germany's Greater National Economy] (in German). Berlin: J. Springer. OCLC 797286817.
  • Hagemann, Harald; Wendler, Eugen (2018). The Economic Thought of Friedrich List. Routledge. pp. 58–62.
  • Helleiner, Eric (2021). The Neomercantilists: A Global Intellectual History. Cornell University Press. ISBN 978-1-5017-6014-3.
  • Henderson, William O. (1983). Friedrich List: Economist and Visionary, 1789–1846. London: Frank Cass. ISBN 9780714631615.
  • Hirst, Margaret E. (1909). Life of Friedrich List. London.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link), containing a bibliography and a reprint of List's Petition on Behalf of the Handelsverein to the Federal Assembly (1819), Outlines of American Political Economy (1827), Philadelphia Speech (1827) (to the Harrisburg Convention), and the Introduction to The National System of Political Economy (1841).
  • Heuser, Marie-Luise (2008). "Romantik und Gesellschaft. Die Theorie der produktiven Kräfte" [Romance and Society: The Theory of Productive Forces]. In Gerhard, Myriam (ed.). Oldenburger Jahrbuch für Philosophie 2007 [Oldenburg Yearbook for Philosophy 2007]. pp. 253–277. ISBN 978-3-8142-2101-4.
  • Heuser, Marie-Luise (1986). Die Produktivität der Natur. Schellings Naturphilosophie und das neue Paradigma der Selbstorganisation in den Naturwissenschaften. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot. ISBN 3-428-06079-2.
  • Jentsch, Carl (1901). Friedrich List (in German). Berlin: Ernst Hofmann and Co.
  • Linebarger, Paul M. A.; Chu, Chu; Burks, Ardath W. (1954). Far Eastern Governments and Politics: China and Japan (2nd ed.). Princeton, NJ: D. Van Nostrand.
  • Nipperdey, Thomas (1996). Germany from Napoleon to Bismarck.
  • Szporluk, Roman (1988). Communism and Nationalism: Karl Marx versus Friedrich List. New York: Oxford University Press.
  • Thum, Gregor (2021). "Seapower and Frontier Settlement: Friedrich List's American Vision for Germany". In Lahti, Janne (ed.). German and United States Colonialism in a Connected World: Entangled Empires. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 17–39.
  • Todd, David (2015). Free Trade and its Enemies in France, 1814–1851. Cambridge University Press. pp. 15, 125 & 146–153.
  • Tribe, Keith (2007). Strategies of Economic Order. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521619431.
  • Wendler, Eugen (2014). Friedrich List (1789-1846): A Visionary Economist with Social Responsibility. Springer.

Articles edit

  • Chang, Ha-Joon (September 2002). "Kicking Away the Ladder: How the Economic and Intellectual Histories of Capitalism Have Been Re-Written to Justify Neo-Liberal Capitalism". Post-Autistic Economics Review (15).
  • Clairmonte, Frederick (February 1959). "Friedrich List and the Historical Concept of Balance Growth". Indian Economic Review. 4 (3): 24–44.
  • Ince, Onur Ulas (2016). "Friedrich List and the Imperial Origins of the National Economy". New Political Economy. 21 (4): 380–400. doi:10.1080/13563467.2016.1115827. S2CID 147126854.
  • Freeman, C. (1995). "The National System of Innovation in Historical Perspective". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 19: 5–24.
  • Helleiner, Eric (2020-11-23). "The Diversity of Economic Nationalism". New Political Economy. 26 (2): 229–238. doi:10.1080/13563467.2020.1841137. ISSN 1356-3467.
  • Levi-Faur, David (1997). "Friedrich List and the Political Economy of the Nation-State". Review of International Political Economy. 4: 154–178. doi:10.1080/096922997347887.
  • Levi-Faur, David (1997). "Economic Nationalism: From Friedrich List to Robert Reich". Review of International Studies. 23 (3): 359–370. doi:10.1017/S0260210597003598. S2CID 145497541.
  • Notz, William (June 1926). "Frederick List in America". The American Economic Review. American Economic Association. 16 (2): 249–265. JSTOR 1805356.
