fbpx
Wikipedia

Economics of English towns and trade in the Middle Ages

The economics of English towns and trade in the Middle Ages is the economic history of English towns and trade from the Norman invasion in 1066, to the death of Henry VII in 1509. Although England's economy was fundamentally agricultural throughout the period, even before the invasion the market economy was important to producers. Norman institutions, including serfdom, were superimposed on a mature network of well-established towns involved in international trade. Over the next five centuries the English economy would at first grow and then suffer an acute crisis, resulting in significant political and economic change. Despite economic dislocation in urban areas, including shifts in the holders of wealth and the location of these economies, the economic output of towns developed and intensified over the period. By the end of the period, England would have a weak early modern government overseeing an economy involving a thriving community of indigenous English merchants and corporations.

Invasion and the early Norman period (1066–1100) edit

William the Conqueror invaded England in 1066, defeating the Anglo-Saxon King Harold Godwinson at the Battle of Hastings and placing the country under Norman rule. This campaign was followed by fierce military operations known as the Harrying of the North between 1069–1070, extending Norman authority across the north of England. William's system of government was broadly feudal in that the right to possess land was linked to service to the king, but in many other ways the invasion did little to alter the nature of the English economy.[1] Most of the damage done in the invasion was in the north and the west of England, some of it still recorded as "wasteland" in 1086.[2] Many of the key features of the English trading and financial system remained in place in the decades immediately after the conquest.[2]

Trade, manufacturing and the towns edit

 
A page of the Domesday Book, capturing the economic condition of England in 1086.

Although primarily rural, England had a number of old, economically important towns in 1066.[3] A large amount of trade came through the Eastern towns, including London, York, Winchester, Lincoln, Norwich, Ipswich and Thetford.[3] Much of this trade was with France, the Low Countries and Germany, but the North-East of England traded with partners as far away as Sweden.[4] Cloth was already being imported to England before the invasion through the mercery trade.[5]

Some towns, such as York, suffered from Norman sacking during William's northern campaigns.[6] Other towns saw the widespread demolition of houses to make room for new motte and bailey fortifications, as was the case in Lincoln.[6] The Norman invasion also brought significant economic changes with the arrival of the first Jews to English cities.[7] William I brought over wealthy Jews from the Rouen community in Normandy to settle in London, apparently to carry out financial services for the crown.[8] In the years immediately after the invasion, a lot of wealth was drawn out of England in various ways by the Norman rulers and reinvested in Normandy, making William immensely wealthy as an individual ruler.[9]

The minting of coins was decentralised in the Saxon period; every borough was mandated to have a mint and therefore a centre for trading in bullion.[10] Nonetheless, there was strict royal control over these moneyers and coin dies could only be made in London.[10] William retained this arrangement and also maintained a high coin standard, which led to the use of the term sterling for Norman silver coins.[10]

Governance and taxation edit

William I inherited the Anglo-Saxon system in which the king drew his revenues from a mixture of customs; profits from re-minting coinage; fines; profits from his own demesne lands, and the system of English land-based taxation called the geld.[11] William reaffirmed this system, enforcing collection of the geld through his new system of sheriffs and increasing the taxes on trade.[12] William was also famous for commissioning the Domesday Book in 1086, a vast document which attempted to record the economic condition of his new kingdom.

Mid-medieval growth (1100–1290) edit

The 12th and 13th centuries were a period of huge economic growth in England. The population of England rose from around one and a half million in 1086 to around four or five million in 1300, stimulating increased agricultural outputs and the export of raw materials to Europe.[13] In contrast to the previous two centuries, England was relatively secure from invasion. Except for the years of the Anarchy, most military conflicts either had only localised economic impact or proved only temporarily disruptive. English economic thinking remained conservative, seeing the economy as consisting of three groups: the ordines, those who fought, or the nobility; laboratores, those who worked, in particular the peasantry; and oratores, those who prayed, or the clerics.[14] Trade and merchants played little part in this model and were frequently vilified at the start of the period, although increasingly tolerated towards the end of the 13th century.[15]

Trade, manufacturing and the towns edit

Growth of English towns edit

 
The medieval plan for Liverpool, a new English town founded by order of King John in 1207.

After the end of the Anarchy, the number of small towns in England began to increase sharply.[16] By 1297 a hundred and twenty new towns had established and in 1350, by when the expansion had effectively ceased, there were around 500 towns in England.[17] Many of these new towns were centrally plannedRichard I created Portsmouth, John founded Liverpool, with Harwich, Stony Stratford, Dunstable, Royston, Baldock, Wokingham, Maidenhead and Reigate following under successive monarchs.[18] The new towns were usually located with access to trade routes, rather than defence, in mind.[19] The streets were laid out to make access to the town's market convenient.[19] A growing percentage of England's population lived in urban areas; estimates suggest that this rose from around 5.5% in 1086 to up to 10% in 1377.[20]

London held a special status within the English economy. The nobility purchased and consumed many luxury goods and services in the capital, and as early as the 1170s the London markets were providing exotic products such as spices, incense, palm oil, gems, silks, furs and foreign weapons.[21] London was also an important hub for industrial activity; it had many blacksmiths making a wide range of goods, including decorative ironwork and early clocks.[22] Pewter-working, using English tin and lead, was also widespread in London during the period.[23] The provincial towns also had a substantial number of trades by the end of the 13th century—a large town like Coventry, for example, contained over three hundred different specialist occupations, and a smaller town such as Durham could support some sixty different professions.[24] The increasing wealth of the nobility and the church was reflected in the widespread building of cathedrals and other prestigious buildings in the larger towns, in turn making use of lead from English mines for roofing.[25]

Land transport remained much more expensive than river or sea transport during the period.[26] Many towns in this period, including York, Exeter and Lincoln, were linked to the oceans by navigable rivers and could act as seaports, with Bristol's port coming to dominate the lucrative trade in wine with Gascony by the 13th century, but shipbuilding generally remained on a modest scale and economically unimportant to England at this time.[27] Transport remained very costly in comparison to the overall price of products.[28] By the 13th century, groups of common carriers ran carting businesses, with carting brokers existing in London to link traders and carters.[29] These used the four major land routes crossing England: Ermine Street, the Fosse Way, Icknield Street and Watling Street.[29] A large number of bridges were built during the 12th century to improve the trade network.[30]

In the 13th century, England was still primarily supplying raw materials for export to Europe, rather than finished or processed goods.[31] There were some exceptions, such as very high quality cloths from Stamford and Lincoln, including the famous "Lincoln Scarlet" dyed cloth.[31] Despite royal efforts to encourage it, barely any English cloth was being exported by 1347.[32]

Expansion of the money supply edit

 
An Edward I silver penny from Lincoln; Edward increased the controls on the minting of coins begun under Henry II, creating the Master of the Mint.

There was a gradual reduction in the number of locations allowed to mint coins in England; under Henry II, only 30 boroughs were still able to use their own moneyers and the tightening of controls continued throughout the 13th century.[33] By the reign of Edward I there were only nine mints outside London and the king created a new official called the Master of the Mint to oversee these and the thirty furnaces operating in London to meet the supply for new coins.[34] The amount of money in circulation hugely increased in this period; before the Norman invasion there had been around £50,000 in circulation as coin, but by 1311 this had risen to more than £1m.[35] The physical implication of this growth was that coins had to be manufactured in large numbers, being moved in barrels and sacks to be stored in local treasuries for royal use as the king travelled.[36] During the 13th Century, nominal wages fluctuated, but the overall trend was flat. As a result of the increase in money supply, prices in general increased significantly over the course of the century. As a result of the price inflation, real wages—one of the stickiest of prices—declined steadily.

Rise of the guilds edit

The first English guilds emerged during the early 12th century.[37] These guilds were fraternities of craftsmen that set out to manage their local affairs including "prices, workmanship, the welfare of its workers and the suppression of interlopers and sharp practices".[38] Amongst these early guilds were the "guilds merchants", who ran the local markets in towns and represented the merchant community in discussions with the crown.[37] Other early guilds included the "craft guilds", representing specific trades. By 1130 there were major weavers' guilds in six English towns, as well as a fullers guild in Winchester.[39] Over the coming decades more guilds were created, often becoming increasingly involved in both local and national politics, although the guilds merchants were largely replaced by official groups established by new royal charters.[40]

The craft guilds required relatively stable markets and a relative equality of income and opportunity amongst their members to function effectively.[41] By the 14th century these conditions were increasingly uncommon.[41] The first strains were seen in London, where the old guild system began to collapse – more trade was being conducted at a national level, making it hard for craftsmen to both manufacture goods and trade in them, and there were growing disparities in incomes between the richer and poor craftsmen.[41] As a result, under Edward III many guilds became companies or livery companies, chartered companies focusing on trade and finance (the management of large amounts of money), leaving the guild structures to represent the interests of the smaller, poorer manufacturers.[42]

Merchants and the development of the charter fairs edit

 
The market place at Bridgnorth, one of many medieval English towns to be granted the right to hold fairs, in this case annually on the feast of the Translation of St. Leonard.

