fbpx
Wikipedia

Principal–agent problem

The principal–agent problem refers to the conflict in interests and priorities that arises when one person or entity (the "agent") takes actions on behalf of another person or entity (the "principal").[1] The problem worsens when there is a greater discrepancy of interests and information between the principal and agent, as well as when the principal lacks the means to punish the agent.[2] The deviation from the principal's interest by the agent is called "agency costs".[3]

Basic idea of agency theory

Common examples of this relationship include corporate management (agent) and shareholders (principal), elected officials (agent) and citizens (principal), or brokers (agent) and markets (buyers and sellers, principals).[4] In all these cases, the principal has to be concerned with whether the agent is acting in the best interest of the principal. Principal-agent models typically either examine moral hazard (hidden actions) or adverse selection (hidden information).[5]

The principal–agent problem typically arises where the two parties have different interests and asymmetric information (the agent having more information), such that the principal cannot directly ensure that the agent is always acting in the principal's best interest, particularly when activities that are useful to the principal are costly to the agent, and where elements of what the agent does are costly for the principal to observe.

The agency problem can be intensified when an agent acts on behalf of multiple principals (see multiple principal problem).[6][7] When multiple principals have to agree on the agent's objectives, they face a collective action problem in governance, as individual principals may lobby the agent or otherwise act in their individual interests rather than in the collective interest of all principals.[8] The multiple principal problem is particularly serious in the public sector.[6][9][10]

Various mechanisms may be used to align the interests of the agent with those of the principal. In employment, employers (principal) may use piece rates/commissions, profit sharing, efficiency wages, performance measurement (including financial statements), the agent posting a bond, or the threat of termination of employment to align worker interests with their own.

Overview edit

The principal's interests are expected to be pursued by the agent however, when their interests differ, a dilemma arises. The agent possesses resources such as time, information and expertise that the principal lacks. But at the same time, the principal does not have entire control over the agent's ability to act in their best interests. In this situation, the theory posits that the agent's activities are diverted from following the principal's interests and instead drive them to maximize their personal advantage. For example, in case of a dual sequence of relationships, the citizens or voters count on the politicians that they elected to fulfill their duties by structuring a system in which their healthcare and financial safety is guaranteed. Each citizen is a cog in the society machine and if everyone was overlooking the functioning of each and every entity in the system, society would never develop. However, at the same time, the minister of health cannot be overlooking each and every operation being done at the internal level of each public entity, bureaucrats are in charge of running those institutions. However, when the seed of corruption is planted, the whole system is disrupted as the agent is no longer pursuing the interest of the principal.[11]

The principal and agent theory emerged in the 1970s from the combined disciplines of economics and institutional theory. There is some contention as to who originated the theory, with theorists Stephen Ross and Barry Mitnick both claiming authorship.[12] Ross is said to have originally described the dilemma in terms of a person choosing a flavor of ice-cream for someone whose tastes they does not know (Ibid). The most cited reference to the theory, however, comes from Michael C. Jensen and William Meckling.[13] The theory has come to extend well beyond economics or institutional studies to all contexts of information asymmetry, uncertainty and risk.

In the context of law, principals do not know enough about whether (or to what extent) a contract has been satisfied, and they end up with agency costs. The solution to this information problem—closely related to the moral hazard problem—is to ensure the provision of appropriate incentives so agents act in the way principals wish.

In terms of game theory, it involves changing the rules of the game so that the self-interested rational choices of the agent coincide with what the principal desires. Even in the limited arena of employment contracts, the difficulty of doing this in practice is reflected in a multitude of compensation mechanisms and supervisory schemes, as well as in critique of such mechanisms as e.g., Deming (1986) expresses in his Seven Deadly Diseases of management.

Employment contract edit

In the context of the employment contract, individual contracts form a major method of restructuring incentives, by connecting as closely as optimal the information available about employee performance, and the compensation for that performance. Because of differences in the quantity and quality of information available about the performance of individual employees, the ability of employees to bear risk, and the ability of employees to manipulate evaluation methods, the structural details of individual contracts vary widely, including such mechanisms as "piece rates, [share] options, discretionary bonuses, promotions, profit sharing, efficiency wages, deferred compensation, and so on."[14] Typically, these mechanisms are used in the context of different types of employment: salesmen often receive some or all of their remuneration as commission, production workers are usually paid an hourly wage, while office workers are typically paid monthly or semimonthly (and if paid overtime, typically at a higher rate than the hourly rate implied by the salary).[citation needed] The way in which these mechanisms are used is different in the two parts of the economy which Doeringer and Piore called the "primary" and "secondary" sectors (see also dual labour market).

The secondary sector is characterised by short-term employment relationships, little or no prospect of internal promotion, and the determination of wages primarily by market forces. In terms of occupations, it consists primarily of low or unskilled jobs, whether they are blue-collar (manual-labour), white-collar (e.g., filing clerks), or service jobs (e.g., waiters). These jobs are linked by the fact that they are characterized by "low skill levels, low earnings, easy entry, job impermanence, and low returns to education or experience." In a number of service jobs, such as food service, golf caddying, and valet parking jobs, workers in some countries are paid mostly or entirely with tips.

The use of tipping is a strategy on the part of the owners or managers to align the interests of the service workers with those of the owners or managers; the service workers have an incentive to provide good customer service (thus benefiting the company's business), because this makes it more likely that they will get a good tip.

The issue of tipping is sometimes discussed in connection with the principal–agent theory. "Examples of principals and agents include bosses and employees ... [and] diners and waiters." "The "principal–agent problem", as it is known in economics, crops up any time agents aren't inclined to do what principals want them to do. To sway them [(agents)], principals have to make it worth the agents' while ... [in the restaurant context,] the better the diner's experience, the bigger the waiter's tip."[15] "In the ... language of the economist, the tip serves as a way to reduce what is known as the classic "principal–agent" problem." According to "Videbeck, a researcher at the New Zealand Institute for the Study of Competition and Regulation[,] '[i]n theory, tipping can lead to an efficient match between workers' attitudes to service and the jobs they perform. It is a means to make people work hard. Friendly waiters will go that extra mile, earn their tip, and earn a relatively high income...[On the other hand,] if tipless wages are sufficiently low, then grumpy waiters might actually choose to leave the industry and take jobs that would better suit their personalities.'"[16]

As a solution to the principal–agent problem, though, tipping is not perfect. In the hopes of getting a larger tip, a server, for example, may be inclined to give a customer an extra large glass of wine or a second scoop of ice cream. While these larger servings make the customer happy and increase the likelihood of the server getting a good tip, they cut into the profit margin of the restaurant. In addition, a server may dote on generous tippers while ignoring other customers, and in rare cases harangue bad tippers.

Non-financial compensation edit

Part of this variation in incentive structures and supervisory mechanisms may be attributable to variation in the level of intrinsic psychological satisfaction to be had from different types of work. Sociologists and psychologists frequently argue that individuals take a certain degree of pride in their work, and that introducing performance-related pay can destroy this "psycho-social compensation", because the exchange relation between employer and employee becomes much more narrowly economic, destroying most or all of the potential for social exchange. Evidence for this is inconclusive—Deci (1971), and Lepper, Greene and Nisbett (1973) find support for this argument; Staw (1989) suggests other interpretations of the findings.

Incentive structures as mentioned above can be provided through non-monetary recognition such as acknowledgements and compliments on an employee (agent) in place of employment. Research conducted by Crifo and Diaye (2004) [17] mentioned that agents who receive compensations such as praises, acknowledgement and recognition help to define intrinsic motivations that increase performance output from the agents thus benefiting the principal.

Furthermore, the studies provided a conclusive remark that intrinsic motivation can be increased by utilising the use of non-monetary compensations that provide acknowledgement for the agent. These higher rewards, can provide a principal with the adequate methodologies to improve the effort inputs of the agent when looking at the principal agent theory through an employer vs employee level of conduct.

Team production edit

On a related note, Drago and Garvey (1997) use Australian survey data to show that when agents are placed on individual pay-for-performance schemes, they are less likely to help their coworkers. This negative effect is particularly important in those jobs that involve strong elements of "team production" (Alchian and Demsetz 1972), where output reflects the contribution of many individuals, and individual contributions cannot be easily identified, and compensation is therefore based largely on the output of the team. In other words, pay-for-performance increases the incentives to free-ride, as there are large positive externalities to the efforts of an individual team member, and low returns to the individual (Holmström 1982, McLaughlin 1994).

The negative incentive effects implied are confirmed by some empirical studies, (e.g., Newhouse, 1973) for shared medical practices; costs rise and doctors work fewer hours as more revenue is shared. Leibowitz and Tollison (1980) find that larger law partnerships typically result in worse cost containment. As a counter, peer pressure can potentially solve the problem (Kandel and Lazear 1992), but this depends on peer monitoring being relatively costless to the individuals doing the monitoring/censuring in any particular instance (unless one brings in social considerations of norms and group identity and so on). Studies suggest that profit-sharing, for example, typically raises productivity by 3–5% (Jones and Kato 1995, Knez and Simester 2001), although there are some selection issues (Prendergast).

Empirical evidence edit

There is however considerable empirical evidence of a positive effect of compensation on performance (although the studies usually involve "simple" jobs where aggregate measures of performance are available, which is where piece rates should be most effective). In one study, Lazear (1996) saw productivity rising by 44% (and wages by 10%) in a change from salary to piece rates, with a half of the productivity gain due to worker selection effects. Research shows that pay for performance increases performance when the task at hand is more repetitive, and reduces performance when the task at hand requires more creative thinking.[18]

Furthermore,[19] formulated from their studies that compensation tend to have an impact on performance as a result of risk aversion and the level of work that a CEO is willing to input. This showed that when the CEO returned less effort then the data correlated a pay level of neutral aversion based on incentives. However, when offered incentives the data correlated a spike in performance as a direct result.

Conclusively, their studies indicated business owner (principal) and business employees (agents) must find a middle ground which coincides with an adequate shared profit for the company that is proportional to CEO pay and performance. In doing this risk aversion of employee efforts being low can be avoided pre-emptively.

  • Paarsch and Shearer (1996) also find evidence supportive of incentive and productivity effects from piece rates, as do Banker, Lee, and Potter (1996), although the latter do not distinguish between incentive and worker selection effects.
  • Rutherford, Springer and Yavas (2005) find evidence of agency problems in residential real estate by showing that real estate agents sell their own houses at a price premium of approximately 4.5% compared to their clients' houses.
  • Fernie and Metcalf (1996) find that top British jockeys perform significantly better when offered percentage of prize money for winning races compared to being on fixed retainers.
  • McMillan, Whalley and Zhu (1989) and Groves et al. (1994) look at Chinese agricultural and industrial data respectively and find significant incentive effects.
  • Kahn and Sherer (1990)find that better evaluations of white-collar office workers were achieved by those employees who had a steeper relation between evaluations and pay.
  • Nikkinen and Sahlström (2004) find empirical evidence that agency theory can be used, at least to some extent, to explain financial audit fees internationally.
  • There is very little correlation between performance pay of CEOs and the success of the companies they manage.[20]

Contract design edit

Milgrom and Roberts (1992) identify four principles of contract design: When perfect information is not available, Holmström (1979)[21] developed the Informativeness Principle to solve this problem. This essentially states that any measure of performance that (on the margin) reveals information about the effort level chosen by the agent should be included in the compensation contract. This includes, for example, Relative Performance Evaluation—measurement relative to other, similar agents, so as to filter out some common background noise factors, such as fluctuations in demand. By removing some exogenous sources of randomness in the agent's income, a greater proportion of the fluctuation in the agent's income falls under their control, increasing their ability to bear risk. If taken advantage of, by greater use of piece rates, this should improve incentives. (In terms of the simple linear model below, this means that increasing x produces an increase in b.)