  • Selwyn, B. (2009). "An Historical Materialist Appraisal of Friedrich List and his Modern Day Followers". New Political Economy. 14 (2): 157–180. doi:10.1080/13563460902825965. S2CID 145702401.

External links edit

  • Wikiquote - Quotations From List
  • An unfinished review of The National System of Political Economy written by Karl Marx in 1845 2006-01-06 at the Wayback Machine
  • Newspaper clippings about Friedrich List in the 20th Century Press Archives of the ZBW

friedrich, list, georg, august, 1789, november, 1846, german, american, economist, political, theorist, developed, nationalist, theory, political, economy, both, europe, united, states, forefather, german, historical, school, economics, argued, zollverein, ger. Georg Friedrich List 6 August 1789 30 November 1846 was a German American economist and political theorist who developed the nationalist theory of political economy in both Europe and the United States 1 2 3 4 He was a forefather of the German historical school of economics and argued for the Zollverein a pan German customs union from a nationalist standpoint 5 He advocated raising tariffs on imported goods while supporting free trade of domestic goods and stated the cost of a tariff should be seen as an investment in a nation s future productivity 4 Friedrich ListLithography of List by Josef Kriehuber 1845Born 1789 08 06 6 August 1789Reutlingen Duchy of Wurttemberg Holy Roman EmpireDied30 November 1846 1846 11 30 aged 57 Kufstein County of Tyrol Austrian EmpireNationalityGerman AmericanAcademic careerFieldEconomicsSchool ortraditionHistorical SchoolInfluencesJean Antoine Chaptal Alexander Hamilton Daniel Raymond Adolphe ThiersContributionsNational System of InnovationHistorical school of economicsSignatureList was a political liberal 6 who collaborated with Karl von Rotteck and Carl Theodor Welcker on the Rotteck Welckersches Staatslexikon de an encyclopedia of political science that advocated constitutional liberalism and which influenced the Vormarz 7 At the time in Europe liberal and nationalist ideas were almost inseparably linked and political liberalism was not yet attached to what was later considered economic liberalism 6 8 Emmanuel Todd considers List a forerunner to John Maynard Keynes as a theorist of moderate or regulated capitalism 9 Contents 1 Biography 1 1 Early life 1 2 University of Tubingen 1 3 Move to United States 1825 1830 1 4 Return to Europe 1831 1846 2 Views 2 1 Nationalist view of political economy 2 2 Stages of economic development 2 3 Railways 2 4 Britain and world trade 2 5 Influences 3 Legacy 4 See also 5 Works in English translation 6 References 7 Bibliography 7 1 Books and book chapters 7 2 Articles 8 External linksBiography editEarly life edit List was born in the free imperial city of Reutlingen in the Duchy of Wurttemberg on August 6 1789 10 His father Johannes was a prosperous master tanner and a city official and Georg Friedrich was the second son and youngest child in his family 11 He was educated at the town s Latin School In an apprenticeship at his father s tanning business List showed little interest in manual labor He was apprenticed as a bureaucratic clerk at Blaubeuren 11 After passing his examination he became Taxes and Warehouses Commissioner in Schelklingen 11 University of Tubingen edit At age 23 List was promoted to a post at Tubingen While there he regularly attended lectures at the University of Tubingen and expanded his reading He also made the acquaintance of the future minister Johannes von Schlayer de 11 In 1816 List s position in the bureaucracy was improved as the succession of King William I of Wurttemberg ushered in a period of reform Under minister Karl August von Wangenheim de List rose quickly through the bureaucracy and was made the first Professor of Administration and Politics at the University List had been an advocate for establishing such a position arguing in 1817 No one in our University has any conception of a national economy No one teaches the science of agriculture forestry mining industry or trade T he forms of government are in such a truly barbarous state that if an official of the seventeenth century rose again from the dead he could at once take up his old work though he would assuredly be astonished to find the advances that had been made during the interval in the simplest process of manufacture 12 As a deputy to the Wurttemberg chamber he was active in advocating administrative reforms He was eventually expelled from the chamber and in April 1822 sentenced to ten months imprisonment with hard labor in the fortress of Asperg He escaped to Alsace and after visiting France and England returned in 1824 to finish his sentence and was released on undertaking to emigrate to America Move to United States 1825 1830 edit Arriving in the United States in 1825 he settled in Pennsylvania where he became an extensive landholder 13 He first engaged in farming but soon switched to journalism and edited a German paper