The period also saw the development of charter fairs in England, which reached their heyday in the 13th century.[43] From the 12th century onwards, many English towns acquired a charter from the Crown allowing them to hold an annual fair, usually serving a regional or local customer base and lasting for two or three days.[44] The practice increased in the next century and over 2,200 charters were issued to markets and fairs by English kings between 1200 and 1270.[44] Fairs grew in popularity as the international wool trade increased: the fairs allowed English wool producers and ports on the east coast to engage with visiting foreign merchants, circumnavigating those English merchants in London keen to make a profit as middlemen.[45] At the same time, wealthy magnate consumers in England began to use the new fairs as a way to buy goods like spices, wax, preserved fish and foreign cloth in bulk from the international merchants at the fairs, again bypassing the usual London merchants.[46]

Some fairs grew into major international events, falling into a set sequence during the economic year, with the Stamford fair in Lent, St Ives' in Easter, Boston's in July, Winchester's in September and Northampton's in November, with the many smaller fairs falling in-between.[47] Although not as large as the famous Champagne fairs in France, these English "great fairs" were still huge events; St Ives' Great Fair, for example, drew merchants from Flanders, Brabant, Norway, Germany and France for a four-week event each year, turning the normally small town into "a major commercial emporium".[45]

The structure of the fairs reflected the importance of foreign merchants in the English economy and by 1273 only one third of the English wool trade was actually controlled by English merchants.[48] Between 1280–1320 the trade was primarily dominated by Italian merchants, but by the early 14th century German merchants had begun to present serious competition to the Italians.[48] The Germans formed a self-governing alliance of merchants in London called the "Hanse of the Steelyard"—the eventual Hanseatic League—and their role was confirmed under the Great Charter of 1303, which exempted them from paying the customary tolls for foreign merchants.[49][nb 1] One response to this was the creation of the Company of the Staple, a group of merchants established in English-held Calais in 1314 with royal approval, who were granted a monopoly on wool sales to Europe.[50]

Jewish contribution to the English economy edit

 
Clifford's Tower in the city of York, a major hub for Jewish economic activity and the site of an early Jewish pogrom in 1190.

The Jewish community in England continued to provide essential money lending and banking services that were otherwise banned by the usury laws, and grew in the 12th century by Jewish immigrants fleeing the fighting around Rouen.[51] The Jewish community spread beyond London to eleven major English cities, primarily the major trading hubs in the east of England with functioning mints, all with suitable castles for protection of the often persecuted Jewish minority.[52] By the time of the Anarchy and the reign of Stephen, the communities were flourishing and providing financial loans to the king.[53]

Under Henry II, the Jewish financial community continued to grow richer still.[54] All major towns had Jewish centres and even smaller towns, such as Windsor, saw visits travelling Jewish merchants.[55] Henry II used the Jewish community as "instruments for the collection of money for the Crown", and placed them under royal protection.[56] The Jewish community at York lent extensively to fund the Cistercian order's acquisition of land and prospered considerably.[57] Some Jewish merchants grew extremely wealthy, Aaron of Lincoln so much that upon his death a special royal department had to be established to unpick his financial holdings and affairs.[58]

By the end of Henry's reign the king ceased to borrow from the Jewish community and instead turned to an aggressive campaign of tallage taxation and fines.[59] Financial and anti-Semite violence grew under Richard I. After the massacre of the York community in which numerous financial records were destroyed, seven towns were nominated to separately store Jewish bonds and money records and this arrangement ultimately evolved into the Exchequer of the Jews.[60] After an initially peaceful start to John's reign, the king again began to extort money from the Jewish community, imprisoning the wealthier members, including Isaac of Norwich, until a huge, new taillage was paid.[61] During the Baron's War of 1215–1217, the Jews were subjected to fresh anti-Semitic attacks.[58] Henry III restored some order and Jewish money-lending became sufficiently successful again to allow fresh taxation.[62] The Jewish community became poorer towards the end of the century and was finally expelled from England in 1290 by Edward I, being largely replaced by foreign merchants.[54]

Governance and taxation edit

 
A medieval carving from Rievaulx Abbey showing of one of the many new windmills established during the 13th century.

During the 12th century the Norman kings attempted to formalise the feudal governance system initially created after the invasion. After the invasion the king had enjoyed combination of income from his own demesne lands, the Anglo-Saxon geld tax and fines. Successive kings found that they needed additional revenues, especially in order to pay for mercenary forces.[63] One way of doing this was to exploit the feudal system, and kings adopted the French feudal aid model, a levy of money imposed on feudal subordinates when necessary; another method was to exploit the scutage system, in which feudal military service could be transmuted to a cash payment to the king.[63] Taxation was also an option, although the old geld tax was increasingly ineffective due to an increasing number of exemptions. Instead a succession of kings created alternative land taxes, such as the tallage and carucage taxes. These were increasingly unpopular and, along with the feudal charges, were condemned and constrained in the Magna Carta of 1215. As part of the formalisation of the royal finances, Henry I created the Chancellor of the Exchequer, a post which would lead to the maintenance of the Pipe rolls, a set of royal financial records of lasting significance to historians in tracking both royal finances and medieval prices.[64]

Royal revenue streams still proved insufficient and from the middle of the 13th century there was a shift away from the earlier land based tax system towards one based on a mixture of indirect and direct taxation.[65] At the same time Henry III of England had introduced the practice of consulting with leading nobles on tax issues, leading to the system of the English parliament agreeing on new taxes when required. In 1275, the "Great and Ancient Custom" began to tax woollen products and hides, with the Great Charter of 1303 imposing additional levies on foreign merchants in England, with the poundage tax introduced in 1347.[65] In 1340, the discredited tallage tax system was finally abolished by Edward III.[66]

In the English towns the burgage tenure for urban properties was established early on in the medieval period, being based primarily on tenants paying cash rents rather than providing labour services.[67] Further development of a set of taxes that could be raised by the towns, including murage for walls, pavage for streets or pontage, a temporary tax for the repair of bridges.[68] Combined with the lex mercatoria, which was a set of codes and customary practices governing trading, provided a reasonable basis for the economic governance of the towns.[69]

The 12th century also saw a concerted attempt to curtail the remaining rights of unfree peasant workers and to set out their labour rents more explicitly in the form of the English Common Law.[70] This process resulted in the Magna Carta explicitly authorising feudal landowners to settle law cases concerning feudal labour and fines through their own manorial courts rather than through the royal courts.[71]

Mid-medieval economic crisis: the Great Famine and the Black Death (1290–1350) edit

 
The Black Death reached England in 1348 from Europe.

Great Famine edit

The Great Famine of 1315 began a number of acute crises in the English agrarian economy. The famine centred on a sequence of harvest failures in 1315, 1316 and 1321, combined with an outbreak of the murrain sickness amongst sheep and oxen between 1319–1321 and the fatal ergotism fungi amongst the remaining stocks of wheat.[72] In the ensuing famine, many people died and the peasantry were said to have been forced to eat horses, dogs and cats as well to have conducted cannibalism against children, although these last reports are usually considered to be exaggerations.[73] Poaching and encroachment on the royal forests surged, sometimes on a mass scale.[74] Sheep and cattle numbers fell by up to a half, significantly reducing the availability of wool and meat, and food prices almost doubled, with grain prices particularly inflated.[75] Food prices remained at similar levels for the next decade.[75] Salt prices also increased sharply due to the wet weather.[76]

Various factors exacerbated the crisis. Economic growth had already begun to slow significantly in the years prior to the crisis and the English rural population was increasingly under economic stress, with around half the peasantry estimated to possess insufficient land to provide them with a secure livelihood.[77] Where additional land was being brought into cultivation, or existing land cultivated more intensively, the soil may have become exhausted and useless.[78] Bad weather also played an important part in the disaster; 1315-6 and 1318 saw torrential rains and an incredibly cold winter, which in combination badly impacted on harvests and stored supplies.[79] The rains of these years was followed by drought in the 1320s and another fierce winter in 1321, complicating recovery.[80] Disease, independent of the famine, was also high during the period, striking at the wealthier as well as the poorer classes. The commencement of war with France in 1337 only added to the economic difficulties.[81] The Great Famine firmly reversed the population growth of the 12th and 13th centuries and left a domestic economy that was "profoundly shaken, but not destroyed".[82]

Black Death edit

The Black Death epidemic first arrived in England in 1348, re-occurring in waves during 1360–1362, 1368–1369, 1375 and more sporadically thereafter.[83] The most immediate economic impact of this disaster was the widespread loss of life, between around 27% mortality amongst the upper classes, to 40–70% amongst the peasantry.[84][nb 2] Despite the very high loss of life, few settlements were abandoned during the epidemic itself, but many were badly affected or nearly eliminated altogether.[85] The medieval authorities did their best to respond in an organised fashion, but the economic disruption was immense.[86] Building work ceased and many mining operations paused.[87] In the short term, efforts were taken by the authorities to control wages and enforce pre-epidemic working conditions.[88] Coming on top of the previous years of famine, however, the longer term economic implications were profound.[88] In contrast to the previous centuries of rapid growth, the English population would not begin to recover for over a century, despite the many positive reasons for a resurgence.[89] The crisis would dramatically affect English agriculture, wages and prices for the remainder of the medieval period.[90]

Late medieval economic recovery (1350–1509) edit

The events of the crisis between 1290 and 1348 and the subsequent epidemics produced many challenges for the English economy. In the decades after the disaster, the economic and social issues arising from the Black Death combined with the costs of the Hundred Years War to produce the Peasants Revolt of 1381.[91] Although the revolt was suppressed, it undermined many of the vestiges of the feudal economic order and the countryside became dominated by estates organised as farms, frequently owned or rented by the new economic class of the gentry. The English agricultural economy remained depressed throughout the 15th century, with growth coming from the greatly increased English cloth trade and manufacturing.[92] The economic consequences of this varied considerably from region to region, but generally London, the South and the West prospered at the expense of the Eastern and the older cities.[93] The role of merchants and of trade became increasingly seen as important to the country and usury became increasingly accepted, with English economic thinking increasingly influenced by Renaissance humanist theories.[94]

Governance and taxation edit

 
Richard II meets the rebels calling for economic and political reform during the Peasants Revolt of 1381.

