fbpx
Wikipedia

Ethnic enclave

In sociology, an ethnic enclave is a geographic area with high ethnic concentration, characteristic cultural identity, and economic activity.[2] The term is usually used to refer to either a residential area or a workspace with a high concentration of ethnic firms.[3] Their success and growth depends on self-sufficiency, and is coupled with economic prosperity.

Ethnic enclaves
Binondo, Manila, the world’s oldest Chinatown,[1] is an example of an ethnic enclave.

The theory of social capital and the formation of migrant networks creates the social foundation for ethnic enclaves. Douglas Massey describes how migrant networks provide new immigrants with social capital that can be transferred to other tangible forms.[4] As immigrants tend to cluster in close geographic spaces, they develop migrant networks—systems of interpersonal relations through which participants can exchange valuable resources and knowledge. Immigrants can capitalize on social interactions by transforming information into tangible resources, and thereby lower costs of migration. Information exchanged may include knowledge of employment opportunities, affordable housing, government assistance programs and helpful NGOs.[5] Thus by stimulating social connections, ethnic enclaves generate a pool of intangible resources that help to promote the social and economic development of its members.[5]

By providing a space for individuals who share the same ethnic identity to create potentially beneficial relations, ethnic enclaves assist members in achieving economic mobility. Enclaves create an alternative labor market that is ethnic-specific and does not demand social and cultural skills of the host country. By eliminating language and cultural barriers, enclave economies employ a greater proportion of co-ethnics and speed the incorporation of new immigrants into a bustling economy. By increasing employment opportunities and facilitating upward mobility, studying ethnic enclaves helps to explain the success of some immigrant groups.[3] Additionally, while the ethnic enclave theory was developed to explain immigrant incorporation into the receiving society, it has also been linked to migration processes at large as successful incorporation of immigrants has the potential to lower migration costs for future immigrants, an example of chain migration.

Despite their immediate benefits, the long-term implications of participation in an ethnic enclave are a topic of debate. Enclave economies have been linked to a glass ceiling limiting immigrant growth and upward mobility. While participation in the enclave economy may assist in achieving upward mobility through increased availability of employment opportunities in the enclave labor market, it may also impede acquisition of host country skills that benefit the immigrant over the long-run.[6] Such delays constrain immigrants to activity within the enclave and secludes them from the larger economy. Opportunities available to mainstream society can thus be out of reach for immigrants who haven't learned about them. Thus, the accelerated path toward economic mobility that lures new immigrants into enclave economies may impede success. Integration into an ethnic enclave may delay and even halt cultural assimilation, preventing the immigrants from benefiting from mainstream institutions.[7]

History

 
New York City is home to the largest overseas Chinese population of any city proper in the Western Hemisphere, with over half a million. Multiple large Chinatowns in Manhattan, Brooklyn (above), and Queens are thriving as traditionally urban ethnic enclaves, as large-scale Chinese immigration continues into New York,[8][9][10][11] with the largest metropolitan Chinese population outside Asia.[12]
 
Broad Avenue, Koreatown in Palisades Park, New Jersey, United States,[13] where Koreans comprise the majority (52%) of the population.[14]
 
India Square in Jersey City, New Jersey, one of 24 Indian ethnic enclaves in the New York City Metropolitan Area.

Ethnic enclaves have been prominent urban features for centuries. Examples include a new Armenian one near Beirut, an old one in Bucharest,[15] and an even older Armenian Quarter in Jerusalem.[16] Urban quarters have often belonged mainly to residents having a particular sectarian or ethnic origin.

Historically, the formation of ethnic enclaves has been the result of a variety of socioeconomic factors that draw immigrants to similar spaces in the receiving city, state, or country. Cultural diversity brings together people who don't understand each other's language but a group can communicate more easily with neighbors in an enclave. In some cases, enclaves have been enforced by law, as in a ghetto. Roman colonies were established to control newly conquered provinces, and grew to absorb the surrounding territory. Some enclaves were established when a governing authority permitted a group to establish their own new town, as in the English town of Gravesend, Brooklyn in 1645.

The lack of access to economic capital and of knowledge regarding residential neighborhoods can constrain newly arrived immigrants to regions of affordable housing. Social dynamics such as prejudice and racism may concentrate co-ethnics into regions displaying ethnic similarity. Housing discrimination may also prevent ethnic minorities from settling into a particular residential area outside the enclave. When discussing the ethnic enclave as defined by a spatial cluster of businesses, success and growth can be largely predicted by three factors. These factors include 1) the size and population of the enclave 2) the level of entrepreneurial skills of those in the enclave and 3) the availability of capital resources to the enclave. Successful enclaves can reach a point where they become self-sufficient, or "institutionally complete" through the supply of new immigrants and demand of goods offered in the market. They only reach this point after first supplying for the needs of co-ethnics and then expanding to meet needs of those in the larger market of the host society.[17]

The term "ethnic enclave" arose in response to a publication by Alejandro Portes and Kenneth Wilson in 1980.[18] Portes and Wilson identified a third labor market in which Cuban immigrants in Miami took part. Instead of entering the secondary labor market of the host society, Portes and Wilson discovered that new immigrants tended to become employed by co-ethnics running immigrant-owned firms. The collection of small immigrant enterprises providing employment to new immigrants was defined as the enclave economy.[19]

Theories

Enclave economy hypothesis

Observations of the Cuban ethnic enclave economy in Miami led Alejandro Portes and Kenneth Wilson to conclude that participation in an enclave economy provided immigrants with an alternative, speedy option to achieve economic mobility in a host society. The discourse pioneered by Portes and Wilson produced the construct for a body of literature that came to be known by the ethnic enclave hypothesis. While never empirically defined, the term "ethnic enclave" began to be widely used to represent two distinct definitions: that of an enclave economy and that of a residential area of high co-ethnic concentration.[3] The most fundamental concept within the enclave hypothesis is that of social capital, which lays the foundation for the establishment of migrant networks and the advantages associated with them.[5]

Cumulative causation

With the rise in globalization and ease of international transportation, patterns of immigration show the role of ethnic enclaves for contributing to increased migration over time. New immigrants unintentionally lower costs for future immigration of co-ethnics by pooling together resources for themselves. Thus, by achieving mobility in the receiving country themselves, immigrants create a social structure that makes it easier for future immigrants to become upwardly mobile. According to Douglas Massey, "Networks build into the migration process a self-perpetuating momentum that leads to its growth over time, in spite of fluctuating wage differentials, recessions, and increasingly restrictive immigration policies."[4] Ethnic enclaves thus contribute to continued immigration by providing co-ethnics with a space to make connections that ultimately lower migration costs and promote economic mobility. Many worn path taken by former immigrants are made accessible to enclave members, making immigration easier to future generations. By generating further immigration, migration leads to its own cumulative causation over time.

Modes of incorporation

An approach that analyzes ethnic enclaves and their members by their modes of incorporation is preferred to a neoclassical model, which states that the economic success of immigrants depends on the education, work experience, and other elements of human capital that they possess.[17] Sociologists have concluded that these factors do not suffice in explaining the integration and success of immigrants measured by occupational mobility and earnings.