in Reading 14 He was active in the establishment of railroads 13 Some argue e g Chang 2002 that it was in America that he gathered from a study of Alexander Hamilton s work the inspiration which made him an economist of his pronounced National System views which found realization in Henry Clay s American System Others deny this Daastol 2011 since he argued for a German customs union already in 1819 when he established the first German union for industry and trade List s ideas on protectionism predate his American sojourn and were influenced by liberal protectionists such as Adolphe Thiers 15 The main theoretical reference approvingly cited by List in his 1827 pamphlet Outlines of American Political Economy in which he defended the doctrine of pragmatic protection and free trade was Jean Antoine Chaptal s De l industrie francaise 1819 14 15 The discovery of coal on some land which he had acquired made him financially independent Return to Europe 1831 1846 edit In 1830 he was appointed United States consul at Hamburg but on his arrival in Europe he found that the Senate had failed to confirm his appointment 14 After residing for some time in Paris he returned to Pennsylvania He next settled in Leipzig in 1833 where for some time he was U S consul He was a journalist in Paris from 1837 to 1843 where he wrote articles for Thiers s centre left paper Le Constitutionnel 15 He wrote several letters for the Augsburg Allgemeine Zeitung which were published in 1841 in a volume under the title of Das nationale System der politischen Oekonomie 14 In 1841 his ill health had led him to decline an offer to edit the Rheinische Zeitung a new Cologne paper of liberal views and Karl Marx took the post 16 In 1843 he established the Zollvereinsblatt in Augsburg a newspaper in which he advocated the enlargement of the customs union German Zollverein and the organization of a national commercial system 13 He strongly advocated the extension of the railway system in Germany The development of the Zollverein to where it unified Germany economically was due largely to his enthusiasm and ardour He visited Austria and Hungary in 1844 14 In 1846 he visited England with a view to forming a commercial alliance between that country and Germany but was unsuccessful 13 His last days were darkened by many misfortunes he lost much of his American property in a financial crisis ill health also overtook him and he killed himself in Kufstein on 30 November 1846 4 Views editThis section needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Friedrich List news newspapers books scholar JSTOR February 2023 Learn how and when to remove this template message This section includes a list of general references but it lacks sufficient corresponding inline citations Please help to improve this section by introducing more precise citations February 2023 Learn how and when to remove this template message Nationalist view of political economy edit nbsp Das nationale System der politischen Okonomie 1930 17 List s theory of national economics differed from the doctrines of individual economics and cosmopolitan economics by Adam Smith and J B Say List argued that Smithian critiques of mercantilism were partly correct but argued for the need for temporary tariff protection targeted to protect specific infant industries that were critical to economic growth 18 List contrasted the economic behaviour of an individual with that of a nation 18 An individual promotes only his own personal interests but a state fosters the welfare of all its citizens An individual may prosper from activities which harm the interests of a nation Slavery may be a public calamity for a country nevertheless some people may do very well in carrying on the slave trade and in holding slaves Likewise activities beneficial to society may injure the interests of certain individuals Canals and railroads may do great good to a nation but all waggoners will complain of this improvement Every new invention has some inconvenience for a number of individuals and is nevertheless a public blessing List argued that although some government action was essential to stimulate the economy an overzealous government might do more harm than good It is bad policy to regulate everything and to promote everything by employing social powers where things may better regulate themselves and can be better promoted by private exertions but it is no less bad policy to let those things alone which can only be promoted by interfering social power Due to the universal union that nations have with their populace List stated that from this political union originates their commercial union and it is in consequence of the perpetual peace thus maintained that commercial union has become so beneficial to them The result of a general free trade would not be a universal republic but on the contrary a universal subjection of the less advanced nations to the predominant manufacturing commercial and naval power is a conclusion for which