Even before the end of the first outbreak of the Black Death, there were efforts by the authorities to stem the upward pressure on wages and prices, with parliament passing the emergency Ordinance of Labourers in 1349 and the Statute of Labourers in 1351.[95] The efforts to regulate the economy continued as wages and prices rose, putting pressure on the landed classes, and in 1363 parliament attempted unsuccessfully to centrally regulate craft production, trading and retailing.[96] A rising amount of the royal courts' time was involved in enforcing the failing labour legislation—as much as 70% by the 1370s.[97] Many land owners attempted to vigorously enforce rents payable through agricultural service rather than money through their local manor courts, leading to many village communities attempting to legally challenge local feudal practices using the Domesday Book as a legal basis for their claims.[98] With the wages of the lower classes still rising, the government also attempted to regulate demand and consumption by reinstating the sumptuary laws in 1363.[99] These laws banned the lower classes from consuming certain products or wearing high status clothes, and reflected the significance of the consumption of high quality breads, ales and fabrics as a way of signifying social class in the late medieval period.[100]

The 1370s also saw the government facing difficulties in funding the war with France. The impact of the Hundred Years War on the English economy as a whole remains uncertain; one suggestion is that the high taxation required to pay for the conflict "shrunk and depleted" the English economy, whilst others have argued for the war having a more modest or even neutral economic impact.[101] The English government clearly found it difficult to pay for its army and from 1377 turned to a new system of poll taxes, aiming to spread the costs of taxation across the entire of English society.[102]

Peasants' Revolt of 1381 edit

One result of the economic and political tensions was the Peasants' Revolt of 1381 in which widespread rural discontent was followed by invasion of London involving thousands of rebels.[103] The rebels had many demands, including the effective end of the feudal institution of serfdom and a cap on the levels of rural rents.[104] The ensuing violence took the political classes by surprise and the revolt was not fully put down until the autumn, with up to 7,000 rebels being executed in the aftermath.[105] As a result of the revolt, parliament retreated from the poll tax and instead focused on a system of indirect taxes centring on foreign trade, with 80% of tax revenues drawn from the exports of wool.[106] Parliament continued to collect direct tax levies at historically high levels up until 1422, although they reduced in later years.[107] As a result, successive monarchs found that their tax revenues were uncertain, with Henry VI enjoying less than half the annual tax revenue of the late 14th century.[108] England's monarchs became increasingly dependent on borrowing and forced loans to meet the gap between taxes and expenditure and even then faced later rebellions over levels of taxation, including the Yorkshire rebellion of 1489 and the Cornish rebellion of 1497 during the reign of Henry VII.[109]

Trade, manufacturing and the towns edit

Shrinking towns edit

The percentage of England's population living in towns continued to grow but in absolute terms English towns shrunk significantly as a consequence of the Black Death, especially in the formerly prosperous east.[20] The importance of England's Eastern ports declined over the period, as trade from London and the South-West increased in relative significance.[110] Increasingly elaborate road networks were built across England, some involving the construction of up to thirty bridges to cross rivers and other obstacles.[111] Nonetheless, it remained cheaper to move goods by water, and consequently timber was brought to London from as far away as the Baltic, and stone from Caen brought over the Channel to the South of England.[111] Shipbuilding, particular in the South-West, became a major industry for the first time and investment in trading ships such as cogs was probably the single biggest form of late medieval investment in England.[112]

Rise of the cloth trade edit

 
Cog ships were increasingly important to English trade as both exports and imports grew.

Cloth manufactured in England increasingly dominated European markets during the 15th and early 16th centuries.[113] England exported almost no cloth at all in 1347, but by 1400 around 40,000 cloths[nb 3] a year were being exported – the trade reached its first peak in 1447 when exports reached 60,000.[32] Trade fell slightly during the serious depression of the mid-15th century, but picked up again and reached 130,000 cloths a year by the 1540s.[32] The centres of weaving in England shifted westwards towards the Stour Valley, the West Riding, the Cotswolds and Exeter, away from the former weaving centres in York, Coventry and Norwich.[114]

The wool and cloth trade was primarily now being run by English merchants themselves rather than by foreigners. Increasingly, the trade was also passing through London and the ports of the South-West. By the 1360s, between 66 and 75% of the export trade was in English hands and by the 15th century this had risen to 80%, with London managing around 50% of these exports in 1400, and as much as 83% of wool and cloth exports by 1540.[115] The growth in the numbers of chartered trading companies in London, such as the Worshipful Company of Drapers or the Company of Merchant Adventurers of London continued and English producers began to provide credit to European buyers, rather than the other way around.[48] Usury grew during the period, with few cases being prosecuted by the authorities.[116]

 
A medieval merchant's trading house in Southampton, restored to its mid-14th-century appearance.

There were some reversals. The attempts of English merchants to break through the Hanseatic league directly into the Baltic markets failed in the domestic political chaos of the Wars of the Roses in the 1460s and 1470s.[117] The wine trade with Gascony fell by half during the war with France, and the eventual loss of the province brought an end to the English domination of the business and temporary disruption to Bristol's prosperity until Spanish wines began to be imported through the city a few years later.[118] Indeed, the disruption to both the Baltic and the Gascon trade contributed to a sharp reduction in the consumption of furs and wine by the English gentry and nobility during the 15th century.[119]

There were advances in manufacturing, especially in the South and West. Despite some French attacks, the war created much coastal prosperity thanks to the huge expenditure on ship building during the war, with the South-West also becoming a centre for English piracy against foreign vessels.[120] Metalworking continued to grow and in particular, pewter working which generated exports second only to cloth.[121] By the 15th century pewter working in London was a large industry, with a hundred pewter workers recorded in London alone, and pewter working had also spread from London to eleven major cities across England.[122] London goldsmithing remained significant but saw relatively little growth, with around 150 goldsmiths working in London during the period.[123] Iron-working continued to expand and in 1509 the first cast iron cannon was made in England.[124] This was reflected in the rapid growth in the number of iron-working guilds, from three in 1300 to fourteen by 1422.[125]

The result was a substantial influx of money that in turn encouraged the import of manufactured luxury goods; by 1391 shipments from abroad routinely included "ivory, mirrors, paxes, armour, paper..., painted clothes, spectacles, tin images, razors, calamine, treacle, sugar-candy, marking irons, patens..., ox-horns and quantities of wainscot".[126] Imported spices now formed a part of almost all noble and gentry diets, with the quantities being consumed varying according to the wealth of the household.[127] The English government was also importing large quantities of raw materials, including copper, for manufacturing weapons.[128] Many major landowners tended to focus their efforts on maintaining a single major castle or house rather than the dozens a century before, but these were usually decorated much more luxurious than previously. Major merchants' dwellings, too, were more lavish than in previous years.[129]

Decline of the fair system edit

Towards the end of the 14th century, the position of fairs had begun to decline. The larger merchants, particularly in London, had begun to establish direct links with the larger landowners such as the nobility and the church; rather than the landowners buying from a chartered fair, they would buy directly from the merchant.[130] Meanwhile, the growth of the indigenous England merchant class in the major cities, especially London, gradually crowded out the foreign merchants upon whom the great chartered fairs had largely depended.[130] The crown's control over trade in the towns, especially the emerging newer towns towards the end of the 15th century that lacked central civic government, was increasingly weaker, making chartered status less relevant as more trade occurred from private properties and took place all year around.[131] Nonetheless, the great fairs remained of importance well into the 15th century, as illustrated by their role in exchanging money, regional commerce and in providing choice for individual consumers.[132]

See also edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ "Hanse" is the old English word for "group".
  2. ^ The precise mortality figures for the Black Death have debated at length for many years.
  3. ^ A "cloth" in medieval times was a single piece of woven fabric from a loom of a fixed size; an English broadcloth, for example, was 24 yards long and 1.75 yards wide (22 m by 1.6 m).