Social

Upon arrival to a foreign country, immigrants face challenges in assimilation and integration processes and thus experience different modes and levels of incorporation within the host society. Many factors influence the level of ease or challenge experienced by immigrants as they make the transition and undergo physical, social, and psychological challenges. The segmented assimilation model notes that there can exist a "consciously pluralistic society in which a variety of subcultures and racial and ethnic identities coexist" [20][21]

One influential factor in an immigrant's journey is the presence of relatives or friends in the receiving country. Friends and family, making up a kinship network, who are willing to help the newcomers can be classified as a type of capital commonly referred to as social capital. Upon arrival, many immigrants have limited or no access to human capital and thus rely heavily on any available source of social capital.[17] The cost to immigration is large, however this burden can be shared and thus eased through an immigrant's access to social capital in the receiving country. Kinship networks in the receiving country can provide aid not only for the physical and economic needs of immigrants, but also for their emotional and socio-psychological needs.[22]

Quality of kinship networks

Access to social capital does not guarantee ease or success for the migrant. Because social capital is rooted in relationships it easily lends itself to conflict and disagreement between parties.[22] The level of economic stability on the side of the receiving party can dictate the level of aid they are willing or able to offer. In addition, the economic condition of the country and the availability of jobs open to the immigrants can largely affect the quality of the support network available to the migrant. If the receiving country provides favorable conditions such as access to social programs, the local economy, and employment opportunities, the network is likely to be of much higher quality. Adversely, kinship networks may break down if much stress is placed on the relationships involved due to economic hardships. The duration and intensity of aid needed can dictate the quality of the kinship network available to the immigrant. Immigrant ideas regarding level of support to be received are often high and left unmet if true economic conditions do not allow for favorable network conditions.[22] Shared norms and relational ties can also lead to obligatory ties which some scholars, such as Tsang and Inkpen, argue restricts an individual's willingness to explore opportunities outside the network.[23]

Ethnic identity

Methods of assimilation and access to social capital vary between and even within ethnic groups. A variety of factors can influence individuals' ethnic identities including their social class background and the social networks available to them. As theorized by sociologist Mary C. Waters, the involvement level of parents in ethnic organizations or activities heavily influences the development of their children's ethnic identities. This is important to note as second-generation immigrants must actively work to identify themselves with their ethnic group.[20]

Enclave networks

Enclave networks offer access to a unique type of social capital and act as large kinship networks. Within enclave networks, social capital commonly exists both as a private and public good.[23] Though there is some debate in relation to the long-term benefits offered by these networks, the short-term benefits are universally acknowledged. The socio-psychological challenges faced by the immigrant can be largely reduced through the individual's entrance into an ethnic enclave. Ethnic enclaves can resemble the immigrant's place of origin through physical look, layout, and language employed both written and orally.[17] In addition to increasing the cultural comfort of the migrant, healthy ethnic enclaves offer solidarity and trust among members, and informal training systems within the workplace. The geographic proximity of the enclave network allows for easy flow of knowledge and varying types of assistance between firms as well. Where there is an atmosphere of trust in ethnic enclaves, this transfer of knowledge and sharing of social capital exists as an asset to the firms.[23] Connections with members in an enclave may also afford the newcomer work opportunities. Immigrants may also receive informal training regarding the customs and practices of the larger culture outside the enclave and help navigating challenges in many areas of everyday life.[17] Social hostility may be a challenge faced by immigrants in their host society, therefore to avoid this factor, ethnic enclaves provide a haven where economic success may still be achieved.[7]

Economic

Ethnic enclave economies are predicated upon aspects of economic sociology and the sociology of immigration. Ethnic Enclaves generate a pool of social capital through which members can access resources that lower the costs of migration. Enclave membership provides economic assistance such as job opportunities and small businesses loans. Small ethnic firms within the enclave provide new immigrants with immediate access to economic opportunities by subverting the secondary sector of the economy and creating numerous low-wage jobs that are easily accessed by members.[17][24] The ethno-centric nature of businesses and firms provides easy integration into enclave economies. Goods and services tend to be offered in the ethnic group's language, while social and cultural norms specific to the host country are not required of employees in the enclave economy. Thus, the ethno-specific nature of enclave economies makes them attractive to new immigrants who are otherwise unable integrate into the mainstream economy.

Ethnic enclave economies also provide a method for immigrants who enter at lower wage jobs to rise to the status community entrepreneurs own firms within the community. While benefiting from the higher wages that owning a business provides them, these established immigrants continue the cycle of providing attractive (albeit lower income) labor to newcomers within the framework of the ethnic enclave.[25] The ethnic enclave economy allows for a measure of independence for immigrants by creating a path for them to own businesses.[26] Ethnic enclave economies also have the effect of raising the hourly wages of workers within the enclave.[27]

An individual's entrance into the enclave economy is dependent upon the conditions of incorporation they experience. Unfavorable modes of incorporation into the host society provide incentives for immigrants to enter the informal economy. Discrimination, hostility, and a lack of resources may encourage immigrants to enter into informal employment.[17] Ethnic enclaves are rich in informal activities, as the entrepreneurial services making the core of the enclave's founding were historically informal ventures. Informality proves favorable for many immigrant entrepreneurs by bypass regulatory expenses. Additionally, the scope of employment for immigrants is greatly widened by the availability of informal jobs in the enclave economic sector. The informality of the enclave economy simultaneously induces risk and fraud. Informal activities are constantly under risk of detection by the formal sector, which has a negative effect on job security. Furthermore, due to the absence of legal framework, immigrant laborers often remain silent about various forms of exploitation. The most common form of labor exploitation in immigrant economies is unpaid labor. Undocumented immigrants are especially afraid to report violations of labor laws and exploitation.[28]

Political and civic involvement

Government policy toward immigrants is the first mode of reception to the receiving country.[3] Governments generally enforce measures to reduce the amount of "unwanted" immigrants which may potentially pose a burden on the receiving society and economy.[29]

The granting of different statuses and visas (i.e. refugee, temporary visas for students and workers) to immigrant groups affects the type of reception immigrants will receive. Aside from immigration control policies, some governments also impose measures to accelerate social and political incorporation of new immigrants, and to stimulate economic mobility.

Wayne Cornelius studies two central theses regarding institutional response to increased movement of people across transnational borders. The first of these is the gap hypothesis which describes the dissonance between official immigration policies and real policy outcomes. Policy gaps are the result of unintended consequences and inadequate enforcement by the receiving society. Many reasons can explain unintended consequences of immigration policy. Governments with undefined or ambiguous stances toward immigration may propagate unintended consequences, and the reliance on flawed policies can further reduce the efficacy of institutional measures. Furthermore, political incoherency policy poses a greater challenge for the incorporation and enforcement of effective measures.

A negative public opinion toward immigrants is a good measure of significant policy gaps in the receiving government; however, special interest groups may also constrain political responses to immigration. This is especially true in liberal democracies, where "lobbying by powerful employer groups, religious groups, ethnic and immigrant advocacy groups, and even labor unions leads governments to adopt more expansionary immigration policies, even when the economy goes bad and general public opinion turns hostile to immigrants."[30] Furthermore, governments and special groups in the immigrant-sending country may align themselves with pro-immigration lobbyists in the receiving country. Thus, the policymaking process is complicated by involvement of multiple factions.