the reasons are very strong A universal republic i e a union of the nations of the earth whereby they recognise the same conditions of right among themselves and renounce self redress can only be realised if a large number of nationalities attain to as nearly the same degree as possible of industry and civilisation political cultivation and power Only with the gradual formation of this union can free trade be developed only as a result of this union can it confer on all nations the same great advantages which are now experienced by those provinces and states which are politically united The system of protection inasmuch as it forms the only means of placing those nations which are far behind in civilisation on equal terms with the one predominating nation appears to be the most efficient means of furthering the final union of nations and hence also of promoting true freedom of trade 19 In his seventh letter List repeated his assertion that economists should realise that since the human race is divided into independent states a nation would act unwisely to endeavour to promote the welfare of the whole human race at the expense of its particular strength welfare and independence It is a dictate of the law of self preservation to make its particular advancement in power and strength the first principles of its policy A country should not count the cost of defending the overseas trade of its merchants And the manufacturing and agricultural interest must be promoted and protected even by sacrifices of the majority of the individuals if it can be proved that the nation would never acquire the necessary perfection without such protective measures 20 List argued that international trade reduced the security of the states who took part in it 21 List argued that statesmen had two responsibilities one to contemporary society and one to future generations Normally the attention of most leaders is occupied by urgent matters leaving little time to consider future problems But when a country had reached a turning point in its development its leaders were morally obliged to deal with issues that would affect the next generation On the threshold of a new phase in the development of their country statesmen should be prepared to take the long view despite the need to deal also with matters of immediate urgency 22 List s fundamental doctrine was that a nation s true wealth is the full and many sided development of its productive power rather than its current exchange values For example its economic education should be more important than immediate production of value and it might be right that one generation should sacrifice its gain and enjoyment to secure the strength and skill of the future Under normal conditions an economically mature nation should also develop agriculture manufacture and commerce However the last two factors were more important since they better influenced the nation s culture and independence and were especially connected to navigation railways and high technology and a purely agricultural state tended to stagnateHowever List claimed that only countries in temperate regions were adapted to grow higher forms of industry On the other hand tropical regions had a natural monopoly in the production of certain raw materials Thus there were a spontaneous division of labor and a confederation of powers between both groups of countries List contended that Smith s economic system is not an industrial system but a mercantile system and he called it the exchange value system Contrary to Smith he argued that the immediate private interest of individuals would not lead to the highest good of society The nation stood between the individual and humanity and was defined by its language manners historical development culture and constitution The unity must be the first condition of the security well being progress and civilization of the individual Private economic interests like all others must be subordinated to the maintenance completion and strengthening of the nation Stages of economic development edit List theorised that nations of the temperate zone which are furnished with all the necessary conditions naturally pass through stages of economic development in advancing to their normal economic state These are Pastoral life Agriculture Agriculture united with manufactures Agriculture manufactures and commerce are combinedThe progress of the nation through these stages is the task of the state which must create the required conditions for the progress by using legislation and administrative action This view leads to List s scheme of industrial politics Every nation should begin with free trade stimulating and improving its agriculture by trade with richer and more cultivated nations importing foreign manufactures and exporting raw products When it is economically so far advanced that it can manufacture for itself then protection should be used to allow the home industries to develop and save them from being overpowered