References edit

  1. ^ Dyer 2009, p.8.
  2. ^ a b Cantor 1982a, p.18.
  3. ^ a b Stenton, p.162, 166.
  4. ^ Douglas, p.303.
  5. ^ Sutton, p.2.
  6. ^ a b Douglas, p.313.
  7. ^ Douglas, p.314.
  8. ^ Hillaby, pp. 16–17.
  9. ^ Douglas, pp. 303–304.
  10. ^ a b c Stenton, p.162.
  11. ^ Douglas, p.299.
  12. ^ Douglas, p.299, 302.
  13. ^ Cantor 1982a, p.18 suggests an English population of 4 million; Jordan, p.12, suggests 5 million.
  14. ^ Burton, p.8.
  15. ^ Wood, p.15.
  16. ^ Astill, p.46.
  17. ^ Hodgett, p.57; Bailey, p.47; Pounds, p.15.
  18. ^ Hodgett, p.57.
  19. ^ a b Astill, pp48-49.
  20. ^ a b Pounds, p.80.
  21. ^ Nightingale, p.92; Danziger and Gillingham, p.58.
  22. ^ Geddes, pp. 174–175, p.181.
  23. ^ Homer, pp. 57–58.
  24. ^ Bailey, p.51.
  25. ^ Bailey, p.46; Homer, p.64.
  26. ^ Bartlett, p.361.
  27. ^ Bartlett, p.361; Bailey, p.52; Pilkinton p.xvi.
  28. ^ Hodgett, p.109.
  29. ^ a b Bartlett, p.363; Hodgett p.109.
  30. ^ Bartlett, p.364.
  31. ^ a b Hodgett, p.147.
  32. ^ a b c Ramsay, p.xxxi.
  33. ^ Stenton, p.169.
  34. ^ Stenton, pp169-170.
  35. ^ Bailey, p.49.
  36. ^ Stenton, p.163.
  37. ^ a b Ramsay, p.xx.
  38. ^ Myers, p.68.
  39. ^ Hodgett, p.147; Ramsay, p.xx.
  40. ^ Myers, p.69; Ramsay, p.xx.
  41. ^ a b c Myers, p.69.
  42. ^ Myers, p.69; Ramsay, p.xxiii.
  43. ^ Dyer 2009, p.209.
  44. ^ a b Danziger and Gillingham, p.65; Reyerson, p.67.
  45. ^ a b Danziger and Gillingham, p.65.
  46. ^ Dyer 2009, p.192; Harding, p.109.
  47. ^ Dyer 2009, p.209; Ramsay, p.xxiv; Danziger and Gillingham, p.65.
  48. ^ a b c Hodgett, p.148.
  49. ^ Hodgett, p.85.
  50. ^ Postan 1972, pp. 245–247.
  51. ^ Hillaby, p.16.
  52. ^ Hillaby, pp. 21–22.
  53. ^ Hillaby, p.22; Stenton, pp. 193–194.
  54. ^ a b Stenton, pp193-4.
  55. ^ Stenton, p.194.
  56. ^ Stenton, p.197.
  57. ^ Hillaby, p.28.
  58. ^ a b Stenton, p.200.
  59. ^ Hillaby, p.29; Stenton, p.200.
  60. ^ Stenton, p.199.
  61. ^ Hillaby, p.35.
  62. ^ Stacey, p.44.
  63. ^ a b Lawler and Lawler, p.6.
  64. ^ Bartlett, p.159; Postan 1972, p.261.
  65. ^ a b Hodgett, p.203.
  66. ^ Brown, Alfred 1989, p.76.
  67. ^ Tait, pp. 102–103.
  68. ^ Cooper, p.127.
  69. ^ Swedberg, p.77.
  70. ^ Bartlett, p.321.
  71. ^ Danziger and Gillingham, pp. 41–42.
  72. ^ Cantor 1982a, p.20; Aberth, p.14.
  73. ^ Aberth, pp. 13–14.
  74. ^ Richardson, p.32.
  75. ^ a b Jordan, p.38, 54; Aberth, p.20.
  76. ^ Jordan, p.54.
  77. ^ Jordan, p.12; Bailey, p.46; Aberth, p. 26–27; Cantor 1982a, p.18; Jordan, p.12.
  78. ^ Postan 1972, pp. 26–27; Aberth, p.26; Cantor 1982a, p.18; Jordan, p.12.
  79. ^ Aberth, p.34; Jordan, p.17, 19.
  80. ^ Jordan, p.17.
  81. ^ Fryde and Fryde, p.754.
  82. ^ Jordan, p.78; Hodgett, p.201.
  83. ^ Dyer 2009, p.271, 274; Hatcher 1996, p.37.
  84. ^ Dyer 2009, p.272, Hatcher 1996, p.25.
  85. ^ Dyer 2009, p.274.
  86. ^ Dyer 2009, pp. 272–273.
  87. ^ Dyer 2009, p.273.
  88. ^ a b Fryde, p.753.
  89. ^ Hatcher 1996, p.61.
  90. ^ Dyer 2009, p.278.
  91. ^ Kowaleski, p. 233.
  92. ^ Hatcher 1996, p. 36; Lee, p. 127.
  93. ^ Dyer 2009, pp 300–301.
  94. ^ Wood, p. 120, 173.
  95. ^ Fryde and Fryde, p.753; Bailey, p.47.
  96. ^ Ramsay, p.xxii; Jones, p.14.
  97. ^ Jones, p.15.
  98. ^ Jones, p.17.
  99. ^ Jones, p.16.
  100. ^ Jones, p.16; Woolgar, p.20.
  101. ^ Postan 1942, p.10; McFarlane, p.139.
  102. ^ Jones, p.21.
  103. ^ Jones, p.2.
  104. ^ Jones, pp114-5.
  105. ^ Jones, p. 201.
  106. ^ Jones, p. 207; McFarlane, p. 143.
  107. ^ McFarlane, p. 143.
  108. ^ McFarlane, p.143; Hodgett, p. 204.
  109. ^ McFarlane, p. 143; Hodgett, p. 204; Fletcher and MacCulloch, pp. 20–22.
  110. ^ Bailey, p. 48.
  111. ^ a b Hodgett, p. 110.
  112. ^ Kowaleski, p. 235.
  113. ^ Hodgett, p. 142.
  114. ^ Lee, p. 127.
  115. ^ Hodgett, p.148; Ramsay, p.xxxi; Kowalesk, p.248.
  116. ^ Wood, p. 173.
  117. ^ Postan 1972, p. 219.
  118. ^ Kowaleski, p. 238; Postan 1972, p. 219; Pilkinton, p.xvi.
  119. ^ Hatcher 2002, p. 266.
  120. ^ Kowaleski, p. 235, 252.
  121. ^ Homer, p. 73.
  122. ^ Homer, p.68, 70.
  123. ^ Homer, p.70.
  124. ^ Geddes, p.181.
  125. ^ Geddes, p.184.
  126. ^ Ramsay, ppxxxi-xxxii.
  127. ^ Woolgar, p.30.
  128. ^ Ramsay, p.xxxii.
  129. ^ Kermode, pp 19–21.
  130. ^ a b Myers, pp 161–4; Raban, p. 50; Barron, p. 78.
  131. ^ Dyer 2009, pp 319–20.
  132. ^ Ramsay, p.xxiv.

Bibliography edit

  • Aberth, John. (2001) From the Brink of the Apocalypse: Confronting Famine, War, Plague and Death in the Later Middle Ages. London: Routledge. ISBN 0-415-92715-3.
  • Abulafia, David. (ed) (1999) The New Cambridge Medieval History: c. 1198-c. 1300. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-36289-4.
  • Anderson, Michael. (ed) (1996) British Population History: From the Black Death to the Present Day. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-57884-4.
  • Archer, Rowena E. and Simon Walker. (eds) (1995) Rulers and Ruled in Late Medieval England. London: Hambledon Press. ISBN 978-1-85285-133-0.
  • Armstrong, Lawrin, Ivana Elbl and Martin M. Elbl. (eds) (2007) Money, Markets and Trade in Late Medieval Europe: Essays in Honour of John H. A. Munro. Leiden: BRILL. ISBN 978-90-04-15633-3.
  • Astill, Grenville. (2000) "General Survey 600-1300," in Palliser (ed) 2000.
  • Bailey, Mark. (1996) "Population and Economic Resources," in Given-Wilson (ed) 1996.
  • Barron, Caroline. (2005) London in the Later Middle Ages: Government and People 1200-1500. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-928441-2.
  • Blair, John and Nigel Ramsay. (eds) (2001) English Medieval Industries: Craftsmen, Techniques, Products. London: Hambledon Press. ISBN 978-1-85285-326-6.
  • Britnell, Richard and John Hatcher (eds). (2002) Progress and Problems in Medieval England: Essays in Honour of Edward Miller. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-52273-1.
  • Brown, Alfred L. (1989) The Governance of Late Medieval England, 1272-1461. Stanford: Stanford University Press. ISBN 978-0-8047-1730-4.
  • Burton, Janet E. (1994) Monastic and Religious Orders in Britain, 1000-1300. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-37797-3.
  • Cantor, Leonard (ed). (1982) The English Medieval Landscape. London: Croom Helm. ISBN 978-0-7099-0707-7.
  • Cantor, Leonard. (1982a) "Introduction: the English Medieval Landscape," in Cantor (ed) 1982.
  • Cooper, Alan. (2006) Bridges, Law and Power in Medieval England, 700-1400. Woodbridge, UK: Boydell Press. ISBN 978-1-84383-275-1.
  • Danziger, Danny and John Gillingham. (2003) 1215: The Year of the Magna Carta. London: Coronet Books. ISBN 978-0-7432-5778-7.
  • Dobbin, Frank. (ed) (2004) The Sociology of the Economy. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. ISBN 978-0-87154-284-7.
  • Douglas, David Charles. (1962) William the Conqueror: the Norman Impact upon England. Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Dyer, Christopher. (2009) Making a Living in the Middle Ages: The People of Britain, 850 - 1520. London: Yale University Press. ISBN 978-0-300-10191-1.
  • Fletcher, Anthony and Diarmaid MacCulloch. (2008) Tudor Rebellions. Harlow, UK: Pearson Education. ISBN 978-1-4058-7432-8.
  • Fryde, E. B. and Natalie Fryde. (1991) "Peasant Rebellion and Peasant Discontents," in Miller (ed) 1991.
  • Geddes, Jane. (2001) "Iron," in Blair and Ramsay (eds) 2001.
  • Given-Wilson, Chris (ed). (1996) An Illustrated History of Late Medieval England. Manchester: Manchester University Press. ISBN 978-0-7190-4152-5.
  • Hamilton, J. S. (ed) (2006) Fourteenth Century England, Volume 4. Woodbridge, UK: Boydell Press. ISBN 978-1-84383-220-1.
  • Harding, Alan. (1997) England in the Thirteenth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-31612-5.
  • Hatcher, John. (1996) "Plague, Population and the English Economy," in Anderson (ed) 1996.
  • Hicks, Michael (eds). (2001) The Fifteenth Century 2: Revolution and Consumption in Late Medieval England. Woodbridge, UK: Boydell. ISBN 978-0-85115-832-7.
  • Hillaby, Joe. (2003) "Jewish Colonisation in the Twelfth Century," in Skinner (ed) 2003.
  • Hodgett, Gerald. (2006) A Social and Economic History of Medieval Europe. Abingdon, UK: Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-37707-2.
  • Homer, Ronald F. (2010) "Tin, Lead and Pewter," in Blair and Ramsay (eds) 2001.
  • Jones, Dan. (2010) Summer of Blood: The Peasants' Revolt of 1381. London: Harper. ISBN 978-0-00-721393-1.
  • Jordan, William Chester. (1997) The Great Famine: Northern Europe in the Early Fourteenth Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-05891-7.
  • Kermode, Jenny. (1998) Medieval Merchants: York, Beverley and Hull in the Later Middle Ages. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-52274-8.
  • Kowalski, Maryanne. (2007) "Warfare, Shipping, and Crown Patronage: The Economic Impact of the Hundred Years War on the English Port Towns," in Armstrong, Elbl and Elbl (eds) 2007.
  • Lawler, John and Gail Gates Lawler. (2000) A Short Historical Introduction to the Law of Real Property. Washington DC: Beard Books. ISBN 978-1-58798-032-9.
  • Lee, John. (2001) "The Trade of Fifteenth Century Cambridge and its Region," in Hicks (ed) 2001.
  • McFarlane, Kenneth Bruce. (1981) England in the Fifteenth Century: Collected Essays. London: Hambledon Press. ISBN 978-0-907628-01-9.
  • Miller, Edward. (ed) (1991) The Agrarian History of England and Wales, Volume III: 1348-1500. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-20074-5.
  • Myers, A. R. (1971) England in the Late Middle Ages. Harmondsworth, UK: Penguin. ISBN 0-14-020234-X.
  • Nightingale, Pamela. (2002) "The growth of London in the medieval English economy," in Britnell and Hatcher (eds) 2002.
  • Palliser, D. M. (ed) (2000) The Cambridge Urban History of Britain: 600 - 1540, Volume 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-44461-3.
  • Pilkinton, Mark Cartwright. (1997) Bristol. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. ISBN 978-0-8020-4221-7.
  • Postan, M. M. (1942) "Some Social Consequences of the Hundred Years War," in Economic History Review, XII (1942).
  • Postan, M. M. (1972) The Medieval Economy and Society. Harmondsworth, UK: Penguin. ISBN 0-14-020896-8.
  • Pounds, Norman John Greville. (2005) The Medieval City. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press. ISBN 978-0-313-32498-7.
  • Raban, Sandra. (2000) England Under Edward I and Edward II, 1259-1327. Oxford: Blackwell. ISBN 978-0-631-22320-7.
  • Ramsay, Nigel. (2001) "Introduction," in Blair and Ramsay (eds) 2001.
  • Reyerson, Kathryn L. (1999) "Commerce and communications," in Abulafia (ed) 1999.
  • Richardson, Amanda. "Royal Landscapes," in Hamilton (ed) 2006.
  • Skinner, Patricia (ed). (2003) The Jews in Medieval Britain: Historical, Literary, and Archaeological Perspectives. Woodbridge, UK: Boydell. ISBN 978-0-85115-931-7.
  • Stacey, Robert C. (2003) "The English Jews under Henry III," in Skinner (ed) 2003.
  • Stenton, Doris Mary. (1976) English Society in the Early Middle Ages (1066–1307). Harmondsworth, UK: Penguin. ISBN 0-14-020252-8.
  • Swedberg, Richard. (2004) "On Legal Institutions and Their Role in the Economy," in Dobbin (ed) 2004.
  • Tait, James. (1999) The Medieval English Borough: Studies on its Origins and Constitutional History. Manchester: Manchester University Press. ISBN 978-0-7190-0339-4.
  • Wood, Diana. (2002) Medieval Economic Thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-45893-1.
  • Woolgar, Christopher. (1995) "Diet and Consumption in Gentry and Noble Households: A Case Study from around the Wash," in Archer and Walker (eds) 1995.