However, setting incentives as intense as possible is not necessarily optimal from the point of view of the employer. The Incentive-Intensity Principle states that the optimal intensity of incentives depends on four factors: the incremental profits created by additional effort, the precision with which the desired activities are assessed, the agent's risk tolerance, and the agent's responsiveness to incentives. According to Prendergast (1999, 8), "the primary constraint on [performance-related pay] is that [its] provision imposes additional risk on workers ..." A typical result of the early principal–agent literature was that piece rates tend to 100% (of the compensation package) as the worker becomes more able to handle risk, as this ensures that workers fully internalize the consequences of their costly actions. In incentive terms, where we conceive of workers as self-interested rational individuals who provide costly effort (in the most general sense of the worker's input to the firm's production function), the more compensation varies with effort, the better the incentives for the worker to produce.

The third principle—the Monitoring Intensity Principle—is complementary to the second, in that situations in which the optimal intensity of incentives is high corresponds highly to situations in which the optimal level of monitoring is also high. Thus employers effectively choose from a "menu" of monitoring/incentive intensities. This is because monitoring is a costly means of reducing the variance of employee performance, which makes more difference to profits in the kinds of situations where it is also optimal to make incentives intense.

The fourth principle is the Equal Compensation Principle, which essentially states that activities equally valued by the employer should be equally valuable (in terms of compensation, including non-financial aspects such as pleasantness of the workplace) to the employee. This relates to the problem that employees may be engaged in several activities, and if some of these are not monitored or are monitored less heavily, these will be neglected, as activities with higher marginal returns to the employee are favoured. This can be thought of as a kind of "disintermediation"—targeting certain measurable variables may cause others to suffer. For example, teachers being rewarded by test scores of their students are likely to tend more towards teaching 'for the test', and de-emphasise less relevant but perhaps equally or more important aspects of education; while AT&T's practice at one time of paying programmers by the number of lines of code written resulted in programs that were longer than necessary—i.e., program efficiency suffering (Prendergast 1999, 21). Following Holmström and Milgrom (1990) and Baker (1992), this has become known as "multi-tasking" (where a subset of relevant tasks is rewarded, non-rewarded tasks suffer relative neglect). Because of this, the more difficult it is to completely specify and measure the variables on which reward is to be conditioned, the less likely that performance-related pay will be used: "in essence, complex jobs will typically not be evaluated through explicit contracts." (Prendergast 1999, 9).

Where explicit measures are used, they are more likely to be some kind of aggregate measure, for example, baseball and American Football players are rarely rewarded on the many specific measures available (e.g., number of home runs), but frequently receive bonuses for aggregate performance measures such as Most Valuable Player. The alternative to objective measures is subjective performance evaluation, typically by supervisors. However, there is here a similar effect to "multi-tasking", as workers shift effort from that subset of tasks which they consider useful and constructive, to that subset which they think gives the greatest appearance of being useful and constructive, and more generally to try to curry personal favour with supervisors. (One can interpret this as a destruction of organizational social capital—workers identifying with, and actively working for the benefit of, the firm – in favour of the creation of personal social capital—the individual-level social relations which enable workers to get ahead ("networking").)

Linear model edit

The four principles can be summarized in terms of the simplest (linear) model of incentive compensation:

 

where w (wage) is equal to a (the base salary) plus b (the intensity of incentives provided to the employee) times the sum of three terms: e (unobserved employee effort) plus x (unobserved exogenous effects on outcomes) plus the product of g (the weight given to observed exogenous effects on outcomes) and y (observed exogenous effects on outcomes). b is the slope of the relationship between compensation and outcomes.

 

The above discussion on explicit measures assumed that contracts would create the linear incentive structures summarised in the model above. But while the combination of normal errors and the absence of income effects yields linear contracts, many observed contracts are nonlinear. To some extent this is due to income effects as workers rise up a tournament/hierarchy: "Quite simply, it may take more money to induce effort from the rich than from the less well off." (Prendergast 1999, 50). Similarly, the threat of being fired creates a nonlinearity in wages earned versus performance. Moreover, many empirical studies illustrate inefficient behaviour arising from nonlinear objective performance measures, or measures over the course of a long period (e.g., a year), which create nonlinearities in time due to discounting behaviour. This inefficient behaviour arises because incentive structures are varying: for example, when a worker has already exceeded a quota or has no hope of reaching it, versus being close to reaching it—e.g., Healy (1985), Oyer (1997), Leventis (1997). Leventis shows that New York surgeons, penalised for exceeding a certain mortality rate, take less risky cases as they approach the threshold. Courty and Marshke (1997) provide evidence on incentive contracts offered to agencies, which receive bonuses on reaching a quota of graduated trainees within a year. This causes them to 'rush-graduate' trainees in order to make the quota.

Options framework edit

In certain cases agency problems may be analysed by applying the techniques developed for financial options, as applied via a real options framework.[22][23] Stockholders and bondholders have different objective—for instance, stockholders have an incentive to take riskier projects than bondholders do, and to pay more out in dividends than bondholders would like. At the same time, since equity may be seen as a call option on the value of the firm, an increase in the variance in the firm value, other things remaining equal, will lead to an increase in the value of equity, and stockholders may therefore take risky projects with negative net present values, which while making them better off, may make the bondholders worse off. See Option pricing approaches under Business valuation for further discussion. Nagel and Purnanandam (2017) notice that since bank assets are risky debt claims, bank equity resembles a subordinated debt and therefore the stock's payoff is truncated by the difference between the face values of the corporation debt and of the bank deposits.[24] Based on this observation, Peleg-Lazar and Raviv (2017) show that in contrast to the classical agent theory of Michael C. Jensen and William Meckling, an increase in variance would not lead to an increase in the value of equity if the bank's debtor is solvent.[25]

Performance evaluation edit

Objective edit

The major problem in measuring employee performance in cases where it is difficult to draw a straightforward connection between performance and profitability is the setting of a standard by which to judge the performance. One method of setting an absolute objective performance standard—rarely used because it is costly and only appropriate for simple repetitive tasks—is time-and-motion studies, which study in detail how fast it is possible to do a certain task. These have been used constructively in the past, particularly in manufacturing. More generally, however, even within the field of objective performance evaluation, some form of relative performance evaluation must be used. Typically this takes the form of comparing the performance of a worker to that of his peers in the firm or industry, perhaps taking account of different exogenous circumstances affecting that.

The reason that employees are often paid according to hours of work rather than by direct measurement of results is that it is often more efficient to use indirect systems of controlling the quantity and quality of effort, due to a variety of informational and other issues (e.g., turnover costs, which determine the optimal minimum length of relationship between firm and employee). This means that methods such as deferred compensation and structures such as tournaments are often more suitable to create the incentives for employees to contribute what they can to output over longer periods (years rather than hours). These represent "pay-for-performance" systems in a looser, more extended sense, as workers who consistently work harder and better are more likely to be promoted (and usually paid more), compared to the narrow definition of "pay-for-performance", such as piece rates. This discussion has been conducted almost entirely for self-interested rational individuals. In practice, however, the incentive mechanisms which successful firms use take account of the socio-cultural context they are embedded in (Fukuyama 1995, Granovetter 1985), in order not to destroy the social capital they might more constructively mobilise towards building an organic, social organization, with the attendant benefits from such things as "worker loyalty and pride (...) [which] can be critical to a firm's success ..." (Sappington 1991,63)

Subjective edit

Subjective performance evaluation allows the use of a subtler, more balanced assessment of employee performance, and is typically used for more complex jobs where comprehensive objective measures are difficult to specify and/or measure. Whilst often the only feasible method, the attendant problems with subjective performance evaluation have resulted in a variety of incentive structures and supervisory schemes. One problem, for example, is that supervisors may under-report performance in order to save on wages, if they are in some way residual claimants, or perhaps rewarded on the basis of cost savings. This tendency is of course to some extent offset by the danger of retaliation and/or demotivation of the employee, if the supervisor is responsible for that employee's output.

Another problem relates to what is known as the "compression of ratings". Two related influences—centrality bias, and leniency bias—have been documented (Landy and Farr 1980, Murphy and Cleveland 1991). The former results from supervisors being reluctant to distinguish critically between workers (perhaps for fear of destroying team spirit), while the latter derives from supervisors being averse to offering poor ratings to subordinates, especially where these ratings are used to determine pay, not least because bad evaluations may be demotivating rather than motivating. However, these biases introduce noise into the relationship between pay and effort, reducing the incentive effect of performance-related pay. Milkovich and Wigdor (1991) suggest that this is the reason for the common separation of evaluations and pay, with evaluations primarily used to allocate training.

Finally, while the problem of compression of ratings originates on the supervisor-side, related effects occur when workers actively attempt to influence the appraisals supervisors give, either by influencing the performance information going to the supervisor: multitasking (focussing on the more visibly productive activities—Paul 1992), or by working "too hard" to signal worker quality or create a good impression (Holmström 1982); or by influencing the evaluation of it, e.g., by "currying influence" (Milgrom and Roberts 1988) or by outright bribery (Tirole 1992).

Incentive structures edit

Tournaments edit

Much of the discussion here has been in terms of individual pay-for-performance contracts; but many large firms use internal labour markets (Doeringer and Piore 1971, Rosen 1982) as a solution to some of the problems outlined. Here, there is "pay-for-performance" in a looser sense over a longer time period. There is little variation in pay within grades, and pay increases come with changes in job or job title (Gibbs and Hendricks 1996). The incentive effects of this structure are dealt with in what is known as "tournament theory" (Lazear and Rosen 1981, Green and Stokey (1983), see Rosen (1986) for multi-stage tournaments in hierarchies where it is explained why CEOs are paid many times more than other workers in the firm). See the superstar article for more information on the tournament theory.

Workers are motivated to supply effort by the wage increase they would earn if they win a promotion. Some of the extended tournament models predict that relatively weaker agents, be they competing in a sports tournaments (Becker and Huselid 1992, in NASCAR racing) or in the broiler chicken industry (Knoeber and Thurman 1994), would take risky actions instead of increasing their effort supply as a cheap way to improve the prospects of winning.

These actions are inefficient as they increase risk taking without increasing the average effort supplied. Neilson (2007) further added to this from his studies which indicated that when two employees competed to win in a tournament they have a higher chance of bending and or breaking the rules to win. Nelson (2007) also indicated that when the larger the price (incentive) the more inclined the agent (employee in this case) is to increase their effort parameter from Neilson's studies.[26]

A major problem with tournaments is that individuals are rewarded based on how well they do relative to others. Co-workers might become reluctant to help out others and might even sabotage others' effort instead of increasing their own effort (Lazear 1989, Rob and Zemsky 1997). This is supported empirically by Drago and Garvey (1997). Why then are tournaments so popular? Firstly, because—especially given compression rating problems—it is difficult to determine absolutely differences in worker performance. Tournaments merely require rank order evaluation.

Secondly, it reduces the danger of rent-seeking, because bonuses paid to favourite workers are tied to increased responsibilities in new jobs, and supervisors will suffer if they do not promote the most qualified person. This effectively takes the factors of ambiguity away from the principal agent problem by ensuring that the agent acts in the best interest of the principal but also ensures that the quality of work done is of an optimal level.

Thirdly, where prize structures are (relatively) fixed, it reduces the possibility of the firm reneging on paying wages. As Carmichael (1983) notes, a prize structure represents a degree of commitment, both to absolute and to relative wage levels. Lastly when the measurement of workers' productivity is difficult, e.g., say monitoring is costly, or when the tasks the workers have to perform for the job is varied in nature, making it hard to measure effort and/or performance, then running tournaments in a firm would encourage the workers to supply effort whereas workers would have shirked if there are no promotions.