by the competition of stronger foreign industries in the home market When the national industries have grown strong enough that this competition is not a threat then the highest stage of progress has been reached free trade should again become the rule and the nation be thus thoroughly incorporated with the universal industrial union What a nation loses in exchange during the protective period it more than gains in the long run in productive power The temporary expenditure is analogous to the cost of the industrial education of the individual In a thousand cases the power of the State is compelled to impose restrictions on private industry It prevents the ship owner from taking on board slaves on the west coast of Africa and taking them over to America It imposes regulations as to the building of steamers and the rules of navigation at sea in order that passengers and sailors may not be sacrificed to the avarice and caprice of the captains Everywhere does the State consider it to be its duty to guard the public against danger and loss as in the sale of the necessaries of life so also in the sale of medicines etc 23 Railways edit List was the leading promoter of railways in Germany His proposals on how to start up a system were widely adopted 24 He summed up the advantages to be derived from the development of the railway system in 1841 25 It is a means of national defence it facilitates the concentration distribution and direction of the army It is a means to the improvement of the culture of the nation It brings talent knowledge and skill of every kind readily to market It secures the community against dearth and famine and against excessive fluctuation in the prices of the necessaries of life It promotes the spirit of the nation as it has a tendency to destroy the Philistine spirit arising from isolation and provincial prejudice and vanity It binds nations by ligaments and promotes an interchange of food and of commodities thus making it feel to be a unit The iron rails become a nerve system which on the one hand strengthens public opinion and on the other hand strengthens the power of the state for police and governmental purposes List drew up proposals for a national railway network before the first steam locomotive ran between Nuremberg and Furth He suggested construction of a railway between Leipzig and Dresden which would soon become Germany s first long distance railway He is honored for his early promotion of the importance of railways with a bust in Leipzig main station as well as several streets named after him adjacent to railway stations e g Friedrich List Platz When the Swiss German architect de Martin Machler first proposed what is today Berlin main station in 1917 he suggested the new central interchange station of the German rail network be named in honor of List Britain and world trade edit While List once had urged Germany to join other manufacturing nations of the second rank to check Britain s insular supremacy by 1841 he considered that the United States and Russia would become the most powerful countries citation needed a view also expressed by Alexis de Tocqueville the previous year List hoped to persuade political leaders in England to co operate with Germany to ward off this danger His proposal was perhaps not so far fetched as might appear at first sight In 1844 the writer of an article in a leading review had declared that in every point of view whether politically or commercially we can have no better alliance than that of the German nation spreading as it does its 42 millions of souls without interruption over the surface of central Europe 26 The practical conclusion which List drew for Germany was that it needed for its economic progress an extended and conveniently bounded territory reaching to the seacoast both on north and south and a vigorous expansion of manufacture and trade and that the way to the latter lay through judicious protective legislation with a customs union comprising all German lands and a German marine with a Navigation Act The national German spirit striving after independence and power through union and the national industry awaking from its lethargy and eager to recover lost ground were favorable to the success of List s book and it produced a great sensation He ably represented the tendencies and demands of his time in his own country his work had the effect of fixing the attention not merely of the speculative and official classes but of practical men generally on questions of political economy and his ideas were undoubtedly the economic foundation of modern Germany as applied by the practical genius of Bismarck List considered that Napoleon s Continental System aimed just at damaging Britain during a bitter long term war had in fact been quite good for German industry This was the direct opposite of what was believed by the followers of Adam Smith As List put it I perceived that the popular theory took no account of nations but simply of the entire human