economics, english, towns, trade, middle, ages, economics, english, towns, trade, middle, ages, economic, history, english, towns, trade, from, norman, invasion, 1066, death, henry, 1509, although, england, economy, fundamentally, agricultural, throughout, per. The economics of English towns and trade in the Middle Ages is the economic history of English towns and trade from the Norman invasion in 1066 to the death of Henry VII in 1509 Although England s economy was fundamentally agricultural throughout the period even before the invasion the market economy was important to producers Norman institutions including serfdom were superimposed on a mature network of well established towns involved in international trade Over the next five centuries the English economy would at first grow and then suffer an acute crisis resulting in significant political and economic change Despite economic dislocation in urban areas including shifts in the holders of wealth and the location of these economies the economic output of towns developed and intensified over the period By the end of the period England would have a weak early modern government overseeing an economy involving a thriving community of indigenous English merchants and corporations Contents 1 Invasion and the early Norman period 1066 1100 1 1 Trade manufacturing and the towns 1 2 Governance and taxation 2 Mid medieval growth 1100 1290 2 1 Trade manufacturing and the towns 2 1 1 Growth of English towns 2 1 2 Expansion of the money supply 2 1 3 Rise of the guilds 2 1 4 Merchants and the development of the charter fairs 2 1 5 Jewish contribution to the English economy 2 2 Governance and taxation 3 Mid medieval economic crisis the Great Famine and the Black Death 1290 1350 3 1 Great Famine 3 2 Black Death 4 Late medieval economic recovery 1350 1509 4 1 Governance and taxation 4 1 1 Peasants Revolt of 1381 4 2 Trade manufacturing and the towns 4 2 1 Shrinking towns 4 2 2 Rise of the cloth trade 4 2 3 Decline of the fair system 5 See also 6 Notes 7 References 8 BibliographyInvasion and the early Norman period 1066 1100 editWilliam the Conqueror invaded England in 1066 defeating the Anglo Saxon King Harold Godwinson at the Battle of Hastings and placing the country under Norman rule This campaign was followed by fierce military operations known as the Harrying of the North between 1069 1070 extending Norman authority across the north of England William s system of government was broadly feudal in that the right to possess land was linked to service to the king but in many other ways the invasion did little to alter the nature of the English economy 1 Most of the damage done in the invasion was in the north and the west of England some of it still recorded as wasteland in 1086 2 Many of the key features of the English trading and financial system remained in place in the decades immediately after the conquest 2 Trade manufacturing and the towns edit nbsp A page of the Domesday Book capturing the economic condition of England in 1086 Although primarily rural England had a number of old economically important towns in 1066 3 A large amount of trade came through the Eastern towns including London York Winchester Lincoln Norwich Ipswich and Thetford 3 Much of this trade was with France the Low Countries and Germany but the North East of England traded with partners as far away as Sweden 4 Cloth was already being imported to England before the invasion through the mercery trade 5 Some towns such as York suffered from Norman sacking during William s northern campaigns 6 Other towns saw the widespread demolition of houses to make room for new motte and bailey fortifications as was the case in Lincoln 6 The Norman invasion also brought significant economic changes with the arrival of the first Jews to English cities 7 William I brought over wealthy Jews from the Rouen community in Normandy to settle in London apparently to carry out financial services for the crown 8 In the years immediately after the invasion a lot of wealth was drawn out of England in various ways by the Norman rulers and reinvested in Normandy making William immensely wealthy as an individual ruler 9 The minting of coins was decentralised in the Saxon period every borough was mandated to have a mint and therefore a centre for trading in bullion 10 Nonetheless there was strict royal control over these moneyers and coin dies could only be made in London 10 William retained this arrangement and also maintained a high coin standard which led to the use of the term sterling for Norman silver coins 10 Governance and taxation edit William I inherited the Anglo Saxon system in which the king drew his revenues from a mixture of customs profits from re minting coinage fines profits from his own demesne lands and the system of English land based taxation called the geld 11 William reaffirmed this system enforcing collection of the geld through his new system of sheriffs and increasing the taxes on trade 12 William was also famous for commissioning the Domesday Book in 1086 a vast document which attempted to record the economic condition of his new kingdom Mid medieval growth 1100 1290 editThe 12th and 13th centuries were a period of huge economic growth in England The population of England rose from around one and a half million in 1086 to around four or five million in 1300 stimulating increased agricultural outputs and the export of raw materials to Europe 13 In contrast to the previous two centuries England was relatively secure from invasion Except for the years of the Anarchy most military conflicts either had only localised economic impact or proved only temporarily disruptive English economic thinking remained conservative seeing the economy as consisting of three groups the ordines those who fought or the nobility laboratores those who worked in particular the peasantry and oratores those who prayed or the clerics 14 Trade and merchants played little part in this model and were frequently vilified at the start of the period although increasingly tolerated towards the end of the 13th century 15 Trade manufacturing and the towns edit Growth of English towns edit nbsp The medieval plan for Liverpool a new English town founded by order of King John in 1207 After the end of the Anarchy the number of small towns in England began to increase sharply 16 By 1297 a hundred and twenty new towns had established and in 1350 by when the expansion had effectively ceased there were around 500 towns in England 17 Many of these new towns were centrally planned Richard I created Portsmouth John founded Liverpool with Harwich Stony Stratford Dunstable Royston Baldock Wokingham Maidenhead and Reigate following under successive monarchs 18 The new towns were usually located with access to trade routes rather than defence in mind 19 The streets were laid out to make access to the town s market convenient 19 A growing percentage of England s population lived in urban areas estimates suggest that this rose from around 5 5 in 1086 to up to 10 in 1377 20 London held a special status within the English economy The nobility purchased and consumed many luxury goods and services in the capital and as early as the 1170s the London markets were providing exotic products such as spices incense palm oil gems silks furs and foreign weapons 21 London was also an important hub for industrial activity it had many blacksmiths making a wide range of goods including decorative ironwork and early clocks 22 Pewter working using English tin and lead was also widespread in London during the period 23 The provincial towns also had a substantial number of trades by the end of the 13th century a large town like Coventry for example contained over three hundred different specialist occupations and a smaller town such as Durham could support some sixty different professions 24 The increasing wealth of the nobility and the church was reflected in the widespread building of cathedrals and other prestigious buildings in the larger towns in turn making use of lead from English mines for roofing 25 Land transport remained much more expensive than river or sea transport during the period 26 Many towns in this period including York Exeter and Lincoln were linked to the oceans by navigable rivers and could act as seaports with Bristol s port coming to dominate the lucrative trade in wine with Gascony by the 13th century but shipbuilding generally remained on a modest scale and economically unimportant to England at this time 27 Transport remained very costly in comparison to the overall price of products 28 By the 13th century groups of common carriers ran carting businesses with carting brokers existing in London to link traders and carters 29 These used the four major land routes crossing England Ermine Street the Fosse Way Icknield Street and Watling Street 29 A large number of bridges were built during the 12th century to improve the trade network 30 In the 13th century England was still primarily supplying raw materials for export to Europe rather than finished or processed goods 31 There were some exceptions such as very high quality cloths from Stamford and Lincoln including the famous Lincoln Scarlet dyed cloth 31 Despite royal efforts to encourage it barely any English cloth was being exported by 1347 32 Expansion of the money supply edit nbsp An Edward I silver penny from Lincoln Edward increased the controls on the minting of coins begun under Henry II creating the Master of the Mint There was a gradual reduction in the number of locations allowed to mint coins in England under Henry II only 30 boroughs were still able to use their own moneyers and the tightening of controls continued throughout the 13th century 33 By the reign of Edward I there were only nine mints outside London and the king created a new official called the Master of the Mint to oversee these and the thirty furnaces operating in London to meet the supply for new coins 34 The amount of money in circulation hugely increased in this period before the Norman invasion there had been around 50 000 in circulation as coin but by 1311 this had risen to more than 1m 35 The physical implication of this growth was that coins had to be manufactured in large numbers being moved in barrels and sacks to be stored in local treasuries for royal use as the king travelled 36 During the 13th Century nominal wages fluctuated but the overall trend was flat As a result of the increase in money supply prices in general increased significantly over the course of the century As a result of the price inflation real wages one of the stickiest of prices declined steadily Rise of the guilds edit The first English guilds emerged during the early 12th century 37 These guilds were fraternities of craftsmen that set out to manage their local affairs including prices workmanship the welfare of its workers and the suppression of interlopers and sharp practices 38 Amongst these early guilds were the guilds merchants who ran the local markets in towns and represented the merchant community in discussions with the crown 37 Other early guilds included the craft guilds representing