Tournaments also promote risk seeking behavior. In essence, the compensation scheme becomes more like a call option on performance (which increases in value with increased volatility (cf. options pricing). If you are one of ten players competing for the asymmetrically large top prize, you may benefit from reducing the expected value of your overall performance to the firm in order to increase your chance that you have an outstanding performance (and win the prize). In moderation this can offset the greater risk aversion of agents vs principals because their social capital is concentrated in their employer while in the case of public companies the principal typically owns its stake as part of a diversified portfolio. Successful innovation is particularly dependent on employees' willingness to take risks. In cases with extreme incentive intensity, this sort of behavior can create catastrophic organizational failure. If the principal owns the firm as part of a diversified portfolio this may be a price worth paying for the greater chance of success through innovation elsewhere in the portfolio. If however the risks taken are systematic and cannot be diversified e.g., exposure to general housing prices, then such failures will damage the interests of principals and even the economy as a whole. (cf. Kidder Peabody, Barings, Enron, AIG to name a few). Ongoing periodic catastrophic organizational failure is directly incentivized by tournament and other superstar/winner-take-all compensation systems (Holt 1995).

Deferred compensation edit

Tournaments represent one way of implementing the general principle of "deferred compensation", which is essentially an agreement between worker and firm to commit to each other. Under schemes of deferred compensation, workers are overpaid when old, at the cost of being underpaid when young. Salop and Salop (1976) argue that this derives from the need to attract workers more likely to stay at the firm for longer periods, since turnover is costly. Alternatively, delays in evaluating the performance of workers may lead to compensation being weighted to later periods, when better and poorer workers have to a greater extent been distinguished. (Workers may even prefer to have wages increasing over time, perhaps as a method of forced saving, or as an indicator of personal development. e.g., Loewenstein and Sicherman 1991, Frank and Hutchens 1993.) For example, Akerlof and Katz 1989: if older workers receive efficiency wages, younger workers may be prepared to work for less in order to receive those later. Overall, the evidence suggests the use of deferred compensation (e.g., Freeman and Medoff 1984, and Spilerman 1986—seniority provisions are often included in pay, promotion and retention decisions, irrespective of productivity.)

Energy consumption edit

The "principal–agent problem" has also been discussed in the context of energy consumption by Jaffe and Stavins in 1994. They were attempting to catalog market and non-market barriers to energy efficiency adoption. In efficiency terms, a market failure arises when a technology which is both cost-effective and saves energy is not implemented. Jaffe and Stavins describe the common case of the landlord-tenant problem with energy issues as a principal–agent problem. "[I]f the potential adopter is not the party that pays the energy bill, then good information in the hands of the potential adopter may not be sufficient for optimal diffusion; adoption will only occur if the adopter can recover the investment from the party that enjoys the energy savings. Thus, if it is difficult for the possessor of information to convey it credibly to the party that benefits from reduced energy use, a principal/agent problem arises."[27]

The energy efficiency use of the principal agent terminology is in fact distinct from the usual one in several ways. In landlord/tenant or more generally equipment-purchaser/energy-bill-payer situations, it is often difficult to describe who would be the principal and who the agent. Is the agent the landlord and the principal the tenant, because the landlord is "hired" by the tenant through the payment of rent? As Murtishaw and Sathaye, 2006 point out, "In the residential sector, the conceptual definition of principal and agent must be stretched beyond a strictly literal definition."

Another distinction is that the principal agent problem in energy efficiency does not require any information asymmetry: both the landlord and the tenant may be aware of the overall costs and benefits of energy-efficient investments, but as long as the landlord pays for the equipment and the tenant pays the energy bills, the investment in new, energy-efficient appliances will not be made. In this case, there is also little incentive for the tenant to make a capital efficiency investment with a usual payback time of several years, and which in the end will revert to the landlord as property. Since energy consumption is determined both by technology and by behavior, an opposite principal agent problem arises when the energy bills are paid by the landlord, leaving the tenant with no incentive to moderate her energy use. This is often the case for leased office space, for example.

The energy efficiency principal agent problem applies in many cases to rented buildings and apartments, but arises in other circumstances, most often involving relatively high up-front costs for energy-efficient technology. Though it is challenging to assess exactly, the principal agent problem is considered to be a major barrier to the diffusion of efficient technologies. This can be addressed in part by promoting shared-savings performance-based contracts, where both parties benefit from the efficiency savings. The issues of market barriers to energy efficiency, and the principal agent problem in particular, are receiving renewed attention because of the importance of global climate change and rising prices of the finite supply of fossil fuels.[28]

Trust relationships edit

The problem arises in client–attorney, probate executor, bankruptcy trustee, and other such relationships. In some rare cases, attorneys who were entrusted with estate accounts with sizeable balances acted against the interests of the person who hired them to act as their agent by embezzling the funds or "playing the market" with the client's money (with the goal of pocketing any proceeds).[citation needed]

This section can also be explored from the perspective of the trust game which captures the key elements of principal–agent problems. This game was first experimentally implemented by Berg, Dickhaut, and McCabe in 1995.[29] The setup of the game is that there are two players – trustor/principal (investor) and agents (investee). The trustor is endowed with a budget and come transfer some of the amounts to an agent in expectation of return over the transferred amount in the future. The trustee may send any part of the transferred amount back to the trustor. The amount transferred back by the trustee is referred to as trustworthiness. Most of the studies find that 45% of the endowment was transferred by the principal and around 33% transferred back by an agent. This means that investors are not selfish and can be trusted for economic transactions.

Trust within the principal-agent problem can also be seen from the perspective of an employer-employee relationship, whereby the employee (agent) has distrust in the employer (principal) which causes greater demotivation of the employee. It has been assumed that the principal having control in an organisational culture has benefits to for the organisation by creating greater productivity and efficiency. However it also entails some drawbacks that reduce the employee satisfaction such as reduced motivation, creativity, innovation and greater anxiety and stress.[30]

Personnel management edit

When managing personnel in an organisational setting, the principal-agent problem surfaces when employees are hired to perform specific tasks and fulfil certain roles. In this environment, the goals of employee and employer may not be aligned. Often employees have the desire to further their own career or financial goals where employers often have the output interests of the organisation at the forefront of their actions and goals.[31]

Employees may reveal the principal-agent problem in their work by slacking off and not meeting targets or KPIs and Employers may reveal the principal-agent problem by implementing damaging policies or actions that make the working environment unsustainable.[31]

Bureaucracy and public administration edit

In the context of public administration, the principal–agent problem can be seen in such a way where public administration and bureaucrats are the agents and politicians and ministers are the principal authorities.[32] Ministers in the government usually command by framing policies and direct the bureaucrats to implement the public policies. However, there can be various principal-agent problems in the scenario such as misaligned intentions, information asymmetry, adverse selection, shirking, and slippage.

There are various situations where the ambitions and goals of the principals and agents may diverge. For example, politicians and the government may want public administration to implement a welfare policy program but the bureaucrats may have other interests as well such as rent-seeking. This results in a lack of implementation of public policies, hence the wastage of economic resources. This can also lead to the problem of shirking which is characterized as avoidance of performing a defined responsibility by the agent.

The information asymmetry problem occurs in a scenario where one of the two people has more or less information than the other. In the context of public administration, bureaucrats have an information advantage over the government and ministers as the former work at the ground level and have more knowledge about the dynamic and changing situation. Due to this government may frame policies that are not based on complete information and therefore problems in the implementation of public policies may occur. This can also lead to the problem of slippage which is defined as a myth where the principal sees that agents are working according to the pre-defined responsibilities but that might not be the reality.[33]

The problem of adverse selection is related to the selection of agents to fulfill particular responsibilities but they might deviate from doing so. The prime cause behind this is the incomplete information available at the desk of selecting authorities (principal) about the agents they selected.[34] For example, the Ministry of Road and Transport Highways hired a private company to complete one of its road projects, however, it was later found that the company assigned to complete road projects lacked technical know-how and had management issues.

The principal-agent problem in the public sector arises when there is a disconnect between politicians and public servants and their goals and interests. Other reasons that this occurs is because of political interference, bureaucratic resistance and public accountability.

Political interference happens when the politicians try and influence the decisions of public servants or bureaucrats to try and push their own interests which ultimately leads to policies being warped.[35][35]

Bureaucratic Resistance is when public servants are hesitant to implement the policies that have been proposed or agreed on, which ultimately causes policies to be implemented at a slow rate. Bureaucratic resistance may be due to lack of funding, resources or political support.[35]

Public accountability also plays a role in how the principal-agent theory impacts the public sector. When sworn in, politicians and public servants are responsible for ensure that they act in the interest of the public that they represent or work for, however, due to budget and resourcing issues as well as lack of transparency trust in the public sector often falls and a major disconnect grows.[35]

Economic theory edit

In economic theory, the principal-agent approach (also called agency theory) is part of the field contract theory.[36][37] In agency theory, it is typically assumed that complete contracts can be written, an assumption also made in mechanism design theory. Hence, there are no restrictions on the class of feasible contractual arrangements between principal and agent.

Agency theory can be subdivided in two categories: (1) In adverse selection models, the agent has private information about their type (say, their costs of exerting effort or their valuation of a good) before the contract is written. (2) In moral hazard models, the agent becomes privately informed after the contract is written. Hart and Holmström (1987) divide moral hazard models in the categories "hidden action" (e.g., the agent chooses an unobservable effort level) and "hidden information" (e.g., the agent learns their valuation of a good, which is modelled as a random draw by nature).[38] In hidden action models, there is a stochastic relationship between the unobservable effort and the verifiable outcome (say, the principal's revenue), because otherwise the unobservability of the effort would be meaningless. Typically, the principal makes a take-it-or-leave-it offer to the agent; i.e., the principal has all bargaining power. In principal–agent models, the agent often gets a strictly positive rent (i.e. their payoff is larger than their reservation utility, which they would get if no contract were written), which means that the principal faces agency costs. For example, in adverse selection models the agent gets an information rent, while in hidden action models with a wealth-constrained agent the principal must leave a limited-liability rent to the agent.[36] In order to reduce the agency costs, the principal typically induces a second-best solution that differs from the socially optimal first-best solution (which would be attained if there were complete information). If the agent had all bargaining power, the first-best solution would be achieved in adverse selection models with one-sided private information as well as in hidden action models where the agent is wealth-constrained.

Contract-theoretic principal–agent models have been applied in various fields, including financial contracting,[39] regulation,[40] public procurement,[41] monopolistic price-discrimination,[42] job design,[43] internal labor markets,[44] team production,[45] and many others. From the cybernetics point of view, the Cultural Agency Theory arose in order to better understand the socio-cultural nature of organisations and their behaviours.