The second thesis studied by Wayne Cornelius is the convergence hypothesis, which describes the growing similarity of political responses to immigration among immigrant-receiving countries. These similarities fall into: "(1) the policies that their governments have adopted to control immigration; (2) policies designed to integrate immigrants into host societies by providing them with social services as well as political, economic, and social rights; and (3) attitudes toward immigrants and immigration policy preferences among general publics."[31]

Ethnic groups receive various levels of reception by the host society for various reasons. In general, European immigrants tend to encounter little resistance by host countries, while tenets of racism are evinced by widespread resistance to immigrants of color.[17]

Political incorporation into the host country is coupled with adoption of citizenship of the host country. By studying the diverging trajectories of immigrant citizenship in Canada and the U.S., Irene Bloemraad explains that current models of citizenship acquisition fail to recognize the social nature of political incorporation. Bloemraad describes political incorporation as a "social process of mobilization by friends, family, community organizations and local leaders that is embedded in an institutional context shaped by government policies of diversity and newcomer settlement."[32] This alternative model emphasizes the role of migrant networks in critically shaping how immigrants consider citizenship. Bloemraad shows that friends, family, co-ethnic organizations and local community affect political incorporation by providing a structured mobilization framework. This social structure is most essential for immigrants who face language barriers and may lack familiarity with host institutions.

The extent to which migrant networks promote citizenship depends on the efficacy of government policies on immigrant integration. Governments adopting policies that facilitate the emergence, integration and growth of ethnic economies are presumed to gain support by co-ethnics. Thus, the movement toward political incorporation and citizenship is nested in a larger institutional structure involving economic and social integration policy as these relate to immigrants.[32] Ethnic enclaves have the ability to simultaneously assist in political and civic incorporation of immigrants. By providing a space that facilitates upward mobility and economic integration into the receiving society, enclaves and their members fundamentally influence the perceptions of receiving institutions by co-ethnics. Finally, enclaves may gauge community interest in naturalization and direct immigrants through the process to gaining citizenship

Ethnic enclave debate

The discourse surrounding ethnic enclaves has prompted debate among scholars in two related areas of thought. Both areas discuss the role ethnic enclaves play by either offering aid or hindering the economic and social well-being of the enclave's members. One area of thought discusses the role of enclaves in assimilative patterns and upward mobility while the second area of thought argues the economic ramifications associated with membership within ethnic enclaves.

The immediate economic and social advantages associated with membership in an ethnic enclave are undisputed by scholars, however the long-term consequences remain an area of uncertainty. The role these networks play remains uncertain due to the fact that ethnic enclaves allow immigrants to function successfully within the host society without a significant amount of adjustment either culturally or linguistically. As such, they can either help or hinder naturalization within the host country. The relatively low levels of skill required allow immigrants to achieve financial stability which can in turn encourage eventual naturalization and assimilation. Adversely, this same factor can afford enclave members the opportunity to remain considerably segregated and secluded from the host society. As such, members may circumvent the need to acquire skills necessary for life in the larger host society such as knowledge of cultural norms and language.[33]

The debate regarding the economic viability of ethnic enclaves revolves around the enclave-economy hypothesis. The hypothesis as written by Wilson and Portes formulates the idea that "[i]mmigrant workers are not restricted to the secondary labor market." They instead argue that "those inserted into an immigrant enclave can be empirically distinguished from workers in both the primary and secondary labor markets. Enclave workers will share with those in the primary sector a significant economic return past human capital investments" something those who enter the secondary labor market are not able to enjoy.[7][34] Thus, they assert the enclave economy is not a mobility trap as some would term it, but an alternate mode of incorporation.

In their argument formulated to disprove the enclave economy hypothesis, Sanders and Nee state the need for a distinction between "immigrant-bosses" and "immigrant-workers" as the economic benefits differ along this distinction.[35] They also call for the investigation of economic opportunities available to those in the enclave, believing them to be lesser in quality and supply. Sanders and Nee also assert the idea that segregation and forced entrance of immigrant-workers into low paying jobs is actually aggravated by the existence of ethnic enclaves. Due to these objections, they call for the revision of Portes and Wilson's hypothesis to include an acknowledgement and outline of the entrepreneur/worker economic benefit distinction.

In reaction to Sanders and Nee, Portes and Jensen make the clarification that those in ethnic enclaves need not be wealthier than those who left the enclave for the hypothesis to be supported. They instead assert that this will usually not be the case as the constant entrance of new immigrants into the enclave will actually be somewhat burdensome on the economy; a factor which does not actually represent disadvantage when compared with the other advantages provided.[3] Additionally, Portes and Jensen outline three different conditions to be fulfilled in order to disprove their hypothesis. The first of these conditions requires the demonstration that ethnic entrepreneurship is a mobility trap leading to lower earnings than the immigrant's worth in human capital. The second condition requires data proving the work within the enclave to be exploitative, and the third condition requires data showing employment within the enclave leads to a 'dead end' and offers no chance of upward mobility.[3] They acknowledge that the fulfillment of these three requirements is difficult as there is little data available to accurately test them.

Jennifer Lee adds to the discussion noting the particular niches and types of business immigrant groups enter. She notes that it is most common for immigrants to participate in long hours of physically demanding work in the retail industry. The retail market is a viable option due to the relatively low startup costs and knowledge of the host country's language required. Different niches have different levels of communication, for example the retail and self-service niche, (fruit and vegetable markets, take out restaurants) typically require the lowest level of customer interaction and communication. Lee notes the embeddedness of ethnic enclaves and brings the thought that such practices are good for those within the enclave but harmful to certain groups outside them.[36] She also notes the adverse effects patterns of ethnic embeddedness can have on surrounding ethnic groups by noting the difficulty other groups face in joining the network. She argues that this type of retail niche domination can have positive consequences for co-ethnics, as Portes and Wilson believe, however can also have negative effects on surrounding ethnic groups who face exclusion due solely to their ethnic dissimilarity from the network.[36]

Ethnic enclaves in the United States

Immigration to the United States has occurred in waves that demonstrate the predominance of certain sets of ethnic minorities. As immigrants tended to cluster in certain cities and states, separate waves were responsible for the establishment of ethnic enclaves in separate physical spaces. The best-known ethnic enclaves in American cities began to appear with the arrival of large numbers of Irish immigrants during the first third of the nineteenth century and continued forming throughout that century and the twentieth as successive waves of immigrants arrived in the United States.[37] In the early 20th century, immigrants chose to live in enclave neighborhoods because of language barriers and cost-of-living benefits. Sociologists Robert Park and Edward Burgess integrated a model that studied these patterns in the 1920s. This model showcased how immigrants who arrived in the U.S. in the early 20th century were drawn to urban enclave neighborhoods as they opened up opportunities for social networking and employment. [38]

In 1998, nearly three quarters of all immigrants in the United States lived in California, New York, Texas, Florida, New Jersey or Illinois.[39] Housing discrimination remains a factor in the persistence of racial enclaves in American cities.[40][41] However, more recent patterns of migration, such as chain migration, challenge traditional methods of enclaves establishment.