specific trades By 1130 there were major weavers guilds in six English towns as well as a fullers guild in Winchester 39 Over the coming decades more guilds were created often becoming increasingly involved in both local and national politics although the guilds merchants were largely replaced by official groups established by new royal charters 40 The craft guilds required relatively stable markets and a relative equality of income and opportunity amongst their members to function effectively 41 By the 14th century these conditions were increasingly uncommon 41 The first strains were seen in London where the old guild system began to collapse more trade was being conducted at a national level making it hard for craftsmen to both manufacture goods and trade in them and there were growing disparities in incomes between the richer and poor craftsmen 41 As a result under Edward III many guilds became companies or livery companies chartered companies focusing on trade and finance the management of large amounts of money leaving the guild structures to represent the interests of the smaller poorer manufacturers 42 Merchants and the development of the charter fairs edit nbsp The market place at Bridgnorth one of many medieval English towns to be granted the right to hold fairs in this case annually on the feast of the Translation of St Leonard The period also saw the development of charter fairs in England which reached their heyday in the 13th century 43 From the 12th century onwards many English towns acquired a charter from the Crown allowing them to hold an annual fair usually serving a regional or local customer base and lasting for two or three days 44 The practice increased in the next century and over 2 200 charters were issued to markets and fairs by English kings between 1200 and 1270 44 Fairs grew in popularity as the international wool trade increased the fairs allowed English wool producers and ports on the east coast to engage with visiting foreign merchants circumnavigating those English merchants in London keen to make a profit as middlemen 45 At the same time wealthy magnate consumers in England began to use the new fairs as a way to buy goods like spices wax preserved fish and foreign cloth in bulk from the international merchants at the fairs again bypassing the usual London merchants 46 Some fairs grew into major international events falling into a set sequence during the economic year with the Stamford fair in Lent St Ives in Easter Boston s in July Winchester s in September and Northampton s in November with the many smaller fairs falling in between 47 Although not as large as the famous Champagne fairs in France these English great fairs were still huge events St Ives Great Fair for example drew merchants from Flanders Brabant Norway Germany and France for a four week event each year turning the normally small town into a major commercial emporium 45 The structure of the fairs reflected the importance of foreign merchants in the English economy and by 1273 only one third of the English wool trade was actually controlled by English merchants 48 Between 1280 1320 the trade was primarily dominated by Italian merchants but by the early 14th century German merchants had begun to present serious competition to the Italians 48 The Germans formed a self governing alliance of merchants in London called the Hanse of the Steelyard the eventual Hanseatic League and their role was confirmed under the Great Charter of 1303 which exempted them from paying the customary tolls for foreign merchants 49 nb 1 One response to this was the creation of the Company of the Staple a group of merchants established in English held Calais in 1314 with royal approval who were granted a monopoly on wool sales to Europe 50 Jewish contribution to the English economy edit nbsp Clifford s Tower in the city of York a major hub for Jewish economic activity and the site of an early Jewish pogrom in 1190 The Jewish community in England continued to provide essential money lending and banking services that were otherwise banned by the usury laws and grew in the 12th century by Jewish immigrants fleeing the fighting around Rouen 51 The Jewish community spread beyond London to eleven major English cities primarily the major trading hubs in the east of England with functioning mints all with suitable castles for protection of the often persecuted Jewish minority 52 By the time of the Anarchy and the reign of Stephen the communities were flourishing and providing financial loans to the king 53 Under Henry II the Jewish financial community continued to grow richer still 54 All major towns had Jewish centres and even smaller towns such as Windsor saw visits travelling Jewish merchants 55 Henry II used the Jewish community as instruments for the collection of money for the Crown and placed them under royal protection 56 The Jewish community at York lent extensively to fund the Cistercian order s acquisition of land and prospered considerably 57 Some Jewish merchants grew extremely wealthy Aaron of Lincoln so much that upon his death a special royal department had to be established to unpick his financial holdings and affairs 58 By the end of Henry s reign the king ceased to borrow from the Jewish community and instead turned to an aggressive campaign of tallage taxation and fines 59 Financial and anti Semite violence grew under Richard I After the massacre of the York community in which numerous financial records were destroyed seven towns were nominated to separately store Jewish bonds and money records and this arrangement ultimately evolved into the Exchequer of the Jews 60 After an initially peaceful start to John s reign the king again began to extort money from the Jewish community imprisoning the wealthier members including Isaac of Norwich until a huge new taillage was paid 61 During the Baron s War of 1215 1217 the Jews were subjected to fresh anti Semitic attacks 58 Henry III restored some order and Jewish money lending became sufficiently successful again to allow fresh taxation 62 The Jewish community became poorer towards the end of the century and was finally expelled from England in 1290 by Edward I being largely replaced by foreign merchants 54 Governance and taxation edit nbsp A medieval carving from Rievaulx Abbey showing of one of the many new windmills established during the 13th century During the 12th century the Norman kings attempted to formalise the feudal governance system initially created after the invasion After the invasion the king had enjoyed combination of income from his own demesne lands the Anglo Saxon geld tax and fines Successive kings found that they needed additional revenues especially in order to pay for mercenary forces 63 One way of doing this was to exploit the feudal system and kings adopted the French feudal aid model a levy of money imposed on feudal subordinates when necessary another method was to exploit the scutage system in which feudal military service could be transmuted to a cash payment to the king 63 Taxation was also an option although the old geld tax was increasingly ineffective due to an increasing number of exemptions Instead a succession of kings created alternative land taxes such as the tallage and carucage taxes These were increasingly unpopular and along with the feudal charges were condemned and constrained in the Magna Carta of 1215 As part of the formalisation of the royal finances Henry I created the Chancellor of the Exchequer a post which would lead to the maintenance of the Pipe rolls a set of royal financial records of lasting significance to historians in tracking both royal finances and medieval prices 64 Royal revenue streams still proved insufficient and from the middle of the 13th century there was a shift away from the earlier land based tax system towards one based on a mixture of indirect and direct taxation 65 At the same time Henry III of England had introduced the practice of consulting with leading nobles on tax issues leading to the system of the English parliament agreeing on new taxes when required In 1275 the Great and Ancient Custom began to tax woollen products and hides with the Great Charter of 1303 imposing additional levies on foreign merchants in England with the poundage tax introduced in 1347 65 In 1340 the discredited tallage tax system was finally abolished by Edward III 66 In the English towns the burgage tenure for urban properties was established early on in the medieval period being based primarily on tenants paying cash rents rather than providing labour services 67 Further development of a set of taxes that could be raised by the towns including murage for walls pavage for streets or pontage a temporary tax for the repair of bridges 68 Combined with the lex mercatoria which was a set of codes and customary practices governing trading provided a reasonable basis for the economic governance of the towns 69 The 12th century also saw a concerted attempt to curtail the remaining rights of unfree peasant workers and to set out their labour rents more explicitly in the form of the English Common Law 70 This process resulted in the Magna Carta explicitly authorising feudal landowners to settle law cases concerning feudal labour and fines through their own manorial courts rather than through the royal courts 71 Mid medieval economic crisis the Great Famine and the Black Death 1290 1350 edit nbsp The Black Death reached England in 1348 from Europe Great Famine edit The Great Famine of 1315 began a number of acute crises in the English agrarian economy The famine centred on a sequence of harvest failures in 1315 1316 and 1321 combined with an outbreak of the murrain sickness amongst sheep and oxen between 1319 1321 and the fatal ergotism fungi amongst the remaining stocks of wheat 72 In the ensuing famine many people died and the peasantry were said to have been forced to eat horses dogs and cats as well to have conducted cannibalism against children although these last reports are usually considered to be exaggerations 73 Poaching and encroachment on the royal forests surged sometimes on a mass scale 74 Sheep and cattle numbers fell by up to a half significantly reducing the availability of wool and meat and food prices almost doubled with grain prices particularly inflated 75 Food prices remained at similar levels for the next decade 75 Salt prices also increased sharply due to the wet weather 76 Various factors exacerbated the crisis Economic growth had already begun to slow significantly in the years prior to the crisis and the English rural population was increasingly under economic stress with around half the peasantry estimated to possess insufficient land to provide them with a secure livelihood 77 Where additional land was being brought into cultivation or existing land cultivated more intensively the soil may have become exhausted and useless 78 Bad weather also played an important part in the disaster 1315 6 and 1318 saw torrential rains and an incredibly cold winter which in combination badly impacted on harvests and stored supplies 79 The rains of these years was followed by drought