race on the one hand or of the single individual on the other I saw clearly that free competition between two nations which are highly civilised can only be mutually beneficial in case both of them are in a nearly equal position of industrial development and that any nation which owing to misfortunes is behind others in industry commerce and navigation must first of all strengthen her own individual powers in order to fit herself to enter into free competition with more advanced nations In a word I perceived the distinction between cosmopolitical and political economy 27 List s argument was that Germany should follow actual English practice rather than the abstractions of Smith s doctrines Had the English left everything to itself Laissez faire laissez aller as the popular economical school recommends the German merchants of the Steelyard would be still carrying on their trade in London the Belgians would be still manufacturing cloth for the English England would have still continued to be the sheep farm of the Hansards just as Portugal became the vineyard of England and has remained so till our days owing to the stratagem of a cunning diplomatist Indeed it is more than probable that without her highly protectionist commercial policy England would never have attained to such a large measure of municipal and individual freedom as she now possesses for such freedom is the daughter of industry and wealth Influences editList s hostility to free trade was first decisively shaped by the ideas of his friend Adolphe Thiers and other liberal protectionists in France 15 He was also later influenced by Alexander Hamilton and the American School rooted in Hamilton s economic principles including Daniel Raymond 28 but also by the general mode of thinking of America s first Treasury Secretary and by his strictures on the doctrine of Adam Smith He opposed the cosmopolitan principle in the contemporary economical system and the absolute doctrine of free trade which was in harmony with that principle and instead developed the infant industry argument to which he had been exposed by Hamilton and Raymond 28 He gave prominence to the national idea and insisted on the special requirements of each nation according to its circumstances and especially to the degree of its development He famously doubted the sincerity of calls to free trade from developed nations in particular Britain Any nation which by means of protective duties and restrictions on navigation has raised her manufacturing power and her navigation to such a degree of development that no other nation can sustain free competition with her can do nothing wiser than to throw away these ladders of her greatness to preach to other nations the benefits of free trade and to declare in penitent tones that she has hitherto wandered in the paths of error and has now for the first time succeeded in discovering the truth 29 His idea of productive powers was influenced by the philosophy of productivity of Friedrich Wilhelm Joseph Schelling 30 31 He was acquainted with Robert Schumann and Heinrich Heine 30 Legacy edit nbsp Memorial statue at the main railway station of LeipzigList s principal work is entitled Das Nationale System der Politischen Okonomie 1841 and was translated into English as The National System of Political Economy Before 1914 List and Marx were the two best known German economists and theorists of development although Marx unlike List devised no policies to promote economic development This book has been more frequently translated than the works of any other German economist except Karl Marx 32 He is credited with influencing Nazism in Germany and his ideas are credited as forming the basis of the European Economic Community 33 In Ireland he influenced Arthur Griffith of Sinn Fein and these theories were used by the Fianna Fail government in the 1930s to instigate protectionism with a view to developing Irish industry Among others he strongly influenced was Sergei Witte the Imperial Russian Minister of Finance 1892 1903 Witte s plan for rapid industrialisation was centred around railroad construction the Trans Siberian railroad for example and a policy of protectionism At the time it was largely considered that Russia was a backward country with an under developed economy The boom which was seen during the 1890s was largely credited to Witte s policy Angus Maddison noted that As Marx was not interested in the survival of the capitalist system he was not really concerned with economic policy except in so far as the labour movement was involved There his argument was concentrated on measures to limit the length of the working day and to strengthen trade union bargaining power His analysis was also largely confined to the situation in the leading capitalist country of his day the UK and he did not consider the policy problems of other Western countries in catching up with the lead country as Friedrich List did In so far as Marx was concerned with other countries it