Historical ethnic enclaves

Ethnic enclaves have become commonplace in modern times, with the increase in the geographic mobility of humankind. However, they have also arisen in historical times, for various reasons. The village of Schandorf, now in Austria, was for centuries a Croatian ethnic enclave, surrounded by areas of Austrian and Hungarian ethnicity. The enclave originated around 1543 when the Hungarian magnate Batthyany sought to repopulate lands that had been emptied by devastating Turkish attacks; he invited Croatian settlers.[42] The town of Alghero in Sardinia still marginally preserves a Catalan ethnic enclave; this dates from a military conquest of the town by Catalans in the 14th century.[43] Ethnic enclaves also arose when a people remained in its original territory but came to be surrounded by a far more numerous majority, as in the case of Vepsians and Russians. Many of New York's neighborhoods were once Italian neighborhoods, to the point of New York in the nineteenth and twentieth century once having an Italian population larger than that of Rome, the Italian capital at the time.[citation needed]

See also

References

  1. ^ Prime Sarmiento (May 21, 2018). "Exploring world's 'oldest' Chinatown". China Daily. Retrieved October 12, 2022.
  2. ^ Abrahamson, Mark . "Urban Enclaves: Identity and Place in America." Review by: David M. Hummon. Contemporary Sociology. American Sociological Association. Vol. 25 No. 6 (Nov. 1996): pp. 781-782.
  3. ^ a b c d e f Portes, Alejandro, and Leif Jensen. "Disproving the Enclave Hypothesis: Reply." American Sociological Review. Vol. 57. no. 3 (1992): 418-420.
  4. ^ a b Massey, Douglas S. (1990). The Social and Economic Origins of Immigration. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 510(1), 60–72. https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716290510001005: pp. 60.
  5. ^ a b c Massey, Douglas S. "Why Does Immigration Occur? A Theoretical Synthesis." The Handbook of International Migration: The American Experience, Charles Hirschman, Philip Kasinitz, and Josh DeWind, editors. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1999.
  6. ^ Edin, Per-Anders, Peter Fredriksson, and Olof Aslund. "ETHNIC ENCLAVES AND THE ECONOMIC SUCCESS OF IMMIGRANTS—EVIDENCE FROM A NATURAL EXPERIMENT." The Quarterly Journal of Economics. no. 1 (2003): 329-357.
  7. ^ a b c Sanders, Jimy M. and Nee, Victor. "Limits of Ethnic Solidarity in the Enclave Economy." American Sociological Review. 52. no. 6 (1987): 745-773.
  8. ^ "Yearbook of Immigration Statistics: 2012 Supplemental Table 2". U.S. Department of Homeland Security. Retrieved 2014-04-05.
  9. ^ "Yearbook of Immigration Statistics: 2011 Supplemental Table 2". U.S. Department of Homeland Security. Retrieved 2014-04-05.
  10. ^ "Yearbook of Immigration Statistics: 2010 Supplemental Table 2". U.S. Department of Homeland Security. Retrieved 2014-04-05.
  11. ^ John Marzulli (May 9, 2011). "Malaysian man smuggled illegal Chinese immigrants into Brooklyn using Queen Mary 2: authorities". New York: © Copyright 2012 NY Daily News.com. Retrieved 2014-04-05.
  12. ^ "Chinese New Year 2012 in Flushing". QueensBuzz.com. January 25, 2012. Retrieved 2014-04-05.
  13. ^ Asian Americans: Contemporary Trends and Issues Second Edition, Edited by Pyong Gap Min. Pine Forge Press – An Imprint of Sage Publications, Inc. 2006. ISBN 9781412905565. Retrieved 2012-11-15.
  14. ^ Karen Sudol; Dave Sheingold (October 12, 2011). "Korean language ballots coming to Bergen County". North Jersey Media Group. Retrieved 2012-11-15.
  15. ^ "Bucharest Armenian Neighbourhood". Interesting Times Bureau. 2016-09-18. Retrieved 2019-11-03.
  16. ^ Deyirmenjian, Sevan (6 May 2013). . Jamanak (in Armenian). Istanbul. Archived from the original on 28 March 2016. ...պաշտօնապէս իսկ կոչուելով «Հայոց թաղ» անունով:{{cite news}}: CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link) ()
    . armenische-kirche.ch (in Armenian). Zürich: Diocese of the Armenian Apostolic Church in the German Switzerland. Archived from the original on 25 March 2016. Retrieved 11 November 2015. Իսկ հայոց թաղի բնակիչները...(, )
  17. ^ a b c d e f g h Portes, Alejandro (1995). "Chapter 1: Economic Sociology and the Sociology of Immigration: A conceptual Overview". In Portes, Alejandro (ed.). The Economic Sociology of Immigration. Russel Sage Foundation. pp. 1–41.
  18. ^ Waldinger, Roger. "The Ethnic Enclave Debate Revisited."International Journal of Urban and Regional Research. 17. no. 3 (1993): 428-436.
  19. ^ Portes, Alejandro, and Kenneth Wilson. "Immigrant Enclaves: An Analysis of the Labor Market Experiences of Cubans in Miami." American Journal of Sociology. 86. no. 2 (1980): 295-319.
  20. ^ a b Waters, Mary C. "Ethnic and Racial Identities of Second-Generation Black Immigrants in New York City." International Migration Review. 28. no. 4 (1994): 795-820.
  21. ^ Waters, p. 799.
  22. ^ a b c Menjívar, Cecilia. "Immigrant Kinship Networks and the Impact of the Receiving Context: Salvadorans in San Francisco in the Early 1990s." Social Problems. 44. no. 1 (1997): 104-123.
  23. ^ a b c Inkpen, C. Andrew and Tsang, W. K. Eric. "Social Capital, Networks, and Knowledge Transfer" The Academy of Management Review. Vol 30. No. 1 (1992): 146-165.
  24. ^ Light, Ivan; Sabagh, Georges; Bozorgmehr, Mehdi; Der-Martirosian, Claudia (1994). "Beyond the Ethnic Enclave Economy". Social Problems. 41 (1): 65–80. doi:10.2307/3096842. ISSN 0037-7791. JSTOR 3096842.
  25. ^ Light, Ivan; Sabagh, Georges; Bozorgmehr, Mehdi; Der-Martirosian, Claudia (1994). "Beyond the Ethnic Enclave Economy". Social Problems. 41 (1): 65–80. doi:10.2307/3096842. ISSN 0037-7791. JSTOR 3096842.
  26. ^ Sanders, Jimy M.; Nee, Victor (1996). "Immigrant Self-Employment: The Family as Social Capital and the Value of Human Capital". American Sociological Review. 61 (2): 231–249. doi:10.2307/2096333. ISSN 0003-1224. JSTOR 2096333.
  27. ^ Damm, Anna Piil (2009). "Ethnic Enclaves and Immigrant Labor Market Outcomes: Quasi‐Experimental Evidence". Journal of Labor Economics. 27 (2): 281–314. doi:10.1086/599336. ISSN 0734-306X. JSTOR 10.1086/599336. S2CID 17521852.
  28. ^ Hondagneu-Sotelo, Pierrette. "Blowups and Other Unhappy Endings" in Global Woman: Nannies, Maids, and Sex Workers in the New Economy by Barbara Enrehnreich and Arlie Hochschild. New York: Henry Holt and Company, 2002.
  29. ^ Cornelius, Wayne A. Controlling Immigration: A Global Perspective. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2004. 3-42. Print.
  30. ^ Cornelius, p.11-12.
  31. ^ Cornelius, p.4.
  32. ^ a b Bloemraad, Irene. "Social Forces." Social Forces. Vol. 85. No. 2 (Dec. 2006): pp. 667-695. Print.
  33. ^ Duncan, Natasha T. and Waldorf, Brigitte S." Becoming a U.S. Citizen: The Role of Immigrant Enclaves" Cityscape. 11. No. 3 (2009): 5-28.
  34. ^ Sanders and Nee, pp. 746.
  35. ^ Sanders and Nee, pp. 745.
  36. ^ a b Lee, Jennifer. Civility in the City: Blacks, Jews, and Koreans in Urban America. Cambridge, Massachusetts, and London, England: Harvard University Press, 2002.
  37. ^ Caves, R. W. (2004). Encyclopedia of the City. Routledge. p. 241.
  38. ^ Vigdor, Jacob L. (2009). From immigrants to Americans : the rise and fall of fitting in. Lanham, Md.: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers. ISBN 978-1-4422-0138-5. OCLC 578648211.
  39. ^ Borjas, George J. Heaven's Door: Immigration Policy and the American Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999. p.8-11.
  40. ^ The Racial Structuring of the Housing Market and Segregation in Suburban Areas Linda Brewster Stearns, John R. Logan Social Forces, Vol. 65, No. 1 (Sep., 1986), pp. 28–42
  41. ^ Stephen R Holloway (1998) Exploring the Neighborhood Contingency of Race Discrimination in Mortgage Lending in Columbus, Ohio Annals of the Association of American Geographers 88 (2), 252–276.
  42. ^ See [1].
  43. ^ See [2].