in the 1320s and another fierce winter in 1321 complicating recovery 80 Disease independent of the famine was also high during the period striking at the wealthier as well as the poorer classes The commencement of war with France in 1337 only added to the economic difficulties 81 The Great Famine firmly reversed the population growth of the 12th and 13th centuries and left a domestic economy that was profoundly shaken but not destroyed 82 Black Death edit The Black Death epidemic first arrived in England in 1348 re occurring in waves during 1360 1362 1368 1369 1375 and more sporadically thereafter 83 The most immediate economic impact of this disaster was the widespread loss of life between around 27 mortality amongst the upper classes to 40 70 amongst the peasantry 84 nb 2 Despite the very high loss of life few settlements were abandoned during the epidemic itself but many were badly affected or nearly eliminated altogether 85 The medieval authorities did their best to respond in an organised fashion but the economic disruption was immense 86 Building work ceased and many mining operations paused 87 In the short term efforts were taken by the authorities to control wages and enforce pre epidemic working conditions 88 Coming on top of the previous years of famine however the longer term economic implications were profound 88 In contrast to the previous centuries of rapid growth the English population would not begin to recover for over a century despite the many positive reasons for a resurgence 89 The crisis would dramatically affect English agriculture wages and prices for the remainder of the medieval period 90 Late medieval economic recovery 1350 1509 editThe events of the crisis between 1290 and 1348 and the subsequent epidemics produced many challenges for the English economy In the decades after the disaster the economic and social issues arising from the Black Death combined with the costs of the Hundred Years War to produce the Peasants Revolt of 1381 91 Although the revolt was suppressed it undermined many of the vestiges of the feudal economic order and the countryside became dominated by estates organised as farms frequently owned or rented by the new economic class of the gentry The English agricultural economy remained depressed throughout the 15th century with growth coming from the greatly increased English cloth trade and manufacturing 92 The economic consequences of this varied considerably from region to region but generally London the South and the West prospered at the expense of the Eastern and the older cities 93 The role of merchants and of trade became increasingly seen as important to the country and usury became increasingly accepted with English economic thinking increasingly influenced by Renaissance humanist theories 94 Governance and taxation edit nbsp Richard II meets the rebels calling for economic and political reform during the Peasants Revolt of 1381 Even before the end of the first outbreak of the Black Death there were efforts by the authorities to stem the upward pressure on wages and prices with parliament passing the emergency Ordinance of Labourers in 1349 and the Statute of Labourers in 1351 95 The efforts to regulate the economy continued as wages and prices rose putting pressure on the landed classes and in 1363 parliament attempted unsuccessfully to centrally regulate craft production trading and retailing 96 A rising amount of the royal courts time was involved in enforcing the failing labour legislation as much as 70 by the 1370s 97 Many land owners attempted to vigorously enforce rents payable through agricultural service rather than money through their local manor courts leading to many village communities attempting to legally challenge local feudal practices using the Domesday Book as a legal basis for their claims 98 With the wages of the lower classes still rising the government also attempted to regulate demand and consumption by reinstating the sumptuary laws in 1363 99 These laws banned the lower classes from consuming certain products or wearing high status clothes and reflected the significance of the consumption of high quality breads ales and fabrics as a way of signifying social class in the late medieval period 100 The 1370s also saw the government facing difficulties in funding the war with France The impact of the Hundred Years War on the English economy as a whole remains uncertain one suggestion is that the high taxation required to pay for the conflict shrunk and depleted the English economy whilst others have argued for the war having a more modest or even neutral economic impact 101 The English government clearly found it difficult to pay for its army and from 1377 turned to a new system of poll taxes aiming to spread the costs of taxation across the entire of English society 102 Peasants Revolt of 1381 edit One result of the economic and political tensions was the Peasants Revolt of 1381 in which widespread rural discontent was followed by invasion of London involving thousands of rebels 103 The rebels had many demands including the effective end of the feudal institution of serfdom and a cap on the levels of rural rents 104 The ensuing violence took the political classes by surprise and the revolt was not fully put down until the autumn with up to 7 000 rebels being executed in the aftermath 105 As a result of the revolt parliament retreated from the poll tax and instead focused on a system of indirect taxes centring on foreign trade with 80 of tax revenues drawn from the exports of wool 106 Parliament continued to collect direct tax levies at historically high levels up until 1422 although they reduced in later years 107 As a result successive monarchs found that their tax revenues were uncertain with Henry VI enjoying less than half the annual tax revenue of the late 14th century 108 England s monarchs became increasingly dependent on borrowing and forced loans to meet the gap between taxes and expenditure and even then faced later rebellions over levels of taxation including the Yorkshire rebellion of 1489 and the Cornish rebellion of 1497 during the reign of Henry VII 109 Trade manufacturing and the towns edit Shrinking towns edit The percentage of England s population living in towns continued to grow but in absolute terms English towns shrunk significantly as a consequence of the Black Death especially in the formerly prosperous east 20 The importance of England s Eastern ports declined over the period as trade from London and the South West increased in relative significance 110 Increasingly elaborate road networks were built across England some involving the construction of up to thirty bridges to cross rivers and other obstacles 111 Nonetheless it remained cheaper to move goods by water and consequently timber was brought to London from as far away as the Baltic and stone from Caen brought over the Channel to the South of England 111 Shipbuilding particular in the South West became a major industry for the first time and investment in trading ships such as cogs was probably the single biggest form of late medieval investment in England 112 Rise of the cloth trade edit nbsp Cog ships were increasingly important to English trade as both exports and imports grew Cloth manufactured in England increasingly dominated European markets during the 15th and early 16th centuries 113 England exported almost no cloth at all in 1347 but by 1400 around 40 000 cloths nb 3 a year were being exported the trade reached its first peak in 1447 when exports reached 60 000 32 Trade fell slightly during the serious depression of the mid 15th century but picked up again and reached 130 000 cloths a year by the 1540s 32 The centres of weaving in England shifted westwards towards the Stour Valley the West Riding the Cotswolds and Exeter away from the former weaving centres in York Coventry and Norwich 114 The wool and cloth trade was primarily now being run by English merchants themselves rather than by foreigners Increasingly the trade was also passing through London and the ports of the South West By the 1360s between 66 and 75 of the export trade was in English hands and by the 15th century this had risen to 80 with London managing around 50 of these exports in 1400 and as much as 83 of wool and cloth exports by 1540 115 The growth in the numbers of chartered trading companies in London such as the Worshipful Company of Drapers or the Company of Merchant Adventurers of London continued and English producers began to provide credit to European buyers rather than the other way around 48 Usury grew during the period with few cases being prosecuted by the authorities 116 nbsp A medieval merchant s trading house in Southampton restored to its mid 14th century appearance There were some reversals The attempts of English merchants to break through the Hanseatic league directly into the Baltic markets failed in the domestic political chaos of the Wars of the Roses in the 1460s and 1470s 117 The wine trade with Gascony fell by half during the war with France and the eventual loss of the province brought an end to the English domination of the business and temporary disruption to Bristol s prosperity until Spanish wines began to be imported through the city a few years later 118 Indeed the disruption to both the Baltic and the Gascon trade contributed to a sharp reduction in the consumption of furs and wine by the English gentry and nobility during the 15th century 119 There were advances in manufacturing especially in the South and West Despite some French attacks the war created much coastal prosperity thanks to the huge expenditure on ship building during the war with the South West also becoming a centre for English piracy against foreign vessels 120 Metalworking continued to grow and in particular pewter working which generated exports second only to cloth 121 By the 15th century pewter working in London was a large industry with a hundred pewter workers recorded in London alone and pewter working had also spread from London to eleven major cities across England 122 London goldsmithing remained significant but saw relatively little growth with around 150 goldsmiths working in London during the period 123 Iron working continued to expand and in 1509 the first cast iron cannon was made in England 124 This was reflected in the rapid growth in the number of iron working guilds from three in 1300 to fourteen by 1422 125 The result was a substantial influx of money that in turn encouraged the import of manufactured luxury goods by 1391 shipments from abroad routinely included ivory mirrors paxes armour paper painted clothes spectacles tin images razors calamine treacle sugar candy marking irons patens ox horns and quantities of wainscot 126 Imported spices now formed a part of almost all noble and gentry diets with the quantities being consumed varying according to the wealth of the household 127 The English government was also importing large quantities of raw materials including copper for manufacturing weapons 128 Many major landowners tended to focus their efforts on maintaining a single major castle or house