was mainly with poor countries which were victims of Western imperialism in the merchant capitalist era 34 nbsp 1989 Deutsche Bundespost stamp commemorating the 200th anniversary of List s birthHeterodox economists such as Ha Joon Chang and Erik Reinert refer to List often explicitly when writing about suitable economic policies for developing countries List s influence among developing nations has been considerable Japan has followed his model 35 The international economic policy of Meiji Japan was a combination of Hideyoshi s mercantilism and Friedrich List s Nationale System der Politischen Okonomie 36 It has also been argued that Deng Xiaoping s post Mao policies were inspired by List as well as recent policies in India 37 38 China under Deng took on the clear features of a developmental dictatorship under single party auspices The PRC would then belong to a class of regimes familiar to the 20th century that have their ideological sources in classical Marxism but better reflect the developmental nationalist views of Friedrich List 39 A 1943 German film The Endless Road portrayed List s life and achievements He was played by Eugen Klopfer See also edit nbsp Wikimedia Commons has media related to Friedrich List nbsp Wikiquote has quotations related to Friedrich List Abraham Lincoln Contributions to liberal theory Economic interventionism Economic patriotism Henry Charles Carey Siegfried Moltke a biographer of List sWorks in English translation edit The National System of Political Economy References edit Freeman 1995 Helleiner 2020 Helleiner 2021 a b c Friedrich List at the Encyclopaedia Britannica Tribe 2007 p 36 a b Hagemann amp Wendler 2018 pp 58 62 Wendler 2014 pp 12 135 137 Walther Rudolf 1984 Economic Liberalism Economy and Society 13 2 178 207 doi 10 1080 03085148300000019 Wendler 2014 p 220 Hirst 1909 p 1 a b c d Hirst 1909 pp 2 4 Hirst 1909 p 8 a b c d Wilson J G Fiske J eds 1892 List Friedrich Appletons Cyclopaedia of American Biography New York D Appleton a b c d e Gilman D C Peck H T Colby F M eds 1905 List Friedrich New International Encyclopedia 1st ed New York Dodd Mead a b c d Todd 2015 pp 15 125 146 153 Henderson 1983 p 85 Originally published in 1841 at Stuttgart Tubingen a b Helleiner Eric 2023 Bukovansky Mlada Keene Edward Reus Smit Christian Spanu Maja eds Regulating Commerce The Oxford Handbook of History and International Relations Oxford University Press pp 334 C23P112 doi 10 1093 oxfordhb 9780198873457 013 22 ISBN 978 0 19 887345 7 National System of Political Economy Friedrich List p 102 3 National System of Political Economy Friedrich List p 150 Brooks 2005 pp 1 2 The German Zollverein in the Edinburgh Review 1844 p 117 Friedrich List National System of Political Economy p 166 Nipperdey 1996 p 165 List quoted in John J Lalor ed Cyclopaedia of Political Science 1881 3 118 The German Zollverein in the Edinburgh Review 1844 Vol LXXIX pp 105 et seq The National System of Political Economy by Friedrich List 1841 translated by Sampson S Lloyd M P 1885 edition Author s Preface Page xxvi a b Chang 2002 The National System of Political Economy by Friedrich List 1841 translated by Sampson S Lloyd M P 1885 edition Fourth Book The Politics Chapter 33 a b Heuser 2008 Heuser 1986 Henderson 1983 Makes of nineteenth century culture 1800 1914 Justin Wintle Routledge p 367 Accessed January 27 2010 Dynamic forces in Capitalist Development A Long Run Comparative View by Angus Maddison Oxford University Press 1991 page 19 List s influence on Japanese economic policy see A contrary view How the World Works Archived 2006 01 17 at the Wayback Machine by James Fallows Linebarger Chu amp Burks 1954 p 326 Clairmonte 1959 Boianovsky 2011 p 2 A James Gregor Precis No 16 PS 137b Revolutionary Movements Marxism and Fascism in East Asia Course Notes 29 March 2005 Archived link accessed 10 August 2014 nbsp This article incorporates text from a publication now in the public domain Chisholm Hugh ed 1911 List Friedrich Encyclopaedia Britannica 11th ed Cambridge University Press Bibliography editBooks and book chapters edit Anonymous 1877 Fr List ein Vorlaufer und ein Opfer fur das Vaterland Friederich List a Forerunner and a Sacrifice for the Fatherland Vol II Stuttgart a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint location missing publisher link Boianovsky Mauro 2011 Friedrich List and the Economic Fate of Tropical Countries PDF Universidade de Brasilia dissertation Bolsinger Eckard 2004 The Foundation of Mercantile Realism Friedrich List and International Political Economy PDF 54th Political Studies Association Annual Conference Archived from the original PDF on 2008 06 26 Brooks Stephen G 2005 Producing Security Multinational Corporations Globalization and the Changing Calculus of Conflict Princeton University Press ISBN 978 0 691 13031 6 JSTOR j ctt7sjz7 Borchardt Knut Schotz Hans Otto eds 1991 Wirtschaftspolitik in der Krise Die Geheim Konferenz der Friedrich List Gesellschaft im Sept 1931 uber Moglichkeiten