ethnic, enclave, sociology, ethnic, enclave, geographic, area, with, high, ethnic, concentration, characteristic, cultural, identity, economic, activity, term, usually, used, refer, either, residential, area, workspace, with, high, concentration, ethnic, firms. In sociology an ethnic enclave is a geographic area with high ethnic concentration characteristic cultural identity and economic activity 2 The term is usually used to refer to either a residential area or a workspace with a high concentration of ethnic firms 3 Their success and growth depends on self sufficiency and is coupled with economic prosperity Ethnic enclavesBinondo Manila the world s oldest Chinatown 1 is an example of an ethnic enclave The theory of social capital and the formation of migrant networks creates the social foundation for ethnic enclaves Douglas Massey describes how migrant networks provide new immigrants with social capital that can be transferred to other tangible forms 4 As immigrants tend to cluster in close geographic spaces they develop migrant networks systems of interpersonal relations through which participants can exchange valuable resources and knowledge Immigrants can capitalize on social interactions by transforming information into tangible resources and thereby lower costs of migration Information exchanged may include knowledge of employment opportunities affordable housing government assistance programs and helpful NGOs 5 Thus by stimulating social connections ethnic enclaves generate a pool of intangible resources that help to promote the social and economic development of its members 5 By providing a space for individuals who share the same ethnic identity to create potentially beneficial relations ethnic enclaves assist members in achieving economic mobility Enclaves create an alternative labor market that is ethnic specific and does not demand social and cultural skills of the host country By eliminating language and cultural barriers enclave economies employ a greater proportion of co ethnics and speed the incorporation of new immigrants into a bustling economy By increasing employment opportunities and facilitating upward mobility studying ethnic enclaves helps to explain the success of some immigrant groups 3 Additionally while the ethnic enclave theory was developed to explain immigrant incorporation into the receiving society it has also been linked to migration processes at large as successful incorporation of immigrants has the potential to lower migration costs for future immigrants an example of chain migration Despite their immediate benefits the long term implications of participation in an ethnic enclave are a topic of debate Enclave economies have been linked to a glass ceiling limiting immigrant growth and upward mobility While participation in the enclave economy may assist in achieving upward mobility through increased availability of employment opportunities in the enclave labor market it may also impede acquisition of host country skills that benefit the immigrant over the long run 6 Such delays constrain immigrants to activity within the enclave and secludes them from the larger economy Opportunities available to mainstream society can thus be out of reach for immigrants who haven t learned about them Thus the accelerated path toward economic mobility that lures new immigrants into enclave economies may impede success Integration into an ethnic enclave may delay and even halt cultural assimilation preventing the immigrants from benefiting from mainstream institutions 7 Contents 1 History 2 Theories 2 1 Enclave economy hypothesis 2 2 Cumulative causation 3 Modes of incorporation 3 1 Social 3 1 1 Quality of kinship networks 3 1 2 Ethnic identity 3 1 3 Enclave networks 3 2 Economic 3 3 Political and civic involvement 4 Ethnic enclave debate 5 Ethnic enclaves in the United States 6 Historical ethnic enclaves 7 See also 8 ReferencesHistory Edit New York City is home to the largest overseas Chinese population of any city proper in the Western Hemisphere with over half a million Multiple large Chinatowns in Manhattan Brooklyn above and Queens are thriving as traditionally urban ethnic enclaves as large scale Chinese immigration continues into New York 8 9 10 11 with the largest metropolitan Chinese population outside Asia 12 Broad Avenue Koreatown in Palisades Park New Jersey United States 13 where Koreans comprise the majority 52 of the population 14 India Square in Jersey City New Jersey one of 24 Indian ethnic enclaves in the New York City Metropolitan Area Ethnic enclaves have been prominent urban features for centuries Examples include a new Armenian one near Beirut an old one in Bucharest 15 and an even older Armenian Quarter in Jerusalem 16 Urban quarters have often belonged mainly to residents having a particular sectarian or ethnic origin Historically the formation of ethnic enclaves has been the result of a variety of socioeconomic factors that draw immigrants to similar spaces in the receiving city state or country Cultural diversity brings together people who don t understand each other s language but a group can communicate more easily with neighbors in an enclave In some cases enclaves have been enforced by law as in a ghetto Roman colonies were established to control newly conquered provinces and grew to absorb the surrounding territory Some enclaves were established when a governing authority permitted a group to establish their own new town as in the English town of Gravesend Brooklyn in 1645 The lack of access to economic capital and of knowledge regarding residential neighborhoods can constrain newly arrived immigrants to regions of affordable housing Social dynamics such as prejudice and racism may concentrate co ethnics into regions displaying ethnic similarity Housing discrimination may also prevent ethnic minorities from settling into a particular residential area outside the enclave When discussing the ethnic enclave as defined by a spatial cluster of businesses success and growth can be largely predicted by three factors These factors include 1 the size and population of the enclave 2 the level of entrepreneurial skills of those in the enclave and 3 the availability of capital resources to the enclave Successful enclaves can reach a point where they become self sufficient or institutionally complete through the supply of new immigrants and demand of goods offered in the market They only reach this point after first supplying for the needs of co ethnics and then expanding to meet needs of those in the larger market of the host society 17 The term ethnic enclave arose in response to a publication by Alejandro Portes and Kenneth Wilson in 1980 18 Portes and Wilson identified a third labor market in which Cuban immigrants in Miami took part Instead of entering the secondary labor market of the host society Portes and Wilson discovered that new immigrants tended to become employed by co ethnics running immigrant owned firms The collection of small immigrant enterprises providing employment to new immigrants was defined as the enclave economy 19 Theories EditEnclave economy hypothesis Edit Observations of the Cuban ethnic enclave economy in Miami led Alejandro Portes and Kenneth Wilson to conclude that participation in an enclave economy provided immigrants with an alternative speedy option to achieve economic mobility in a host society The discourse pioneered by Portes and Wilson produced the construct for a body of literature that came to be known by the ethnic enclave hypothesis While never empirically defined the term ethnic enclave began to be widely used to represent two distinct definitions that of an enclave economy and that of a residential area of high co ethnic concentration 3 The most fundamental concept within the enclave hypothesis is that of social capital which lays the foundation for the establishment of migrant networks and the advantages associated with them 5 Cumulative causation Edit See also Chain migration With the rise in globalization and ease of international transportation patterns of immigration show the role of ethnic enclaves for contributing to increased migration over time New immigrants unintentionally lower costs for future immigration of co ethnics by pooling together resources for themselves Thus by achieving mobility in the receiving country themselves immigrants create a social structure that makes it easier for future immigrants to become upwardly mobile According to Douglas Massey Networks build into the migration process a self perpetuating momentum that leads to its growth over time in spite of fluctuating wage differentials recessions and increasingly restrictive immigration policies 4 Ethnic enclaves thus contribute to continued immigration by providing co ethnics with a space to make connections that ultimately lower migration costs and promote economic mobility Many worn path taken by former immigrants are made accessible to enclave members making immigration easier to future generations By generating further immigration migration leads to