rather than the dozens a century before but these were usually decorated much more luxurious than previously Major merchants dwellings too were more lavish than in previous years 129 Decline of the fair system edit Towards the end of the 14th century the position of fairs had begun to decline The larger merchants particularly in London had begun to establish direct links with the larger landowners such as the nobility and the church rather than the landowners buying from a chartered fair they would buy directly from the merchant 130 Meanwhile the growth of the indigenous England merchant class in the major cities especially London gradually crowded out the foreign merchants upon whom the great chartered fairs had largely depended 130 The crown s control over trade in the towns especially the emerging newer towns towards the end of the 15th century that lacked central civic government was increasingly weaker making chartered status less relevant as more trade occurred from private properties and took place all year around 131 Nonetheless the great fairs remained of importance well into the 15th century as illustrated by their role in exchanging money regional commerce and in providing choice for individual consumers 132 See also editTaxation in medieval England History of the English penny c 600 1066 History of the English penny 1154 1485 Notes edit Hanse is the old English word for group The precise mortality figures for the Black Death have debated at length for many years A cloth in medieval times was a single piece of woven fabric from a loom of a fixed size an English broadcloth for example was 24 yards long and 1 75 yards wide 22 m by 1 6 m References edit Dyer 2009 p 8 a b Cantor 1982a p 18 a b Stenton p 162 166 Douglas p 303 Sutton p 2 a b Douglas p 313 Douglas p 314 Hillaby pp 16 17 Douglas pp 303 304 a b c Stenton p 162 Douglas p 299 Douglas p 299 302 Cantor 1982a p 18 suggests an English population of 4 million Jordan p 12 suggests 5 million Burton p 8 Wood p 15 Astill p 46 Hodgett p 57 Bailey p 47 Pounds p 15 Hodgett p 57 a b Astill pp48 49 a b Pounds p 80 Nightingale p 92 Danziger and Gillingham p 58 Geddes pp 174 175 p 181 Homer pp 57 58 Bailey p 51 Bailey p 46 Homer p 64 Bartlett p 361 Bartlett p 361 Bailey p 52 Pilkinton p xvi Hodgett p 109 a b Bartlett p 363 Hodgett p 109 Bartlett p 364 a b Hodgett p 147 a b c Ramsay p xxxi Stenton p 169 Stenton pp169 170 Bailey p 49 Stenton p 163 a b Ramsay p xx Myers p 68 Hodgett p 147 Ramsay p xx Myers p 69 Ramsay p xx a b c Myers p 69 Myers p 69 Ramsay p xxiii Dyer 2009 p 209 a b Danziger and Gillingham p 65 Reyerson p 67 a b Danziger and Gillingham p 65 Dyer 2009 p 192 Harding p 109 Dyer 2009 p 209 Ramsay p xxiv Danziger and Gillingham p 65 a b c Hodgett p 148 Hodgett p 85 Postan 1972 pp 245 247 Hillaby p 16 Hillaby pp 21 22 Hillaby p 22 Stenton pp 193 194 a b Stenton pp193 4 Stenton p 194 Stenton p 197 Hillaby p 28 a b Stenton p 200 Hillaby p 29 Stenton p 200 Stenton p 199 Hillaby p 35 Stacey p 44 a b Lawler and Lawler p 6 Bartlett p 159 Postan 1972 p 261 a b Hodgett p 203 Brown Alfred 1989 p 76 Tait pp 102 103 Cooper p 127 Swedberg p 77 Bartlett p 321 Danziger and Gillingham pp 41 42 Cantor 1982a p 20 Aberth p 14 Aberth pp 13 14 Richardson p 32 a b Jordan p 38 54 Aberth p 20 Jordan p 54 Jordan p 12 Bailey p 46 Aberth p 26 27 Cantor 1982a p 18 Jordan p 12 Postan 1972 pp 26 27 Aberth p 26 Cantor 1982a p 18 Jordan p 12 Aberth p 34 Jordan p 17 19 Jordan p 17 Fryde and Fryde p 754 Jordan p 78 Hodgett p 201 Dyer 2009 p 271 274 Hatcher 1996 p 37 Dyer 2009 p 272 Hatcher 1996 p 25 Dyer 2009 p 274 Dyer 2009 pp 272 273 Dyer 2009 p 273 a b Fryde p 753 Hatcher 1996 p 61 Dyer 2009 p 278 Kowaleski p 233 Hatcher 1996 p 36 Lee p 127 Dyer 2009 pp 300 301 Wood p 120 173 Fryde and Fryde p 753 Bailey p 47 Ramsay p xxii Jones p 14 Jones p 15 Jones p 17 Jones p 16 Jones p 16 Woolgar p 20 Postan 1942 p 10 McFarlane p 139 Jones p 21 Jones p 2 Jones pp114 5 Jones p 201 Jones p 207 McFarlane p 143 McFarlane p 143 McFarlane p 143 Hodgett p 204 McFarlane p 143 Hodgett p 204 Fletcher and MacCulloch pp 20 22 Bailey p 48 a b Hodgett p 110 Kowaleski p 235 Hodgett p 142 Lee p 127 Hodgett p 148 Ramsay p xxxi Kowalesk p 248 Wood p 173 Postan 1972 p 219 Kowaleski p 238 Postan 1972 p 219 Pilkinton p xvi Hatcher 2002 p 266 Kowaleski p 235 252 Homer p 73 Homer p 68 70 Homer p 70 Geddes p 181 Geddes p 184 Ramsay ppxxxi xxxii Woolgar p 30 Ramsay p xxxii Kermode pp 19 21 a b Myers pp 161 4 Raban p 50 Barron p 78 Dyer 2009 pp 319 20 Ramsay p xxiv Bibliography editAberth John 2001 From the Brink of the Apocalypse Confronting Famine War Plague and Death in the Later Middle Ages London Routledge ISBN 0 415 92715 3 Abulafia David ed 1999 The New Cambridge Medieval History c 1198 c 1300 Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 36289 4 Anderson Michael ed 1996 British Population History From the Black Death to the Present Day Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 57884 4 Archer Rowena E and Simon Walker eds 1995 Rulers and Ruled in Late Medieval England London Hambledon Press ISBN 978 1 85285 133 0 Armstrong Lawrin Ivana Elbl and Martin M Elbl eds 2007 Money Markets and Trade in Late Medieval Europe Essays in Honour of John H A Munro Leiden BRILL ISBN 978 90 04 15633 3 Astill Grenville 2000 General Survey 600 1300 in Palliser ed 2000 Bailey Mark 1996 Population and Economic Resources in Given Wilson ed 1996 Barron Caroline 2005 London in the Later Middle Ages Government and People 1200 1500 Oxford Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 928441 2 Blair John and Nigel Ramsay eds 2001 English Medieval Industries Craftsmen Techniques Products London Hambledon Press ISBN 978 1 85285 326 6 Britnell Richard and John Hatcher eds 2002 Progress and Problems in Medieval England Essays in Honour of Edward Miller Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 52273 1 Brown Alfred L 1989 The Governance of Late Medieval England 1272 1461 Stanford Stanford University Press ISBN 978 0 8047 1730 4 Burton Janet E 1994 Monastic and Religious Orders in Britain 1000 1300 Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 37797 3 Cantor Leonard ed 1982 The English Medieval Landscape London Croom Helm ISBN 978 0 7099 0707 7 Cantor Leonard 1982a Introduction the English Medieval Landscape in Cantor ed 1982 Cooper Alan 2006 Bridges Law and Power in Medieval England 700 1400 Woodbridge UK Boydell Press ISBN 978 1 84383 275 1 Danziger Danny and John Gillingham 2003 1215 The Year of the Magna Carta London Coronet Books ISBN 978 0 7432 5778 7 Dobbin Frank ed 2004 The Sociology of the Economy New York Russell Sage Foundation ISBN 978 0 87154 284 7 Douglas David Charles 1962 William the Conqueror the Norman Impact upon England Berkeley University of California Press Dyer Christopher 2009 Making a Living in the Middle Ages The People of Britain 850 1520 London Yale University Press ISBN 978 0 300 10191 1 Fletcher Anthony and Diarmaid MacCulloch 2008 Tudor Rebellions Harlow UK Pearson Education ISBN 978 1 4058 7432 8 Fryde E B and Natalie Fryde 1991 Peasant Rebellion and Peasant Discontents in Miller ed 1991 Geddes Jane 2001 Iron in Blair and Ramsay eds 2001 Given Wilson Chris ed 1996 An Illustrated History of Late Medieval England Manchester Manchester University Press ISBN 978 0 7190 4152 5 Hamilton J S ed 2006 Fourteenth Century England Volume 4 Woodbridge UK Boydell Press ISBN 978 1 84383 220 1 Harding Alan 1997 England in the Thirteenth Century Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 31612 5 Hatcher John 1996 Plague Population and the English Economy in Anderson ed 1996 Hicks Michael eds 2001 The Fifteenth Century 2 Revolution and Consumption in Late Medieval England Woodbridge UK Boydell ISBN 978 0 85115 832 7 Hillaby Joe 2003 Jewish Colonisation in the Twelfth Century in Skinner ed 2003 Hodgett Gerald 2006 A Social and Economic History of Medieval Europe Abingdon UK Routledge ISBN 978 0 415 37707 2 Homer Ronald F 2010 Tin Lead and Pewter in Blair and Ramsay eds 2001 Jones Dan 2010 Summer of Blood The Peasants Revolt of 1381 London Harper ISBN 978 0 00 721393 1 Jordan William Chester 1997 The Great Famine Northern Europe in the Early Fourteenth Century Princeton Princeton University Press ISBN 978 0 691 05891 7 Kermode Jenny 1998 Medieval Merchants York Beverley and Hull in the Later Middle Ages Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 52274 8 Kowalski Maryanne 2007 Warfare Shipping and Crown Patronage The Economic Impact of the Hundred Years War on the English Port Towns in Armstrong Elbl and Elbl eds 2007 Lawler John and Gail Gates Lawler 2000 A Short Historical Introduction to the Law of Real Property Washington DC Beard Books ISBN 978 1 58798 032 9 Lee John 2001 The Trade of Fifteenth Century Cambridge and its Region in Hicks ed 2001 McFarlane Kenneth Bruce 1981 England in the Fifteenth Century Collected Essays London Hambledon Press ISBN 978 0 907628 01 9 Miller Edward ed 1991 The Agrarian History of England and Wales Volume III 1348 1500 Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 20074 5 Myers A R 1971 England in the Late Middle Ages Harmondsworth UK Penguin ISBN 0 14 020234 X Nightingale Pamela 2002 The growth of London in the medieval English economy in Britnell and Hatcher eds 2002 Palliser D M ed 2000 The Cambridge Urban History of Britain 600 1540 Volume 1 Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 44461 3 Pilkinton Mark Cartwright 1997 Bristol Toronto University of Toronto Press ISBN 978 0 8020 4221 7 Postan M M 1942 Some Social Consequences of the Hundred Years War in Economic History Review XII 1942 Postan M M 1972 The Medieval Economy and Society Harmondsworth UK Penguin ISBN 0 14 020896 8 Pounds Norman John Greville 2005 The Medieval City Westport CT Greenwood Press ISBN 978 0 313 32498 7 Raban Sandra 2000 England Under Edward I and Edward II 1259 1327 Oxford Blackwell ISBN 978 0 631 22320 7 Ramsay Nigel 2001 Introduction in Blair and Ramsay eds 2001 Reyerson Kathryn L 1999 Commerce and communications in Abulafia ed 1999 Richardson Amanda Royal Landscapes in Hamilton ed 2006 Skinner Patricia ed 2003 The Jews in Medieval Britain Historical Literary and Archaeological Perspectives Woodbridge UK Boydell ISBN 978 0 85115 931 7 Stacey Robert C 2003 The English Jews under Henry III in Skinner ed 2003 Stenton Doris Mary 1976 English Society in the Early Middle Ages 1066 1307 Harmondsworth UK Penguin ISBN 0 14 020252 8 Swedberg Richard 2004 On Legal Institutions and Their Role in the Economy in Dobbin ed 2004 Tait James 1999 The Medieval English Borough Studies on its Origins and Constitutional History Manchester Manchester University Press ISBN 978 0 7190 0339 4 Wood Diana 2002 Medieval Economic Thought Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 45893 1 Woolgar Christopher 1995 Diet and Consumption in Gentry and Noble Households A Case Study from around the Wash in Archer and Walker eds 1995 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Economics of English towns and trade in the Middle Ages amp oldid 1157662007, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.