Negotiation edit

In the negotiation problem, the principal commissions an agent to conduct negotiations on its behalf. The principal may delegate certain authority to the agent, including the ability to conclude negotiations and enter into binding contracts. The principal may consider and assign a utility to each issue in the negotiation.[46] However, it is not always the case that the principal will explicitly inform the agent of what it considers to be the minimally acceptable terms, otherwise known as the reservation price.[47] The successfulness of a negotiation will be determined by a range of factors. These include: the negotiation objective, the role of the negotiating parties, the nature of the relationship between the negotiating parties, the negotiating power of each party and the negotiation type. Where there are information asymmetries between the principal and agent, this can affect the outcome of the negotiation. As it is impossible for a manager to attend all upcoming negotiations of the company, it is common practice to assign internal or external negotiators to represent the negotiating company at the negotiation table. With the principal–agent problem, two areas of negotiation emerge:

  1. negotiations between the agent and the actual negotiating partner (negotiations at the table)
  2. internal negotiations, as between the agent and the principal (negotiations behind the table).[48]

The principal-agent problem can arises in representative negotiations where the interests of the principal and the agent are misaligned. The principal cannot directly observe the agent's efforts during the course of the negotiation. In such circumstances, this may lead to the agent employing negotiation tactics which are unfavourable to the principal, but which benefit the agent. Depending upon how the agent's reward is determined, the principal may be able to effectively retain control over the agent. If the agent receives a fixed fee, the agent may nonetheless act in a manner that is inconsistent with the principal's interests. The agent may adopt this strategy if they believe the negotiation is a one-shot game. The agent may adopt a different strategy if they account for reputational consequences of acting against the principal's interests. Similarly, if the negotiation is a repeated game, and the principal is aware of the results of the first iteration, the agent may opt to employ a different strategy which more closely aligns with the interests of the principal in order to ensure the principal will continue to contract with the agent in the following iterations. If the agent's reward is dependent upon the outcome of the negotiation, then this may help align the differing interests.[49]

In popular culture edit

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Eisenhardt, K.M. (1989), "Agency Theory: An Assessment and Review", The Academy of Management Review, 14 (1): 57–74, doi:10.5465/amr.1989.4279003, JSTOR 258191.
  2. ^ Adams, Julia (1996). "Principals and Agents, Colonialists and Company Men: The Decay of Colonial Control in the Dutch East Indies". American Sociological Review. 61 (1): 12–28. doi:10.2307/2096404. ISSN 0003-1224. JSTOR 2096404. from the original on September 20, 2022. Retrieved September 16, 2022.
  3. ^ Pay Without Performance, Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried, Harvard University Press 2004 (preface and introduction February 14, 2019, at the Wayback Machine)
  4. ^ "Agency Costs". Investopedia. from the original on April 22, 2019. Retrieved July 3, 2012.
  5. ^ Gailmard, Sean (2014), "Accountability and Principal–Agent Theory", The Oxford Handbook of Public Accountability, Oxford University Press, doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199641253.013.0016, ISBN 978-0-19-964125-3
  6. ^ a b Voorn, B.; Van Genugten, M.; Van Thiel, S. (2019). "Multiple principals, multiple problems: Implications for effective governance and a research agenda for joint service delivery". Public Administration. 97 (3): 671–685. doi:10.1111/padm.12587. hdl:2066/207394.
  7. ^ Downes, Alexander B. (2021). Catastrophic success : why foreign-imposed regime change goes wrong. Cornell University Press. ISBN 978-1-5017-6116-4. OCLC 1252920900.
  8. ^ Bernheim, B.D.; Whinston, M.D. (1986). "Common agency". Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society. 54 (4): 923. doi:10.2307/1912844. JSTOR 1912844.
  9. ^ Martimort, D. (1996). "The multiprincipal nature of government". European Economic Review. 40 (3–5): 673–85. doi:10.1016/0014-2921(95)00079-8.
  10. ^ Moe, T.M. (2005). "Power and political institutions". Perspectives on Politics. 3 (2). doi:10.1017/S1537592705050176. S2CID 39072417.
  11. ^ Potucek, M (2017). Public Policy: A Comprehensive Introduction. Prague, Charles University: Karolinum Press.
  12. ^ Mitnick, Barry M. (January 2006). "Origin of the Theory of Agency". from the original on March 7, 2021. Retrieved April 20, 2015.
  13. ^ Jensen, Michael C.; Meckling, William H. (October 1976). "Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure" (PDF). Journal of Financial Economics. 3 (4): 305–360. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X. (PDF) from the original on March 20, 2021. Retrieved September 8, 2017.
  14. ^ Pendergast, Canice (1999). "The Provision of Incentives in Firms". Journal of Economic Literature. 37 (1): 7–63. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.558.6657. doi:10.1257/jel.37.1.7. JSTOR 2564725.
  15. ^ Paula Szuchman, Jenny Anderson. It's Not You, It's the Dishes (originally published as Spousonomics): How to Minimize Conflict and Maximize Happiness in Your Relationship. Random House Digital, Inc., June 12, 2012. Page 210. Accessed on May 31, 2013
  16. ^ "Only the tip, but size is important". The Age. December 11, 2004. from the original on April 1, 2016. Retrieved July 23, 2013.
  17. ^ Crifo, Patricia. "INCENTIVES IN AGENCY RELATIONSHIPS: TO BE MONETARY OR NON-MONETARY?" (PDF). Retrieved October 29, 2020.[dead link]
  18. ^ Pink, Daniel H. (2009). Drive: The Surprising Truth about What Motivates Us. New York: Riverhead Books. ISBN 9781594488849.
  19. ^ Haubrich, Joseph (1994). "Risk Aversion, Performance Pay, and the Principal-Agent Problem". Journal of Political Economy. 102 (2): 258–276. doi:10.1086/261931. S2CID 15450754. Retrieved October 29, 2020.
  20. ^ Jensen, M. C.; Murphy, K. J. "Performance Pay and Top-Management Incentives". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  21. ^ "Moral Hazard and Observability" April 27, 2021, at the Wayback Machine, The Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 10, No. 1 (Spring, 1979), pp. 74-91
  22. ^ Aswath Damodaran: Applications Of Option Pricing Theory To Equity Valuation April 27, 2012, at the Wayback Machine and Option Pricing Applications in Valuation September 16, 2012, at the Wayback Machine.
  23. ^ D. Mauer and S. Sarkar (2001). Real Options, Agency Conflicts, and Financial Policy March 4, 2016, at the Wayback Machine; G. Siller-Pagaza, G. Otalora, E. Cobas-Flores (2006). The Impact of Real Options in Agency Problems June 2, 2016, at the Wayback Machine
  24. ^ [S. Nagel and A. Purnanandam (2017). Bank Risk Dynamics and Distance to Default April 23, 2023, at the Wayback Machine;
  25. ^ [S. Peleg-Lazar and A. Raviv (2017). Bank Risk Dynamics Where Assets are Risky Debt Claims August 5, 2017, at the Wayback Machine;
  26. ^ Nielson, Williams. Personal Economics (3 ed.). TENNESSEE, KNOXVILLE: Pearson Education. pp. 107–118.
  27. ^ Jaffe, Adam B; Stavins, Robert N (1994). "The energy efficiency gap: What does it mean?" (PDF). Energy Policy. 22 (10): 805. doi:10.1016/0301-4215(94)90138-4. (PDF) from the original on May 1, 2019. Retrieved May 1, 2019.
  28. ^ "Mind the Gap". IEA. from the original on May 1, 2019. Retrieved May 1, 2019.
  29. ^ Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). "Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History". Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 122–142. doi:10.1006/game.1995.1027
  30. ^ Falk, Armin; Kosfeld, Michael (December 2006). "The Hidden Costs of Control". American Economic Review. 96 (5): 1611–1630. doi:10.1257/aer.96.5.1611. ISSN 0002-8282. from the original on March 8, 2023. Retrieved March 8, 2023.
  31. ^ a b Baker, Rose M. (2019). "The Agency of the Principal–Agent Relationship: An Opportunity for HRD". Advances in Developing Human Resources. 21 (3): 303–318. doi:10.1177/1523422319851274. S2CID 197688734.
  32. ^ Potucek, M. (2017). Public Policy: A Comprehensive Introduction. Prague: Karolinum Press, Charles University
  33. ^ Lane, J. E., & Kivistö, J. (2008). "Interests, Information, and Incentives in Higher Education: Principal–Agent Theory and Its Potential Applications to the Study of Higher Education Governance". Higher Education: Handbook of Theory and Research.
  34. ^ Garba, et al. (2020). "Government Higher Education Institutions Relationship Vide the Lens of the Principal–Agent Theory". The 27th International Business Information Management Association Conference (pp. 1–11). Milan: International Business Information Management Association.
  35. ^ a b c d Wood, B. Dan (October 14, 2010). Agency Theory and the Bureaucracy. Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199238958.003.0008.
  36. ^ a b Laffont, Jean-Jacques; Martimort, David (2002). The theory of incentives: The principal-agent model. Princeton University Press.
  37. ^ Bolton, Patrick; Dewatripont, Matthias (2005). Contract theory. MIT Press.
  38. ^ Hart, Oliver; Holmström, Bengt (1987). "The theory of contracts". In Bewley, T. (ed.). Advances in Economics and Econometrics. Cambridge University Press. pp. 71–155.
  39. ^ Tirole, Jean (2006). The theory of corporate finance. Princeton University Press.
  40. ^ Baron, David P.; Myerson, Roger B. (1982). "Regulating a Monopolist with Unknown Costs". Econometrica. 50 (4): 911–930. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.407.6185. doi:10.2307/1912769. JSTOR 1912769.
  41. ^ Schmitz, Patrick W. (2013). "Public procurement in times of crisis: The bundling decision reconsidered". Economics Letters. 121 (3): 533–536. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2013.10.015.
  42. ^ Maskin, Eric; Riley, John (1984). "Monopoly with Incomplete Information". RAND Journal of Economics. 15 (2): 171–196. JSTOR 2555674.
  43. ^ Schmitz, Patrick W. (2013). "Job design with conflicting tasks reconsidered". European Economic Review. 57: 108–117. doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2012.11.001.
  44. ^ Kräkel, Matthias; Schöttner, Anja (2012). "Internal labor markets and worker rents". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 84 (2): 491–509. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.320.692. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2012.08.008.
  45. ^ Homström, Bengt (1982). "Moral hazard in teams". Bell Journal of Economics. 13 (2): 324–340. doi:10.2307/3003457. JSTOR 3003457.
  46. ^ Piasecki, Krzysztof; Roszkowska, Ewa; Wachowicz, Tomasz; Filipowicz-Chomko, Marzena; Łyczkowska-Hanćkowiak, Anna (July 29, 2021). "Fuzzy Representation of Principal's Preferences in Inspire Negotiation Support System". Entropy. 23 (8): 981. Bibcode:2021Entrp..23..981P. doi:10.3390/e23080981. ISSN 1099-4300. PMC 8392366. PMID 34441121.
  47. ^ Lax, David A.; Sebenius, James K. (September 1991). "Negotiating Through an Agent". Journal of Conflict Resolution. 35 (3): 474–493. doi:10.1177/0022002791035003004. ISSN 0022-0027. S2CID 143173392. from the original on May 2, 2022. Retrieved May 2, 2022.
  48. ^ Jung, Stefanie; Krebs Peter (15 June 2019). "The Essentials of Contract Negotiation". Springer International Publishing. doi:10.1007/978-3-030-12866-1 May 2, 2022, at the Wayback Machine
  49. ^ Miller, Gary J.; Whitford, Andrew B. (April 1, 2002). "Trust and Incentives in Principal-Agent Negotiations: The 'Insurance/Incentive Trade-Off'". Journal of Theoretical Politics. 14 (2): 231–267. doi:10.1177/095169280201400204. ISSN 0951-6298. S2CID 17436198. from the original on January 20, 2023. Retrieved May 2, 2022.

Further reading edit

  • Azfar, Omar (2007). "Chapter 8: Disrupting Corruption" (PDF). In Shah, Anwar (ed.). Performance Accountability and Combating Corruption. World Bank. doi:10.1596/978-0-8213-6941-8. hdl:10986/6732. ISBN 9780821369418.
  • Eisenhardt, K. (1989). "Agency theory: An assessment and review". Academy of Management Review. 14 (1): 57–74. doi:10.5465/amr.1989.4279003. JSTOR 258191.
  • Gailmard, Sean (2014), "Accountability and Principal–Agent Theory" in The Oxford Handbook of Public Accountability. Oxford University Press.
  • Green, J. R.; Stokey, N. L. (1983). "A Comparison of Tournaments and Contracts". Journal of Political Economy. 91 (3): 349–64. doi:10.1086/261153. JSTOR 1837093. S2CID 18043549.
  • (PDF), IEA, 2007, archived from the original (PDF) on September 30, 2018, retrieved February 7, 2013.
  • Laffont, Jean-Jacques and Martimort, David (2002). The Theory of Incentives: The Principal–Agent Model. Princeton University Press.
  • Miller, Gary. 2005. “The Political Evolution of Principal-Agent Models” Annual Review of Political Science 8: 203–25..
  • Nikkinen, Jussi; Sahlström, Petri (2004). "Does agency theory provide a general framework for audit pricing?". International Journal of Auditing. 8 (3): 253–262. doi:10.1111/j.1099-1123.2004.00094.x.
  • Rees, R., 1985. "The Theory of Principal and Agent—Part I". Bulletin of Economic Research, 37(1), 3–26
  • Rees, R., 1985. "The Theory of Principal and Agent—Part II". Bulletin of Economic Research, 37(2), 75–97
  • Rutherford, R. & Springer, T. & Yavas, A. (2005). Conflicts between Principals and Agents: Evidence from Residential Brokerage. Journal of Financial Economics (76), 627–65.
  • Rosen, S. (1986). "Prizes and Incentives in Elimination Tournaments". American Economic Review. 76 (4): 701–715. JSTOR 1806068.
  • Sappington, David E. M. (1991). "Incentives in Principal–Agent Relationships". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 5 (2): 45–66. doi:10.1257/jep.5.2.45. JSTOR 1942685.
  • Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1987). "Principal and agent", The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 3, pp. 966–71.