its own cumulative causation over time Modes of incorporation EditAn approach that analyzes ethnic enclaves and their members by their modes of incorporation is preferred to a neoclassical model which states that the economic success of immigrants depends on the education work experience and other elements of human capital that they possess 17 Sociologists have concluded that these factors do not suffice in explaining the integration and success of immigrants measured by occupational mobility and earnings Social Edit Upon arrival to a foreign country immigrants face challenges in assimilation and integration processes and thus experience different modes and levels of incorporation within the host society Many factors influence the level of ease or challenge experienced by immigrants as they make the transition and undergo physical social and psychological challenges The segmented assimilation model notes that there can exist a consciously pluralistic society in which a variety of subcultures and racial and ethnic identities coexist 20 21 One influential factor in an immigrant s journey is the presence of relatives or friends in the receiving country Friends and family making up a kinship network who are willing to help the newcomers can be classified as a type of capital commonly referred to as social capital Upon arrival many immigrants have limited or no access to human capital and thus rely heavily on any available source of social capital 17 The cost to immigration is large however this burden can be shared and thus eased through an immigrant s access to social capital in the receiving country Kinship networks in the receiving country can provide aid not only for the physical and economic needs of immigrants but also for their emotional and socio psychological needs 22 Quality of kinship networks Edit Access to social capital does not guarantee ease or success for the migrant Because social capital is rooted in relationships it easily lends itself to conflict and disagreement between parties 22 The level of economic stability on the side of the receiving party can dictate the level of aid they are willing or able to offer In addition the economic condition of the country and the availability of jobs open to the immigrants can largely affect the quality of the support network available to the migrant If the receiving country provides favorable conditions such as access to social programs the local economy and employment opportunities the network is likely to be of much higher quality Adversely kinship networks may break down if much stress is placed on the relationships involved due to economic hardships The duration and intensity of aid needed can dictate the quality of the kinship network available to the immigrant Immigrant ideas regarding level of support to be received are often high and left unmet if true economic conditions do not allow for favorable network conditions 22 Shared norms and relational ties can also lead to obligatory ties which some scholars such as Tsang and Inkpen argue restricts an individual s willingness to explore opportunities outside the network 23 Ethnic identity Edit Methods of assimilation and access to social capital vary between and even within ethnic groups A variety of factors can influence individuals ethnic identities including their social class background and the social networks available to them As theorized by sociologist Mary C Waters the involvement level of parents in ethnic organizations or activities heavily influences the development of their children s ethnic identities This is important to note as second generation immigrants must actively work to identify themselves with their ethnic group 20 Enclave networks Edit Enclave networks offer access to a unique type of social capital and act as large kinship networks Within enclave networks social capital commonly exists both as a private and public good 23 Though there is some debate in relation to the long term benefits offered by these networks the short term benefits are universally acknowledged The socio psychological challenges faced by the immigrant can be largely reduced through the individual s entrance into an ethnic enclave Ethnic enclaves can resemble the immigrant s place of origin through physical look layout and language employed both written and orally 17 In addition to increasing the cultural comfort of the migrant healthy ethnic enclaves offer solidarity and trust among members and informal training systems within the workplace The geographic proximity of the enclave network allows for easy flow of knowledge and varying types of assistance between firms as well Where there is an atmosphere of trust in ethnic enclaves this transfer of knowledge and sharing of social capital exists as an asset to the firms 23 Connections with members in an enclave may also afford the newcomer work opportunities Immigrants may also receive informal training regarding the customs and practices of the larger culture outside the enclave and help navigating challenges in many areas of everyday life 17 Social hostility may be a challenge faced by immigrants in their host society therefore to avoid this factor ethnic enclaves provide a haven where economic success may still be achieved 7 Economic Edit Ethnic enclave economies are predicated upon aspects of economic sociology and the sociology of immigration Ethnic Enclaves generate a pool of social capital through which members can access resources that lower the costs of migration Enclave membership provides economic assistance such as job opportunities and small businesses loans Small ethnic firms within the enclave provide new immigrants with immediate access to economic opportunities by subverting the secondary sector of the economy and creating numerous low wage jobs that are easily accessed by members 17 24 The ethno centric nature of businesses and firms provides easy integration into enclave economies Goods and services tend to be offered in the ethnic group s language while social and cultural norms specific to the host country are not required of employees in the enclave economy Thus the ethno specific nature of enclave economies makes them attractive to new immigrants who are otherwise unable integrate into the mainstream economy Ethnic enclave economies also provide a method for immigrants who enter at lower wage jobs to rise to the status community entrepreneurs own firms within the community While benefiting from the higher wages that owning a business provides them these established immigrants continue the cycle of providing attractive albeit lower income labor to newcomers within the framework of the ethnic enclave 25 The ethnic enclave economy allows for a measure of independence for immigrants by creating a path for them to own businesses 26 Ethnic enclave economies also have the effect of raising the hourly wages of workers within the enclave 27 An individual s entrance into the enclave economy is dependent upon the conditions of incorporation they experience Unfavorable modes of incorporation into the host society provide incentives for immigrants to enter the informal economy Discrimination hostility and a lack of resources may encourage immigrants to enter into informal employment 17 Ethnic enclaves are rich in informal activities as the entrepreneurial services making the core of the enclave s founding were historically informal ventures Informality proves favorable for many immigrant entrepreneurs by bypass regulatory expenses Additionally the scope of employment for immigrants is greatly widened by the availability of informal jobs in the enclave economic sector The informality of the enclave economy simultaneously induces risk and fraud Informal activities are constantly under risk of detection by the formal sector which has a negative effect on job security Furthermore due to the absence of legal framework immigrant laborers often remain silent about various forms of exploitation The most common form of labor exploitation in immigrant economies is unpaid labor Undocumented immigrants are especially afraid to report violations of labor laws and exploitation 28 Political and civic involvement Edit Government policy toward immigrants is the first mode of reception to the receiving country 3 Governments generally enforce measures to reduce the amount of unwanted immigrants which may potentially pose a burden on the receiving society and economy 29 The granting of different statuses and visas i e refugee temporary visas for students and workers to immigrant groups affects the type of reception immigrants will receive Aside from immigration control policies some governments also impose measures to accelerate social and political incorporation of new immigrants and to stimulate economic mobility Wayne Cornelius studies two central theses regarding institutional response to increased movement of people across transnational borders The first of these is the gap hypothesis which describes the dissonance between official immigration policies and real policy