und Folgen einer Kreditausweitung Economic Policy in Crisis The Secret Conference of the Friedrich List Society in September 1931 on the Possibilities and Consequences of Credit Expansion Baden Baden Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft Brugelmann Hermann 1956 Politische Okonomie in kritischen Jahren Die Friedrich List Gesellschaft E V von 1925 1935 Political Economy in Critical Years The Friedrich List Society from 1925 1935 Tubingen Mohr Siebeck Daastol Arno Mong 2011 Friedrich List s Heart Wit and Will Mental Capital as the Productive Force of Progress PDF Erfurt a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint location missing publisher link doctoral dissertation Goldschmidt Friedrich 1878 Friedrich List Deutschlands grosser Volkswirth Friedrich List Germany s Greater National Economy in German Berlin J Springer OCLC 797286817 Hagemann Harald Wendler Eugen 2018 The Economic Thought of Friedrich List Routledge pp 58 62 Helleiner Eric 2021 The Neomercantilists A Global Intellectual History Cornell University Press ISBN 978 1 5017 6014 3 Henderson William O 1983 Friedrich List Economist and Visionary 1789 1846 London Frank Cass ISBN 9780714631615 Hirst Margaret E 1909 Life of Friedrich List London a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint location missing publisher link containing a bibliography and a reprint of List s Petition on Behalf of the Handelsverein to the Federal Assembly 1819 Outlines of American Political Economy 1827 Philadelphia Speech 1827 to the Harrisburg Convention and the Introduction to The National System of Political Economy 1841 Heuser Marie Luise 2008 Romantik und Gesellschaft Die Theorie der produktiven Krafte Romance and Society The Theory of Productive Forces In Gerhard Myriam ed Oldenburger Jahrbuch fur Philosophie 2007 Oldenburg Yearbook for Philosophy 2007 pp 253 277 ISBN 978 3 8142 2101 4 Heuser Marie Luise 1986 Die Produktivitat der Natur Schellings Naturphilosophie und das neue Paradigma der Selbstorganisation in den Naturwissenschaften Berlin Duncker amp Humblot ISBN 3 428 06079 2 Jentsch Carl 1901 Friedrich List in German Berlin Ernst Hofmann and Co Linebarger Paul M A Chu Chu Burks Ardath W 1954 Far Eastern Governments and Politics China and Japan 2nd ed Princeton NJ D Van Nostrand Nipperdey Thomas 1996 Germany from Napoleon to Bismarck Szporluk Roman 1988 Communism and Nationalism Karl Marx versus Friedrich List New York Oxford University Press Thum Gregor 2021 Seapower and Frontier Settlement Friedrich List s American Vision for Germany In Lahti Janne ed German and United States Colonialism in a Connected World Entangled Empires Cham Palgrave Macmillan pp 17 39 Todd David 2015 Free Trade and its Enemies in France 1814 1851 Cambridge University Press pp 15 125 amp 146 153 Tribe Keith 2007 Strategies of Economic Order Cambridge University Press ISBN 9780521619431 Wendler Eugen 2014 Friedrich List 1789 1846 A Visionary Economist with Social Responsibility Springer Articles edit Chang Ha Joon September 2002 Kicking Away the Ladder How the Economic and Intellectual Histories of Capitalism Have Been Re Written to Justify Neo Liberal Capitalism Post Autistic Economics Review 15 Clairmonte Frederick February 1959 Friedrich List and the Historical Concept of Balance Growth Indian Economic Review 4 3 24 44 Ince Onur Ulas 2016 Friedrich List and the Imperial Origins of the National Economy New Political Economy 21 4 380 400 doi 10 1080 13563467 2016 1115827 S2CID 147126854 Freeman C 1995 The National System of Innovation in Historical Perspective Cambridge Journal of Economics 19 5 24 Helleiner Eric 2020 11 23 The Diversity of Economic Nationalism New Political Economy 26 2 229 238 doi 10 1080 13563467 2020 1841137 ISSN 1356 3467 Levi Faur David 1997 Friedrich List and the Political Economy of the Nation State Review of International Political Economy 4 154 178 doi 10 1080 096922997347887 Levi Faur David 1997 Economic Nationalism From Friedrich List to Robert Reich Review of International Studies 23 3 359 370 doi 10 1017 S0260210597003598 S2CID 145497541 Notz William June 1926 Frederick List in America The American Economic Review American Economic Association 16 2 249 265 JSTOR 1805356 Selwyn B 2009 An Historical Materialist Appraisal of Friedrich List and his Modern Day Followers New Political Economy 14 2 157 180 doi 10 1080 13563460902825965 S2CID 145702401 External links edit nbsp Wikimedia Commons has media related to Friedrich List A Comparison Of List Marx and Adam Smith Quotations From List Wikiquote Quotations From List Union Europe List s vision of a peaceful union An unfinished review of The National System of Political Economy written by Karl Marx in 1845 Archived 2006 01 06 at the Wayback Machine Newspaper clippings about Friedrich List in the 20th Century Press Archives of the ZBW Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Friedrich List amp oldid 1180182522, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.