External links edit

  •   Quotations related to Principal–agent problem at Wikiquote

principal, agent, problem, this, article, multiple, issues, please, help, improve, discuss, these, issues, talk, page, learn, when, remove, these, template, messages, this, article, technical, most, readers, understand, please, help, improve, make, understanda. This article has multiple issues Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page Learn how and when to remove these template messages This article may be too technical for most readers to understand Please help improve it to make it understandable to non experts without removing the technical details May 2023 Learn how and when to remove this template message This article has an unclear citation style The references used may be made clearer with a different or consistent style of citation and footnoting May 2023 Learn how and when to remove this template message This article needs attention from an expert in Economics or Business See the talk page for details WikiProject Economics or WikiProject Business may be able to help recruit an expert May 2023 Learn how and when to remove this template message The principal agent problem refers to the conflict in interests and priorities that arises when one person or entity the agent takes actions on behalf of another person or entity the principal 1 The problem worsens when there is a greater discrepancy of interests and information between the principal and agent as well as when the principal lacks the means to punish the agent 2 The deviation from the principal s interest by the agent is called agency costs 3 Basic idea of agency theoryCommon examples of this relationship include corporate management agent and shareholders principal elected officials agent and citizens principal or brokers agent and markets buyers and sellers principals 4 In all these cases the principal has to be concerned with whether the agent is acting in the best interest of the principal Principal agent models typically either examine moral hazard hidden actions or adverse selection hidden information 5 The principal agent problem typically arises where the two parties have different interests and asymmetric information the agent having more information such that the principal cannot directly ensure that the agent is always acting in the principal s best interest particularly when activities that are useful to the principal are costly to the agent and where elements of what the agent does are costly for the principal to observe The agency problem can be intensified when an agent acts on behalf of multiple principals see multiple principal problem 6 7 When multiple principals have to agree on the agent s objectives they face a collective action problem in governance as individual principals may lobby the agent or otherwise act in their individual interests rather than in the collective interest of all principals 8 The multiple principal problem is particularly serious in the public sector 6 9 10 Various mechanisms may be used to align the interests of the agent with those of the principal In employment employers principal may use piece rates commissions profit sharing efficiency wages performance measurement including financial statements the agent posting a bond or the threat of termination of employment to align worker interests with their own Contents 1 Overview 2 Employment contract 2 1 Non financial compensation 2 2 Team production 2 3 Empirical evidence 3 Contract design 3 1 Linear model 3 2 Options framework 4 Performance evaluation 4 1 Objective 4 2 Subjective 5 Incentive structures 5 1 Tournaments 5 2 Deferred compensation 6 Energy consumption 7 Trust relationships 8 Personnel management 9 Bureaucracy and public administration 10 Economic theory 11 Negotiation 12 In popular culture 13 See also 14 References 15 Further reading 16 External linksOverview editThe principal s interests are expected to be pursued by the agent however when their interests differ a dilemma arises The agent possesses resources such as time information and expertise that the principal lacks But at the same time the principal does not have entire control over the agent s ability to act in their best interests In this situation the theory posits that the agent s activities are diverted from following the principal s interests and instead drive them to maximize their personal advantage For example in case of a dual sequence of relationships the citizens or voters count on the politicians that they elected to fulfill their duties by structuring a system in which their healthcare and financial safety is guaranteed Each citizen is a cog in the society machine and if everyone was overlooking the functioning of each and every entity in the system society would never develop However at the same time the minister of health cannot be overlooking each and every operation being done at the internal level of each public entity bureaucrats are in charge of running those institutions However when the seed of corruption is planted the whole system is disrupted as the agent is no longer pursuing the interest of the principal 11 The principal and agent theory emerged in the 1970s from the combined disciplines of economics and institutional theory There is some contention as to who originated the theory with theorists Stephen Ross and Barry Mitnick both claiming authorship 12 Ross is said to have originally described the dilemma in terms of a person choosing a flavor of ice cream for someone whose tastes they does not know Ibid The most cited reference to the theory however comes from Michael C Jensen and William Meckling 13 The theory has come to extend well beyond economics or institutional studies to all contexts of information asymmetry uncertainty and risk In the context of law principals do not know enough about whether or to what extent a contract has been satisfied and they end up with agency costs The solution to this information problem closely related to the moral hazard problem is to ensure the provision of appropriate incentives so agents act in the way principals wish In terms of game theory it involves changing the rules of the game so that the self interested rational choices of the agent coincide with what the principal desires Even in the limited arena of employment contracts the difficulty of doing this in practice is reflected in a multitude of compensation mechanisms and supervisory schemes as well as in critique of such mechanisms as e g Deming 1986 expresses in his Seven Deadly Diseases of management Employment contract editThis section has multiple issues Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page Learn how and when to remove these template messages The neutrality of this article is disputed Relevant discussion may be found on the talk page Please do not remove this message until conditions to do so are met November 2020 Learn how and when to remove this template message This section possibly contains original research Please improve it by verifying the claims made and adding inline citations Statements consisting only of original research should be removed November 2020 Learn how and when to remove this template message Learn how and when to remove this template message In the context of the employment contract individual contracts form a major method of restructuring incentives by connecting as closely as optimal the information available about employee performance and the compensation for that performance Because of differences in the quantity and quality of information available about the performance of individual employees the ability of employees to bear risk and the ability of employees to manipulate evaluation methods the structural details of individual contracts vary widely including such mechanisms as piece rates share options discretionary bonuses promotions profit sharing efficiency wages deferred compensation and so on 14 Typically these mechanisms are used in the context of different types of employment salesmen often receive some or all of their remuneration as commission production workers are usually paid an hourly wage while office workers are typically paid monthly or semimonthly and if paid overtime typically at a higher rate than the hourly rate implied by the salary citation needed The way in which these mechanisms are used is different in the two parts of the economy which Doeringer and Piore called the primary and secondary sectors see also dual labour market The secondary sector is characterised by short term employment relationships little or no prospect of internal promotion and the determination of wages primarily by market forces In terms of occupations it consists primarily of low or unskilled jobs whether they are blue collar manual labour white collar e g filing clerks or service jobs e g waiters These jobs are linked by the fact that they are characterized by low skill levels low earnings easy entry job impermanence and low returns to education or experience In a number of service jobs such as food service golf caddying and valet parking jobs workers in some countries are paid mostly or entirely with tips The use of tipping is a strategy on the part of the owners or managers to align the interests of the service workers with those of the owners or managers the service workers have an incentive to provide good customer service thus benefiting the company s business because this makes it more likely that they will get a good tip The issue of tipping is sometimes discussed in connection with the principal agent theory Examples of principals and agents include bosses and employees and diners and waiters The principal agent problem as it is known in economics crops up any time agents aren t inclined to do what principals want them to do To sway them agents principals have to make it worth the agents while in the restaurant context the better the diner s experience the bigger the waiter s tip 15 In the language of the economist the tip serves as a way to reduce what is known as the classic principal agent problem According to Videbeck a researcher at the New Zealand Institute for the Study of Competition and Regulation i n theory tipping can lead to an efficient match between workers attitudes to service and the jobs they perform It is a means to make people work hard Friendly waiters will go that extra mile earn their tip and earn a relatively high income On the other hand if tipless wages are sufficiently low then grumpy waiters might actually choose to leave the industry and take jobs that would better suit their personalities 16 As a solution to the principal agent problem though tipping is not perfect In the hopes of getting a larger tip a server for example may be inclined to give a customer an extra large glass of wine or a second scoop of ice cream While these larger servings make the customer happy and increase the likelihood of the server getting a good tip they cut into the profit margin of the restaurant In addition a server may dote on generous tippers while ignoring other customers and in rare cases harangue bad tippers Non financial compensation edit Part of this variation in incentive structures and supervisory mechanisms may be attributable to variation in the level of intrinsic psychological satisfaction to be had from different types of work Sociologists and psychologists frequently argue that individuals take a certain degree of pride in their work and that introducing performance related pay can destroy this psycho social compensation because the exchange relation between employer and employee becomes much more narrowly economic destroying most or all of the potential for social exchange Evidence for this is inconclusive Deci 1971 and Lepper Greene and Nisbett 1973 find support for this argument Staw 1989 suggests other interpretations of the findings Incentive structures as mentioned above can be provided through non monetary recognition such as acknowledgements and compliments on an employee agent in place of employment Research conducted by Crifo and Diaye 2004 17 mentioned that agents who receive compensations such as praises acknowledgement and recognition help to define intrinsic motivations that increase performance output from the agents thus benefiting the principal Furthermore the studies provided a conclusive remark that intrinsic motivation can be increased by utilising the use of non monetary compensations that provide acknowledgement for the agent These higher rewards can provide a principal with the adequate methodologies to improve the effort inputs of the agent when looking at the principal agent theory through an employer vs employee level of conduct Team production edit On a related note Drago and Garvey 1997 use Australian survey data to show that when agents are placed on individual pay for performance schemes they are less likely to help their coworkers This negative effect is particularly important in those jobs that involve strong elements of team production Alchian and Demsetz 1972 where output reflects the contribution of many individuals and individual contributions cannot be easily identified and compensation is therefore based largely on the output of the team In other words pay for performance increases the incentives to free ride as there are large positive externalities to the efforts of an individual team member and low returns to the individual Holmstrom 1982 McLaughlin 1994 The negative incentive effects implied are confirmed by some empirical studies e g Newhouse 1973 for shared medical practices costs rise and doctors work fewer hours as more revenue is shared Leibowitz and Tollison 1980 find that larger law partnerships typically result in worse cost containment As a counter peer pressure can potentially solve the problem Kandel and Lazear 1992 but this depends on peer monitoring being relatively costless to the individuals doing the monitoring censuring in any particular instance unless one brings in social considerations of norms and group identity and so on Studies suggest that profit sharing for example typically raises productivity by 3 5 Jones and Kato 1995 Knez and Simester 2001 although there are some selection issues Prendergast Empirical evidence edit There is however considerable empirical evidence of a positive effect of compensation on performance although the studies usually involve simple jobs where aggregate measures of performance are available which is where piece rates should be most effective In one study Lazear 1996 saw productivity rising by 44 and wages by 10 in a change from salary to piece rates with a half of the productivity gain due to worker selection effects Research shows that pay for performance increases performance when the task at hand is more repetitive and reduces performance when the task at hand requires more creative thinking 18 Furthermore 19 formulated from their studies that compensation tend to have an impact on performance as a result of risk aversion and the level of work that a CEO is willing to input This showed that when the CEO returned less effort then the data correlated a pay level of neutral aversion based on incentives However when offered incentives the data correlated a spike in performance as a direct result Conclusively their studies indicated business owner principal and business employees