outcomes Policy gaps are the result of unintended consequences and inadequate enforcement by the receiving society Many reasons can explain unintended consequences of immigration policy Governments with undefined or ambiguous stances toward immigration may propagate unintended consequences and the reliance on flawed policies can further reduce the efficacy of institutional measures Furthermore political incoherency policy poses a greater challenge for the incorporation and enforcement of effective measures A negative public opinion toward immigrants is a good measure of significant policy gaps in the receiving government however special interest groups may also constrain political responses to immigration This is especially true in liberal democracies where lobbying by powerful employer groups religious groups ethnic and immigrant advocacy groups and even labor unions leads governments to adopt more expansionary immigration policies even when the economy goes bad and general public opinion turns hostile to immigrants 30 Furthermore governments and special groups in the immigrant sending country may align themselves with pro immigration lobbyists in the receiving country Thus the policymaking process is complicated by involvement of multiple factions The second thesis studied by Wayne Cornelius is the convergence hypothesis which describes the growing similarity of political responses to immigration among immigrant receiving countries These similarities fall into 1 the policies that their governments have adopted to control immigration 2 policies designed to integrate immigrants into host societies by providing them with social services as well as political economic and social rights and 3 attitudes toward immigrants and immigration policy preferences among general publics 31 Ethnic groups receive various levels of reception by the host society for various reasons In general European immigrants tend to encounter little resistance by host countries while tenets of racism are evinced by widespread resistance to immigrants of color 17 Political incorporation into the host country is coupled with adoption of citizenship of the host country By studying the diverging trajectories of immigrant citizenship in Canada and the U S Irene Bloemraad explains that current models of citizenship acquisition fail to recognize the social nature of political incorporation Bloemraad describes political incorporation as a social process of mobilization by friends family community organizations and local leaders that is embedded in an institutional context shaped by government policies of diversity and newcomer settlement 32 This alternative model emphasizes the role of migrant networks in critically shaping how immigrants consider citizenship Bloemraad shows that friends family co ethnic organizations and local community affect political incorporation by providing a structured mobilization framework This social structure is most essential for immigrants who face language barriers and may lack familiarity with host institutions The extent to which migrant networks promote citizenship depends on the efficacy of government policies on immigrant integration Governments adopting policies that facilitate the emergence integration and growth of ethnic economies are presumed to gain support by co ethnics Thus the movement toward political incorporation and citizenship is nested in a larger institutional structure involving economic and social integration policy as these relate to immigrants 32 Ethnic enclaves have the ability to simultaneously assist in political and civic incorporation of immigrants By providing a space that facilitates upward mobility and economic integration into the receiving society enclaves and their members fundamentally influence the perceptions of receiving institutions by co ethnics Finally enclaves may gauge community interest in naturalization and direct immigrants through the process to gaining citizenshipEthnic enclave debate EditThe discourse surrounding ethnic enclaves has prompted debate among scholars in two related areas of thought Both areas discuss the role ethnic enclaves play by either offering aid or hindering the economic and social well being of the enclave s members One area of thought discusses the role of enclaves in assimilative patterns and upward mobility while the second area of thought argues the economic ramifications associated with membership within ethnic enclaves The immediate economic and social advantages associated with membership in an ethnic enclave are undisputed by scholars however the long term consequences remain an area of uncertainty The role these networks play remains uncertain due to the fact that ethnic enclaves allow immigrants to function successfully within the host society without a significant amount of adjustment either culturally or linguistically As such they can either help or hinder naturalization within the host country The relatively low levels of skill required allow immigrants to achieve financial stability which can in turn encourage eventual naturalization and assimilation Adversely this same factor can afford enclave members the opportunity to remain considerably segregated and secluded from the host society As such members may circumvent the need to acquire skills necessary for life in the larger host society such as knowledge of cultural norms and language 33 The debate regarding the economic viability of ethnic enclaves revolves around the enclave economy hypothesis The hypothesis as written by Wilson and Portes formulates the idea that i mmigrant workers are not restricted to the secondary labor market They instead argue that those inserted into an immigrant enclave can be empirically distinguished from workers in both the primary and secondary labor markets Enclave workers will share with those in the primary sector a significant economic return past human capital investments something those who enter the secondary labor market are not able to enjoy 7 34 Thus they assert the enclave economy is not a mobility trap as some would term it but an alternate mode of incorporation In their argument formulated to disprove the enclave economy hypothesis Sanders and Nee state the need for a distinction between immigrant bosses and immigrant workers as the economic benefits differ along this distinction 35 They also call for the investigation of economic opportunities available to those in the enclave believing them to be lesser in quality and supply Sanders and Nee also assert the idea that segregation and forced entrance of immigrant workers into low paying jobs is actually aggravated by the existence of ethnic enclaves Due to these objections they call for the revision of Portes and Wilson s hypothesis to include an acknowledgement and outline of the entrepreneur worker economic benefit distinction In reaction to Sanders and Nee Portes and Jensen make the clarification that those in ethnic enclaves need not be wealthier than those who left the enclave for the hypothesis to be supported They instead assert that this will usually not be the case as the constant entrance of new immigrants into the enclave will actually be somewhat burdensome on the economy a factor which does not actually represent disadvantage when compared with the other advantages provided 3 Additionally Portes and Jensen outline three different conditions to be fulfilled in order to disprove their hypothesis The first of these conditions requires the demonstration that ethnic entrepreneurship is a mobility trap leading to lower earnings than the immigrant s worth in human capital The second condition requires data proving the work within the enclave to be exploitative and the third condition requires data showing employment within the enclave leads to a dead end and offers no chance of upward mobility 3 They acknowledge that the fulfillment of these three requirements is difficult as there is little data available to accurately test them Jennifer Lee adds to the discussion noting the particular niches and types of business immigrant groups enter She notes that it is most common for immigrants to participate in long hours of physically demanding work in the retail industry The retail market is a viable option due to the relatively low startup costs and knowledge of the host country s language required Different niches have different levels of communication for example the retail and self service niche fruit and vegetable markets take out restaurants typically require the lowest level of customer interaction and communication Lee notes the embeddedness of ethnic enclaves and brings the thought that such practices are good for those within the enclave but harmful to certain groups outside them 36 She also notes the adverse effects patterns of ethnic embeddedness can have on surrounding ethnic groups by noting the difficulty other groups face in joining the network She argues that this type of retail niche domination can have positive consequences for co ethnics as Portes and Wilson believe however can also have negative effects on surrounding ethnic groups who face exclusion due solely to their ethnic dissimilarity from the network 36 Ethnic enclaves in the United States EditMain article Immigration to the United States Immigration to the United States has occurred in waves that demonstrate the predominance of certain sets of ethnic minorities As immigrants tended to cluster in certain cities and states separate waves were responsible for the establishment of ethnic enclaves in separate physical spaces The best known ethnic enclaves in American cities began to appear with the arrival of large numbers of Irish immigrants during the first third of the nineteenth century and continued forming throughout that century and the twentieth as successive waves of immigrants arrived in the United States 37 In the early 20th century immigrants chose to live in enclave neighborhoods because of language barriers and cost of living benefits Sociologists Robert Park and Edward Burgess integrated a model that studied these patterns in the 1920s This model showcased how immigrants who arrived in the U S in the early 20th century were drawn to urban enclave neighborhoods as they opened up opportunities for social networking and employment 38 In 1998 nearly three quarters of all immigrants in the United States lived in California New York Texas Florida New Jersey or Illinois 39 Housing discrimination remains a factor in the persistence of racial enclaves in American cities 40 41 However more recent patterns of migration such as chain migration challenge traditional methods of enclaves establishment Historical ethnic enclaves EditEthnic enclaves have become commonplace in modern times with the increase in the geographic mobility of humankind However they have also arisen in historical times for various reasons The village of Schandorf now in Austria was for centuries a Croatian ethnic enclave surrounded by areas of Austrian and Hungarian ethnicity The enclave originated around 1543 when the Hungarian magnate Batthyany sought to repopulate lands that had been emptied by devastating Turkish attacks he invited Croatian settlers 42 The town of Alghero in Sardinia still marginally preserves a Catalan ethnic enclave this dates from a military conquest of the town by Catalans in the 14th century 43 Ethnic enclaves also arose when a people remained in its original territory but came to be surrounded by a far more numerous majority as in the case of Vepsians and Russians Many of New York s neighborhoods were once Italian neighborhoods to the point of New York in the nineteenth and twentieth century once having an Italian population larger than that of Rome the Italian capital at the time citation needed Wikimedia Commons has media related to Ethnic enclaves See also EditList of ethnic enclaves in North American cities List of ethnic enclaves in Philippine cities Ethnoburb Ghetto Language islandReferences Edit Prime Sarmiento May 21 2018 Exploring world s oldest Chinatown China Daily Retrieved October 12 2022 Abrahamson Mark Urban Enclaves Identity and Place in America Review by David M Hummon Contemporary Sociology American Sociological Association Vol 25 No 6 Nov 1996 pp 781 782 a b c d e f Portes Alejandro and Leif Jensen Disproving the Enclave Hypothesis Reply American Sociological Review Vol 57 no 3 1992 418 420 a b Massey Douglas S 1990 The Social and Economic Origins of Immigration The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 510 1 60 72 https doi org 10 1177 0002716290510001005 pp 60 a b c Massey Douglas S Why Does Immigration Occur A Theoretical Synthesis The Handbook of International Migration The American Experience Charles Hirschman Philip Kasinitz and Josh DeWind editors New York Russell Sage Foundation 1999 Edin Per Anders Peter Fredriksson and Olof Aslund ETHNIC ENCLAVES AND THE ECONOMIC SUCCESS OF IMMIGRANTS EVIDENCE FROM A NATURAL EXPERIMENT The Quarterly Journal of Economics no 1 2003 329 357 a b c Sanders Jimy M and Nee Victor Limits of Ethnic Solidarity in the Enclave Economy American Sociological Review 52 no 6 1987 745 773 Yearbook of Immigration Statistics 2012 Supplemental Table 2 U S Department of Homeland Security Retrieved 2014 04 05 Yearbook of Immigration Statistics 2011 Supplemental Table 2 U S Department of Homeland Security Retrieved 2014 04 05 Yearbook of Immigration Statistics 2010 Supplemental Table 2 U S Department of Homeland Security Retrieved 2014 04 05 John Marzulli May 9 2011 Malaysian man smuggled illegal Chinese immigrants into Brooklyn using Queen Mary 2 authorities New York c Copyright 2012 NY Daily News com Retrieved 2014 04 05 Chinese New Year 2012 in Flushing QueensBuzz com January 25 2012 Retrieved 2014 04 05 Asian Americans Contemporary Trends and Issues Second Edition Edited by Pyong Gap Min Pine Forge Press An Imprint of Sage Publications Inc 2006 ISBN 9781412905565 Retrieved 2012 11 15 Karen Sudol Dave Sheingold October 12 2011 Korean language ballots coming to Bergen County North Jersey Media Group Retrieved 2012 11 15 Bucharest Armenian Neighbourhood Interesting Times Bureau 2016 09 18 Retrieved 2019 11 03 Deyirmenjian Sevan 6 May 2013 Քանի մը դրուագ Երուսաղէմէն Սուրբ Յակոբի հովանիին ներքոյ Jamanak in Armenian Istanbul Archived from the original on 28 March 2016 պաշտօնապէս իսկ կոչուելով Հայոց թաղ անունով a href Template Cite news html title Template Cite news cite news a CS1 maint bot original URL status unknown link Երուսաղէմահայը The Jerusalemite armenische kirche ch in Armenian Zurich Diocese of the Armenian Apostolic Church in the German Switzerland Archived from the original on 25 March 2016 Retrieved 11 November 2015 Իսկ հայոց թաղի բնակիչները a b c d e f g h Portes Alejandro 1995 Chapter 1 Economic Sociology and the Sociology of Immigration A conceptual Overview In Portes Alejandro ed The Economic Sociology of Immigration Russel Sage Foundation pp 1 41 Waldinger Roger The Ethnic Enclave Debate Revisited International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 17 no 3 1993 428 436 Portes Alejandro and Kenneth Wilson Immigrant Enclaves An Analysis of the Labor Market Experiences of Cubans in Miami American Journal of Sociology 86 no 2 1980 295 319 a b Waters Mary C Ethnic and Racial Identities of Second Generation Black Immigrants in New York City International Migration Review 28 no 4 1994 795 820 Waters p 799 a b c Menjivar Cecilia Immigrant Kinship Networks and the Impact of the Receiving Context Salvadorans in San Francisco in the Early 1990s Social Problems 44 no 1 1997 104 123 a b c Inkpen C Andrew and Tsang W K Eric Social Capital Networks and Knowledge Transfer The Academy of Management Review Vol 30 No 1 1992 146 165 Light Ivan Sabagh Georges Bozorgmehr Mehdi Der Martirosian Claudia 1994 Beyond the Ethnic Enclave Economy Social Problems 41 1 65 80 doi 10 2307 3096842 ISSN 0037 7791 JSTOR 3096842 Light Ivan Sabagh Georges Bozorgmehr Mehdi Der Martirosian Claudia 1994 Beyond the Ethnic Enclave Economy Social Problems 41 1 65 80 doi 10 2307 3096842 ISSN 0037 7791 JSTOR 3096842 Sanders Jimy M Nee Victor 1996 Immigrant Self Employment The Family as Social Capital and the Value of Human Capital American Sociological Review 61 2 231 249 doi 10 2307 2096333 ISSN 0003 1224 JSTOR 2096333 Damm Anna Piil 2009 Ethnic Enclaves and Immigrant Labor Market Outcomes Quasi Experimental Evidence Journal of Labor Economics 27 2 281 314 doi 10 1086 599336 ISSN 0734 306X JSTOR 10 1086 599336 S2CID 17521852 Hondagneu Sotelo Pierrette Blowups and Other Unhappy Endings in Global Woman Nannies Maids and Sex Workers in the New Economy by Barbara Enrehnreich and Arlie Hochschild New York Henry Holt and Company 2002 Cornelius Wayne A Controlling Immigration A Global Perspective Stanford Stanford University Press 2004 3 42 Print Cornelius p 11 12 Cornelius p 4 a b Bloemraad Irene Social Forces Social Forces Vol 85 No 2 Dec 2006 pp 667 695 Print Duncan Natasha T and Waldorf Brigitte S Becoming a U S Citizen The Role of Immigrant Enclaves Cityscape 11 No 3 2009 5 28 Sanders and Nee pp 746 Sanders and Nee pp 745 a b Lee Jennifer Civility in the City Blacks Jews and Koreans in Urban America Cambridge Massachusetts and London England Harvard University Press 2002 Caves R W 2004 Encyclopedia of the City Routledge p 241 Vigdor Jacob L 2009 From immigrants to Americans the rise and fall of fitting in Lanham Md Rowman amp Littlefield Publishers ISBN 978 1 4422 0138 5 OCLC 578648211 Borjas George J Heaven s Door Immigration Policy and the American Economy Princeton Princeton University Press 1999 p 8 11 The Racial Structuring of the Housing Market and Segregation in Suburban Areas Linda Brewster Stearns John R Logan Social Forces Vol 65 No 1 Sep 1986 pp 28 42 Stephen R Holloway 1998 Exploring the Neighborhood Contingency of Race Discrimination in Mortgage Lending in Columbus Ohio Annals of the Association of American Geographers 88 2 252 276 See 1 See 2 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Ethnic enclave amp oldid 1156807360, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.