agents must find a middle ground which coincides with an adequate shared profit for the company that is proportional to CEO pay and performance In doing this risk aversion of employee efforts being low can be avoided pre emptively Paarsch and Shearer 1996 also find evidence supportive of incentive and productivity effects from piece rates as do Banker Lee and Potter 1996 although the latter do not distinguish between incentive and worker selection effects Rutherford Springer and Yavas 2005 find evidence of agency problems in residential real estate by showing that real estate agents sell their own houses at a price premium of approximately 4 5 compared to their clients houses Fernie and Metcalf 1996 find that top British jockeys perform significantly better when offered percentage of prize money for winning races compared to being on fixed retainers McMillan Whalley and Zhu 1989 and Groves et al 1994 look at Chinese agricultural and industrial data respectively and find significant incentive effects Kahn and Sherer 1990 find that better evaluations of white collar office workers were achieved by those employees who had a steeper relation between evaluations and pay Nikkinen and Sahlstrom 2004 find empirical evidence that agency theory can be used at least to some extent to explain financial audit fees internationally There is very little correlation between performance pay of CEOs and the success of the companies they manage 20 Contract design editMilgrom and Roberts 1992 identify four principles of contract design When perfect information is not available Holmstrom 1979 21 developed the Informativeness Principle to solve this problem This essentially states that any measure of performance that on the margin reveals information about the effort level chosen by the agent should be included in the compensation contract This includes for example Relative Performance Evaluation measurement relative to other similar agents so as to filter out some common background noise factors such as fluctuations in demand By removing some exogenous sources of randomness in the agent s income a greater proportion of the fluctuation in the agent s income falls under their control increasing their ability to bear risk If taken advantage of by greater use of piece rates this should improve incentives In terms of the simple linear model below this means that increasing x produces an increase in b However setting incentives as intense as possible is not necessarily optimal from the point of view of the employer The Incentive Intensity Principle states that the optimal intensity of incentives depends on four factors the incremental profits created by additional effort the precision with which the desired activities are assessed the agent s risk tolerance and the agent s responsiveness to incentives According to Prendergast 1999 8 the primary constraint on performance related pay is that its provision imposes additional risk on workers A typical result of the early principal agent literature was that piece rates tend to 100 of the compensation package as the worker becomes more able to handle risk as this ensures that workers fully internalize the consequences of their costly actions In incentive terms where we conceive of workers as self interested rational individuals who provide costly effort in the most general sense of the worker s input to the firm s production function the more compensation varies with effort the better the incentives for the worker to produce The third principle the Monitoring Intensity Principle is complementary to the second in that situations in which the optimal intensity of incentives is high corresponds highly to situations in which the optimal level of monitoring is also high Thus employers effectively choose from a menu of monitoring incentive intensities This is because monitoring is a costly means of reducing the variance of employee performance which makes more difference to profits in the kinds of situations where it is also optimal to make incentives intense The fourth principle is the Equal Compensation Principle which essentially states that activities equally valued by the employer should be equally valuable in terms of compensation including non financial aspects such as pleasantness of the workplace to the employee This relates to the problem that employees may be engaged in several activities and if some of these are not monitored or are monitored less heavily these will be neglected as activities with higher marginal returns to the employee are favoured This can be thought of as a kind of disintermediation targeting certain measurable variables may cause others to suffer For example teachers being rewarded by test scores of their students are likely to tend more towards teaching for the test and de emphasise less relevant but perhaps equally or more important aspects of education while AT amp T s practice at one time of paying programmers by the number of lines of code written resulted in programs that were longer than necessary i e program efficiency suffering Prendergast 1999 21 Following Holmstrom and Milgrom 1990 and Baker 1992 this has become known as multi tasking where a subset of relevant tasks is rewarded non rewarded tasks suffer relative neglect Because of this the more difficult it is to completely specify and measure the variables on which reward is to be conditioned the less likely that performance related pay will be used in essence complex jobs will typically not be evaluated through explicit contracts Prendergast 1999 9 Where explicit measures are used they are more likely to be some kind of aggregate measure for example baseball and American Football players are rarely rewarded on the many specific measures available e g number of home runs but frequently receive bonuses for aggregate performance measures such as Most Valuable Player The alternative to objective measures is subjective performance evaluation typically by supervisors However there is here a similar effect to multi tasking as workers shift effort from that subset of tasks which they consider useful and constructive to that subset which they think gives the greatest appearance of being useful and constructive and more generally to try to curry personal favour with supervisors One can interpret this as a destruction of organizational social capital workers identifying with and actively working for the benefit of the firm in favour of the creation of personal social capital the individual level social relations which enable workers to get ahead networking Linear model edit The four principles can be summarized in terms of the simplest linear model of incentive compensation w a b e x g y displaystyle w a b e x gy nbsp where w wage is equal to a the base salary plus b the intensity of incentives provided to the employee times the sum of three terms e unobserved employee effort plus x unobserved exogenous effects on outcomes plus the product of g the weight given to observed exogenous effects on outcomes and y observed exogenous effects on outcomes b is the slope of the relationship between compensation and outcomes wage base salary incentives unobserved effort unobserved effects weight Y observed exogenous effects displaystyle begin aligned text wage amp text base salary text incentives cdot Big text unobserved effort text unobserved effects Big 5pt amp text weight Y cdot text observed exogenous effects end aligned nbsp The above discussion on explicit measures assumed that contracts would create the linear incentive structures summarised in the model above But while the combination of normal errors and the absence of income effects yields linear contracts many observed contracts are nonlinear To some extent this is due to income effects as workers rise up a tournament hierarchy Quite simply it may take more money to induce effort from the rich than from the less well off Prendergast 1999 50 Similarly the threat of being fired creates a nonlinearity in wages earned versus performance Moreover many empirical studies illustrate inefficient behaviour arising from nonlinear objective performance measures or measures over the course of a long period e g a year which create nonlinearities in time due to discounting behaviour This inefficient behaviour arises because incentive structures are varying for example when a worker has already exceeded a quota or has no hope of reaching it versus being close to reaching it e g Healy 1985 Oyer 1997 Leventis 1997 Leventis shows that New York surgeons penalised for exceeding a certain mortality rate take less risky cases as they approach the threshold Courty and Marshke 1997 provide evidence on incentive contracts offered to agencies which receive bonuses on reaching a quota of graduated trainees within a year This causes them to rush graduate trainees in order to make the quota Options framework edit In certain cases agency problems may be analysed by applying the techniques developed for financial options as applied via a real options framework 22 23 Stockholders and bondholders have different objective for instance stockholders have an incentive to take riskier projects than bondholders do and to pay more out in dividends than bondholders would like At the same time since equity may be seen as a call option on the value of the firm an increase in the variance in the firm value other things remaining equal will lead to an increase in the value of equity and stockholders may therefore take risky projects with negative net present values which while making them better off may make the bondholders worse off See Option pricing approaches under Business valuation for further discussion Nagel and Purnanandam 2017 notice that since bank assets are risky debt claims bank equity resembles a subordinated debt and therefore the stock s payoff is truncated by the difference between the face values of the corporation debt and of the bank deposits 24 Based on this observation Peleg Lazar and Raviv 2017 show that in contrast to the classical agent theory of Michael C Jensen and William Meckling an increase in variance would not lead to an increase in the value of equity if the bank s debtor is solvent 25 Performance evaluation editObjective edit The major problem in measuring employee performance in cases where it is difficult to draw a straightforward connection between performance and profitability is the setting of a standard by which to judge the performance One method of setting an absolute objective performance standard rarely used because it is costly and only appropriate for simple repetitive tasks is time and motion studies which study in detail how fast it is possible to do a certain task These have been used constructively in the past particularly in manufacturing More generally however even within the field of objective performance evaluation some form of relative performance evaluation must be used Typically this takes the form of comparing the performance of a worker to that of his peers in the firm or industry perhaps taking account of different exogenous circumstances affecting that The reason that employees are often paid according to hours of work rather than by direct measurement of results is that it is often more efficient to use indirect systems of controlling the quantity and quality of effort due to a variety of informational and other issues e g turnover costs which determine the optimal minimum length of relationship between firm and employee This means that methods such as deferred compensation and structures such as tournaments are often more suitable to create the incentives for employees to contribute what they can to output over longer periods years rather than hours These represent pay for performance systems in a looser more extended sense as workers who consistently work harder and better are more likely to be promoted and usually paid more compared to the narrow definition of pay for performance such as piece rates This discussion has been conducted almost entirely for self interested rational individuals In practice however the incentive mechanisms which successful firms use take account of the socio cultural context they are embedded in Fukuyama 1995 Granovetter 1985 in order not to destroy the social capital they might more constructively mobilise towards building an organic social organization with the attendant benefits from such things as worker loyalty and pride which can be critical to a firm s success Sappington 1991 63 Subjective edit Subjective performance evaluation allows the use of a subtler more balanced assessment of employee performance and is typically used for more complex jobs where comprehensive objective measures are difficult to specify and or measure Whilst often the only feasible method the attendant problems with subjective performance evaluation have resulted in a variety of incentive structures and supervisory schemes One problem for example is that supervisors may under report performance in order to save on wages if they are in some way residual claimants or perhaps rewarded on the basis of cost savings This tendency is of course to some extent offset by the danger of retaliation and or demotivation of the employee if the supervisor is responsible for that employee s output Another problem relates to what is known as the compression of ratings Two related influences centrality bias and leniency bias have been documented Landy and Farr 1980 Murphy and Cleveland 1991 The former results from supervisors being reluctant to distinguish critically between workers perhaps for fear of destroying team spirit while the latter derives from supervisors being averse to offering poor ratings to subordinates especially where these ratings are used to determine pay not least because bad evaluations may be demotivating rather than motivating However these biases introduce noise into the relationship between pay and effort reducing the incentive effect of performance related pay Milkovich and Wigdor 1991 suggest that this is the reason for the common separation of evaluations and pay with evaluations primarily used to allocate training Finally while the problem of compression of ratings originates on the supervisor side related effects occur when workers actively attempt to influence the appraisals supervisors give either by influencing the performance information going to the supervisor multitasking focussing on the more visibly productive activities Paul 1992 or by working too hard to signal worker quality or create a good impression Holmstrom 1982 or by influencing the evaluation of it e g by currying influence Milgrom and Roberts 1988 or by outright bribery Tirole 1992 Incentive structures editTournaments edit Much of the discussion here has been in terms of individual pay for performance contracts but many large firms use internal labour markets Doeringer and Piore 1971 Rosen 1982 as a solution to some of the problems outlined Here there is pay for performance in a looser sense over a longer time period There is little variation in pay within grades and pay increases come with changes in job or job title Gibbs and Hendricks 1996 The incentive effects of this structure are dealt with in what is known as tournament theory Lazear and Rosen 1981 Green and Stokey 1983 see Rosen 1986 for multi stage tournaments in hierarchies where it is explained why CEOs are paid many times more than other workers in the firm See the superstar article for more information on the tournament theory Workers are motivated to supply effort by the wage increase they would earn if they win a promotion Some of the extended tournament models predict that relatively weaker agents be they competing in a sports tournaments Becker and Huselid 1992 in NASCAR racing or in the broiler chicken industry Knoeber and Thurman 1994 would take risky actions instead of increasing their effort supply as a cheap way to improve the prospects of winning These actions are inefficient as they increase risk taking without increasing the average effort supplied Neilson 2007 further added to this from his studies which indicated that when two employees competed to win in a tournament they have a higher chance of bending and or breaking the rules to win Nelson 2007 also indicated that when the larger the price incentive the more inclined the agent employee in this case is to increase their effort parameter from Neilson s studies 26 A major problem with tournaments is that individuals are rewarded based on how well they do relative to others Co workers might become reluctant to help out others and might even sabotage others effort instead of increasing their own effort Lazear 1989 Rob and Zemsky 1997 This is supported empirically by Drago and Garvey 1997 Why then are tournaments so popular Firstly because especially given compression rating problems it is difficult to determine absolutely differences in worker performance Tournaments merely require rank order evaluation Secondly it reduces the danger of rent seeking because bonuses paid to favourite workers are tied to increased responsibilities in new jobs and supervisors will suffer if they do not promote the most qualified person This effectively takes the factors of ambiguity away from the principal agent problem by ensuring that the agent acts in the best interest of the principal but also ensures that the quality of work done is of an optimal level Thirdly where prize structures are relatively fixed it reduces the possibility of the firm reneging on paying wages As Carmichael 1983 notes a prize structure represents a degree of commitment both to absolute and to relative wage levels Lastly when the measurement of workers productivity is difficult e g say monitoring is costly or when the tasks the workers have to perform for the job is varied in nature making it hard to measure effort and or performance then running tournaments in a firm would encourage the workers to supply effort whereas workers would have shirked if there are no promotions Tournaments also promote risk seeking behavior In essence the compensation scheme becomes more like a call option on performance which increases in value with increased volatility cf options pricing If you are one of ten players competing for the asymmetrically large top prize you may benefit from reducing the expected value of your overall performance to the firm in order to increase your chance that you have an outstanding performance and win the prize In moderation this can offset the greater risk aversion of agents vs principals because their social capital is concentrated in their employer while in the case of public companies the principal typically owns its stake as part of a diversified portfolio Successful innovation is particularly dependent on employees willingness to take risks In cases with extreme incentive intensity this sort of behavior can create catastrophic organizational failure If the principal owns the firm as part of a diversified portfolio this may be a price worth paying for the greater chance of success through innovation elsewhere in the portfolio If however the risks taken are systematic and cannot be diversified e g exposure to general housing prices then such failures will damage the interests of principals and even the economy as a whole cf Kidder Peabody Barings Enron AIG to name a few Ongoing periodic catastrophic organizational failure is directly incentivized by tournament and other superstar winner take all compensation systems Holt 1995 Deferred compensation edit Tournaments represent one way of implementing the general principle of deferred compensation which is essentially an agreement between worker and firm to commit to each other Under schemes of deferred compensation workers are overpaid when old at the cost of being underpaid when young Salop and Salop 1976 argue that this derives from the need to attract workers more likely to stay at the firm for longer periods since turnover is costly Alternatively delays in evaluating the performance of workers may lead to compensation being weighted to later periods when better and poorer workers have to a greater extent been distinguished Workers may even prefer to have wages increasing over time perhaps as a method of forced saving or as an indicator of personal development e g Loewenstein and Sicherman 1991 Frank and Hutchens 1993 For example Akerlof and Katz 1989 if older workers receive efficiency wages younger workers may be prepared to work for less in order to receive those later Overall the evidence suggests the use of deferred compensation e g Freeman and Medoff 1984 and Spilerman 1986 seniority provisions are often included in pay promotion and retention decisions irrespective of productivity Energy consumption editThe principal agent problem has also been discussed in the context of energy consumption by Jaffe and Stavins in 1994 They were attempting to catalog market and non market barriers to energy efficiency adoption In efficiency terms a market failure arises when a technology which is both cost effective and saves energy is not implemented Jaffe and Stavins describe the common case of the landlord tenant problem with energy issues as a principal agent problem I f the potential adopter is not the party that pays the energy bill then good information in the hands of the potential adopter may not be sufficient for optimal diffusion adoption will only occur if the adopter can recover the investment from the party that enjoys the energy savings Thus if it is difficult for the possessor of information to convey it credibly to the party that benefits from reduced energy use a principal agent problem arises 27 The energy efficiency use of the principal agent terminology is in fact distinct from the usual one in several ways In landlord tenant or more generally equipment purchaser energy bill payer situations it is often difficult to describe who would be the principal and who the agent Is the agent the landlord and the principal the tenant because the landlord is hired by the tenant through the payment of rent As Murtishaw and Sathaye 2006 point out In the residential sector the conceptual definition of principal and agent must be stretched beyond a strictly literal definition Another distinction is that the principal agent problem in energy efficiency does not require any information asymmetry both the landlord and the tenant may be aware of the overall costs and benefits of energy efficient investments but as long as the landlord pays for the equipment and the tenant pays the energy bills the investment in new energy efficient appliances will not be made In this case there is also little incentive for the tenant to make a capital efficiency investment with a usual payback time of several years and which in the end will revert to the landlord as property Since energy consumption is determined both by technology and by behavior an opposite principal agent problem arises when the energy bills are paid by the landlord leaving the tenant with no incentive to moderate her energy use This is often the case for leased office space for example The energy efficiency principal agent problem applies in many cases to rented buildings and apartments but arises in other circumstances most often involving relatively high up front costs for energy efficient technology Though it is challenging to assess exactly the principal agent problem is considered to be a major barrier to the diffusion of efficient technologies This can be addressed in part by promoting shared savings performance based contracts where both parties benefit from the efficiency savings The issues of market barriers to energy efficiency and the principal agent problem in particular are receiving renewed attention because of the importance of global climate change and rising prices of the finite supply of fossil fuels 28 Trust relationships editThe problem arises in client attorney probate executor bankruptcy trustee and other such relationships In some rare cases attorneys who were entrusted with estate accounts with sizeable balances acted against the interests of the person who hired them to act as their agent by embezzling the funds or playing the market with the client s money with the goal of pocketing any proceeds citation needed This section can also be explored from the perspective of the trust game which captures the key elements of principal agent problems This game was first experimentally implemented by Berg Dickhaut and McCabe in 1995 29 The setup of the game is that there are two players trustor principal investor and agents investee The trustor is endowed with a budget and come transfer some of the amounts to an agent in expectation of return over the transferred amount in the future The trustee may send any part of the transferred amount back to the trustor The amount transferred back by the trustee is referred to as trustworthiness Most of the studies find that 45 of the endowment was transferred by the principal and around 33 transferred back by an agent This means that investors are not selfish and can be trusted for economic transactions Trust within the principal agent problem can also be seen from the perspective of an employer employee relationship whereby the employee agent has distrust in the employer principal which causes greater demotivation of the employee It has been assumed that the principal having control in an organisational culture has benefits to for the organisation by creating greater productivity and efficiency However it also entails some drawbacks that reduce the employee satisfaction such as reduced motivation creativity innovation and greater anxiety and stress 30 Personnel management editWhen managing personnel in an organisational setting the principal agent problem surfaces when employees are hired to perform specific tasks and fulfil certain roles In this environment the goals of employee and employer may not be aligned Often employees have the desire to further their own career or financial goals where employers often have the output interests of the organisation at the forefront of their actions and goals 31 Employees may reveal the principal agent problem in their work by slacking off and not meeting targets or KPIs and Employers may reveal the principal agent problem by implementing damaging policies or actions that make the working environment unsustainable 31 Bureaucracy and public administration editIn the context of public administration the principal agent problem can be seen in such a way where public administration and bureaucrats are the agents and politicians and ministers are the principal authorities 32 Ministers in the government usually command by framing policies and direct the bureaucrats to implement the public policies However there can be various principal agent problems in the scenario such as misaligned intentions information asymmetry adverse selection shirking and slippage There are various situations where the ambitions and goals of the principals and agents may diverge For example politicians and the government may want public administration to implement a welfare policy program but the bureaucrats may have other interests as well such as rent seeking This results in a lack of implementation of public policies hence the wastage of economic resources This can also lead to the problem of shirking which is characterized as avoidance of performing a defined responsibility by the agent The information asymmetry problem occurs in a scenario where one of the two people has more or less information than the other In the context of public administration bureaucrats have an information advantage over the government and ministers as the former work at the ground level and have more knowledge about the dynamic and changing situation Due to this government may frame policies that are not based on complete information and therefore problems in the implementation of public policies may occur This can also lead to the problem of slippage which is defined as a myth where the principal sees that agents are working according to the pre defined responsibilities but that might not be the reality 33 The problem of adverse selection is related to the selection of agents to fulfill particular responsibilities but they might deviate from doing so The prime cause behind this is the incomplete information available at the desk of selecting authorities principal about the agents they selected 34 For example the Ministry of Road and Transport Highways hired a private company to complete one of its road projects however it was later found that the company assigned to complete road projects lacked technical know how and had management issues The principal agent problem in the public sector arises when there is a disconnect between politicians and public servants and their goals and interests Other reasons that this occurs is because of political interference bureaucratic resistance and public accountability Political interference happens when the politicians try and influence the decisions of public servants or bureaucrats to try and push their own interests which ultimately leads to policies being warped 35 35 Bureaucratic Resistance is when public servants are hesitant to implement the policies that have been proposed or agreed on which ultimately causes policies to be implemented at a slow rate Bureaucratic resistance may be due to lack of funding resources or political support 35 Public accountability also plays a role in how the principal agent theory impacts the public sector When sworn in politicians and public servants are responsible for ensure that they act in the interest of the public that they represent or work for however due to budget and resourcing issues as well as lack of transparency trust in the public sector often falls and a major disconnect grows 35 Economic theory editIn economic theory the principal agent approach also called agency theory is part of the field contract theory 36 37 In agency theory it is typically assumed that complete contracts can be written an assumption also made in mechanism design theory Hence there are no restrictions on the class of feasible contractual arrangements between principal and agent Agency theory can be subdivided in two categories 1 In adverse selection models the agent has private information about their type say their costs of exerting effort or their valuation of a good before the contract is written 2 In moral hazard models the agent becomes privately informed after the contract is written Hart and Holmstrom 1987 divide moral hazard models in the categories hidden action e g the agent chooses an unobservable effort level and hidden information e g the agent learns their valuation of a good which is modelled as a random draw by nature 38 In hidden action models there is a stochastic relationship between the unobservable effort and the verifiable outcome say the principal s revenue because otherwise the unobservability of the effort would be meaningless Typically the principal makes a take it or leave it offer to the agent i e the principal has all bargaining power In principal agent models the agent often gets a strictly positive rent i e their payoff is larger than their reservation utility which they would get if no contract were written which means that the principal faces agency costs For example in adverse selection models the agent gets an information rent while in hidden action models with a wealth constrained agent the principal must leave a limited liability rent to the agent 36 In order to reduce the agency costs the principal typically induces a second best solution that differs from the socially optimal first best solution which would be attained if there were complete information If the agent had all bargaining power the first best solution would be achieved in adverse selection models with one sided private information as well as in hidden action models where the agent is wealth constrained Contract theoretic principal agent models have been applied in various fields including financial contracting 39 regulation 40 public procurement 41 monopolistic price discrimination 42 job design 43 internal labor markets 44 team production 45 and many others From the cybernetics point of view the Cultural Agency Theory arose in order to better understand the socio cultural nature of organisations and their behaviours Negotiation editIn the negotiation problem the principal commissions an agent to conduct negotiations on its behalf The principal may delegate certain authority to the agent including the ability to conclude negotiations and enter into binding contracts The principal may consider and assign a utility to each issue in the negotiation 46 However it is not always the case that the principal will explicitly inform the agent of what it considers to be the minimally acceptable terms otherwise known as the reservation price 47 The successfulness of a negotiation will be determined by a range of factors These include the negotiation objective the role of the negotiating parties the nature of the relationship between the negotiating parties the negotiating power of each party and the negotiation type Where there are information asymmetries between the principal and agent this can affect the outcome of the negotiation As it is impossible for a manager to attend all upcoming negotiations of the company it is common practice to assign internal or external negotiators to represent the negotiating company at the negotiation table With the principal agent problem two areas of negotiation emerge negotiations between the agent and the actual negotiating partner negotiations at the table internal negotiations as between the agent and the principal negotiations behind the table 48 The principal agent problem can arises in representative negotiations where the interests of the principal and the agent are misaligned The principal cannot directly observe the agent s efforts during the course of the negotiation In such circumstances this may lead to the agent employing negotiation tactics which are unfavourable to the principal but which benefit the agent Depending upon how the agent s reward is determined the principal may be able to effectively retain control over the agent If the agent receives a fixed fee the agent may nonetheless act in a manner that is inconsistent with the principal s interests The agent may adopt this strategy if they believe the negotiation is a one shot game The agent may adopt a different strategy if they account for reputational consequences of acting against the principal s interests Similarly if the negotiation is a repeated game and the principal is aware of the results of the first iteration the agent may opt to employ a different strategy which more closely aligns with the interests of the principal in order to ensure the principal will continue to contract with the agent in the following iterations If the agent s reward is dependent upon the outcome of the negotiation then this may help align the differing interests 49 In popular culture editThe Mamas amp the Papas 1967 song Creeque Alley refers to the principal agent problem in the lyric Broke busted disgusted agents can t be trusted See also editIron law of oligarchy Adverse selection Alignment problem Autonomous agency theory Bayesian persuasion a special case of a principal agent setting Contract theory Control fraud Cost overrun Fiduciary Honest services fraud Multiple principal problem Participative decision making Self dealing Structure and agency The Market for Lemons TrusteeReferences edit Eisenhardt K M 1989 Agency Theory An Assessment and Review The Academy of Management Review 14 1 57 74 doi 10 5465 amr 1989 4279003 JSTOR 258191 Adams Julia 1996 Principals and Agents Colonialists and Company Men The Decay of Colonial Control in the Dutch East Indies American Sociological Review 61 1 12 28 doi 10 2307 2096404 ISSN 0003 1224 JSTOR 2096404 Archived from the original on September 20 2022 Retrieved September 16 2022 Pay Without Performance Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried Harvard University Press 2004 preface and introduction Archived February 14 2019 at the Wayback Machine Agency Costs Investopedia Archived from the original on April 22 2019 Retrieved July 3 2012 Gailmard Sean 2014 Accountability and Principal Agent Theory The Oxford Handbook of Public Accountability Oxford University Press doi 10 1093 oxfordhb 9780199641253 013 0016 ISBN 978 0 19 964125 3 a b Voorn B Van Genugten M Van Thiel S 2019 Multiple principals multiple problems Implications for effective governance and a research agenda for joint service delivery Public Administration 97 3 671 685 doi 10 1111 padm 12587 hdl 2066 207394 Downes Alexander B 2021 Catastrophic success why foreign imposed regime change goes wrong Cornell University Press ISBN 978 1 5017 6116 4 OCLC 1252920900 Bernheim B D Whinston M D 1986 Common agency Econometrica Journal of the Econometric Society 54 4 923 doi 10 2307 1912844 JSTOR 1912844 Martimort D 1996 The multiprincipal nature of government European Economic Review 40 3 5 673 85 doi 10 1016 0014 2921 95 00079 8 Moe T M 2005 Power and political institutions Perspectives on Politics 3 2 doi 10 1017 S1537592705050176 S2CID 39072417 Potucek M 2017 Public Policy A Comprehensive Introduction Prague Charles University Karolinum Press Mitnick Barry M January 2006 Origin of the Theory of Agency Archived from the original on March 7 2021 Retrieved April 20 2015 Jensen Michael C Meckling William H October 1976 Theory of the firm Managerial behavior agency costs and ownership structure PDF Journal of Financial Economics 3 4 305 360 doi 10 1016 0304 405X 76 90026 X Archived PDF from the original on March 20 2021 Retrieved September 8 2017 Pendergast Canice 1999 The Provision of Incentives in Firms Journal of Economic Literature 37 1 7 63 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 558 6657 doi 10 1257 jel 37 1 7 JSTOR 2564725 Paula Szuchman Jenny Anderson It s Not You It s the Dishes originally published as Spousonomics How to Minimize Conflict and Maximize Happiness in Your Relationship Random House Digital Inc June 12 2012 Page 210 Accessed on May 31 2013 Only the tip but size is important The Age December 11 2004 Archived from the original on April 1 2016 Retrieved July 23 2013 Crifo Patricia INCENTIVES IN AGENCY RELATIONSHIPS TO BE MONETARY OR NON MONETARY PDF Retrieved October 29 2020 dead link Pink Daniel H 2009 Drive The Surprising Truth about What Motivates Us New York Riverhead Books ISBN 9781594488849 Haubrich Joseph 1994 Risk Aversion Performance Pay and the Principal Agent Problem Journal of Political Economy 102 2 258 276 doi 10 1086 261931 S2CID 15450754 Retrieved October 29 2020 Jensen M C Murphy K J Performance Pay and Top Management Incentives a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Moral Hazard and Observability Archived April 27 2021 at the Wayback Machine The Bell Journal of Economics Vol 10 No 1 Spring 1979 pp 74 91 Aswath Damodaran Applications Of Option Pricing Theory To Equity Valuation Archived April 27 2012 at the Wayback Machine and Option Pricing Applications in Valuation Archived September 16 2012 at the Wayback Machine D Mauer and S Sarkar 2001 Real Options Agency Conflicts and Financial Policy Archived March 4 2016 at the Wayback Machine G Siller Pagaza G Otalora E Cobas Flores 2006 The Impact of Real Options in Agency Problems Archived June 2 2016 at the Wayback Machine S Nagel and A Purnanandam 2017 Bank Risk Dynamics and Distance to Default Archived April 23 2023 at the Wayback Machine S Peleg Lazar and A Raviv 2017 Bank Risk Dynamics Where Assets are Risky Debt Claims Archived August 5 2017 at the Wayback Machine Nielson Williams Personal Economics 3 ed TENNESSEE KNOXVILLE Pearson Education pp 107 118 Jaffe Adam B Stavins Robert N 1994 The energy efficiency gap What does it mean PDF Energy Policy 22 10 805 doi 10 1016 0301 4215 94 90138 4 Archived PDF from the original on May 1 2019 Retrieved May 1 2019 Mind the Gap IEA Archived from the original on May 1 2019 Retrieved May 1 2019 Berg J Dickhaut J amp McCabe K 1995 Trust Reciprocity and Social History Games and Economic Behavior 10 1 122 142 doi 10 1006 game 1995 1027 Falk Armin Kosfeld Michael December 2006 The Hidden Costs of Control American Economic Review 96 5 1611 1630 doi 10 1257 aer 96 5 1611 ISSN 0002 8282 Archived from the original on March 8 2023 Retrieved March 8 2023 a b Baker Rose M 2019 The Agency of the Principal Agent Relationship An Opportunity for HRD Advances in Developing Human Resources 21 3 303 318 doi 10 1177 1523422319851274 S2CID 197688734 Potucek M 2017 Public Policy A Comprehensive Introduction Prague Karolinum Press Charles University Lane J E amp Kivisto J 2008 Interests Information and Incentives in Higher Education Principal Agent Theory and Its Potential Applications to the Study of Higher Education Governance Higher Education Handbook of Theory and Research Garba et al 2020 Government Higher Education Institutions Relationship Vide the Lens of the Principal Agent Theory The 27th International Business Information Management Association Conference pp 1 11 Milan International Business Information Management Association a b c d Wood B Dan October 14 2010 Agency Theory and the Bureaucracy Oxford University Press doi 10 1093 oxfordhb 9780199238958 003 0008 a b Laffont Jean Jacques Martimort David 2002 The theory of incentives The principal agent model Princeton University Press Bolton Patrick Dewatripont Matthias 2005 Contract theory MIT Press Hart Oliver Holmstrom Bengt 1987 The theory of contracts In Bewley T ed Advances in Economics and Econometrics Cambridge University Press pp 71 155 Tirole Jean 2006 The theory of corporate finance Princeton University Press Baron David P Myerson Roger B 1982 Regulating a Monopolist with Unknown Costs Econometrica 50 4 911 930 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 407 6185 doi 10 2307 1912769 JSTOR 1912769 Schmitz Patrick W 2013 Public procurement in times of crisis The bundling decision reconsidered Economics Letters 121 3 533 536 doi 10 1016 j econlet 2013 10 015 Maskin Eric Riley John 1984 Monopoly with Incomplete Information RAND Journal of Economics 15 2 171 196 JSTOR 2555674 Schmitz Patrick W 2013 Job design with conflicting tasks reconsidered European Economic Review 57 108 117 doi 10 1016 j euroecorev 2012 11 001 Krakel Matthias Schottner Anja 2012 Internal labor markets and worker rents Journal of Economic Behavior amp Organization 84 2 491 509 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 320 692 doi 10 1016 j jebo 2012 08 008 Homstrom Bengt 1982 Moral hazard in teams Bell Journal of Economics 13 2 324 340 doi 10 2307 3003457 JSTOR 3003457 Piasecki Krzysztof Roszkowska Ewa Wachowicz Tomasz Filipowicz Chomko Marzena Lyczkowska Hanckowiak Anna July 29 2021 Fuzzy Representation of Principal s Preferences in Inspire Negotiation Support System Entropy 23 8 981 Bibcode 2021Entrp 23 981P doi 10 3390 e23080981 ISSN 1099 4300 PMC 8392366 PMID 34441121 Lax David A Sebenius James K September 1991 Negotiating Through an Agent Journal of Conflict Resolution 35 3 474 493 doi 10 1177 0022002791035003004 ISSN 0022 0027 S2CID 143173392 Archived from the original on May 2 2022 Retrieved May 2 2022 Jung Stefanie Krebs Peter 15 June 2019 The Essentials of Contract Negotiation Springer International Publishing doi 10 1007 978 3 030 12866 1 Archived May 2 2022 at the Wayback Machine Miller Gary J Whitford Andrew B April 1 2002 Trust and Incentives in Principal Agent Negotiations The Insurance Incentive Trade Off Journal of Theoretical Politics 14 2 231 267 doi 10 1177 095169280201400204 ISSN 0951 6298 S2CID 17436198 Archived from the original on January 20 2023 Retrieved May 2 2022 Further reading editAzfar Omar 2007 Chapter 8 Disrupting Corruption PDF In Shah Anwar ed Performance Accountability and Combating Corruption World Bank doi 10 1596 978 0 8213 6941 8 hdl 10986 6732 ISBN 9780821369418 Eisenhardt K 1989 Agency theory An assessment and review Academy of Management Review 14 1 57 74 doi 10 5465 amr 1989 4279003 JSTOR 258191 Gailmard Sean 2014 Accountability and Principal Agent Theory in The Oxford Handbook of Public Accountability Oxford University Press Green J R Stokey N L 1983 A Comparison of Tournaments and Contracts Journal of Political Economy 91 3 349 64 doi 10 1086 261153 JSTOR 1837093 S2CID 18043549 Mind the Gap Quantifying Principal Agent Problems in Energy Efficiency PDF IEA 2007 archived from the original PDF on September 30 2018 retrieved February 7 2013 Laffont Jean Jacques and Martimort David 2002 The Theory of Incentives The Principal Agent Model Princeton University Press Miller Gary 2005 The Political Evolution of Principal Agent Models Annual Review of Political Science 8 203 25 Nikkinen Jussi Sahlstrom Petri 2004 Does agency theory provide a general framework for audit pricing International Journal of Auditing 8 3 253 262 doi 10 1111 j 1099 1123 2004 00094 x Rees R 1985 The Theory of Principal and Agent Part I Bulletin of Economic Research 37 1 3 26 Rees R 1985 The Theory of Principal and Agent Part II Bulletin of Economic Research 37 2 75 97 Rutherford R amp Springer T amp Yavas A 2005 Conflicts between Principals and Agents Evidence from Residential Brokerage Journal of Financial Economics 76 627 65 Rosen S 1986 Prizes and Incentives in Elimination Tournaments American Economic Review 76 4 701 715 JSTOR 1806068 Sappington David E M 1991 Incentives in Principal Agent Relationships Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 2 45 66 doi 10 1257 jep 5 2 45 JSTOR 1942685 Stiglitz Joseph E 1987 Principal and agent The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics v 3 pp 966 71 External links edit nbsp Quotations related to Principal agent problem at Wikiquote Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Principal agent problem amp oldid 1207868667, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.