fbpx
Wikipedia

Diversification (finance)

In finance, diversification is the process of allocating capital in a way that reduces the exposure to any one particular asset or risk. A common path towards diversification is to reduce risk or volatility by investing in a variety of assets. If asset prices do not change in perfect synchrony, a diversified portfolio will have less variance than the weighted average variance of its constituent assets, and often less volatility than the least volatile of its constituents.[1]

Diversification is one of two general techniques for reducing investment risk. The other is hedging.

Examples edit

The simplest example of diversification is provided by the proverb "Don't put all your eggs in one basket". Dropping the basket will break all the eggs. Placing each egg in a different basket is more diversified. There is more risk of losing one egg, but less risk of losing all of them. On the other hand, having a lot of baskets may increase costs.

In finance, an example of an undiversified portfolio is to hold only one stock. This is risky; it is not unusual for a single stock to go down 50% in one year. It is less common for a portfolio of 20 stocks to go down that much, especially if they are selected at random. If the stocks are selected from a variety of industries, company sizes and asset types it is even less likely to experience a 50% drop since it will mitigate any trends in that industry, company class, or asset type.

Since the mid-1970s, it has also been argued that geographic diversification would generate superior risk-adjusted returns for large institutional investors by reducing overall portfolio risk while capturing some of the higher rates of return offered by the emerging markets of Asia and Latin America.[2][3]

Return expectations while diversifying edit

If the prior expectations of the returns on all assets in the portfolio are identical, the expected return on a diversified portfolio will be identical to that on an undiversified portfolio. Some assets will do better than others; but since one does not know in advance which assets will perform better, this fact cannot be exploited in advance. The return on a diversified portfolio can never exceed that of the top-performing investment, and indeed will always be lower than the highest return (unless all returns are identical). Conversely, the diversified portfolio's return will always be higher than that of the worst-performing investment. So by diversifying, one loses the chance of having invested solely in the single asset that comes out best, but one also avoids having invested solely in the asset that comes out worst. That is the role of diversification: it narrows the range of possible outcomes. Diversification need not either help or hurt expected returns, unless the alternative non-diversified portfolio has a higher expected return.[4]

Amount of diversification edit

There is no magic number of stocks that is diversified versus not. Sometimes quoted is 30, although it can be as low as 10, provided they are carefully chosen. This is based on a result from John Evans and Stephen Archer.[5] Similarly, a 1985 book reported that most value from diversification comes from the first 15 or 20 different stocks in a portfolio.[6] More stocks give lower price volatility.

Given the advantages of diversification, many experts [who?] recommend maximum diversification, also known as "buying the market portfolio". Identifying that portfolio is not straightforward. The earliest definition comes from the capital asset pricing model which argues the maximum diversification comes from buying a pro rata share of all available assets. This is the idea underlying index funds.

Diversification has no maximum so long as more assets are available.[7] Every equally weighted, uncorrelated asset added to a portfolio can add to that portfolio's measured diversification. When assets are not uniformly uncorrelated, a weighting approach that puts assets in proportion to their relative correlation can maximize the available diversification.

"Risk parity" is an alternative idea. This weights assets in inverse proportion to risk, so the portfolio has equal risk in all asset classes. This is justified both on theoretical grounds, and with the pragmatic argument that future risk is much easier to forecast than either future market price or future economic footprint.[8] "Correlation parity" is an extension of risk parity, and is the solution whereby each asset in a portfolio has an equal correlation with the portfolio, and is therefore the "most diversified portfolio". Risk parity is the special case of correlation parity when all pair-wise correlations are equal.[9]

Effect of diversification on variance edit

One simple measure of financial risk is variance of the return on the portfolio. Diversification can lower the variance of a portfolio's return below what it would be if the entire portfolio were invested in the asset with the lowest variance of return, even if the assets' returns are uncorrelated. For example, let asset X have stochastic return   and asset Y have stochastic return  , with respective return variances   and  . If the fraction   of a one-unit (e.g. one-million-dollar) portfolio is placed in asset X and the fraction   is placed in Y, the stochastic portfolio return is  . If   and   are uncorrelated, the variance of portfolio return is  . The variance-minimizing value of   is  , which is strictly between   and  . Using this value of   in the expression for the variance of portfolio return gives the latter as  , which is less than what it would be at either of the undiversified values   and   (which respectively give portfolio return variance of   and  ). Note that the favorable effect of diversification on portfolio variance would be enhanced if   and   were negatively correlated but diminished (though not eliminated) if they were positively correlated.

In general, the presence of more assets in a portfolio leads to greater diversification benefits, as can be seen by considering portfolio variance as a function of  , the number of assets. For example, if all assets' returns are mutually uncorrelated and have identical variances  , portfolio variance is minimized by holding all assets in the equal proportions  .[10] Then the portfolio return's variance equals   =   =  , which is monotonically decreasing in  .

The latter analysis can be adapted to show why adding uncorrelated volatile assets to a portfolio,[11][12] thereby increasing the portfolio's size, is not diversification, which involves subdividing the portfolio among many smaller investments. In the case of adding investments, the portfolio's return is   instead of   and the variance of the portfolio return if the assets are uncorrelated is   which is increasing in n rather than decreasing. Thus, for example, when an insurance company adds more and more uncorrelated policies to its portfolio, this expansion does not itself represent diversification—the diversification occurs in the spreading of the insurance company's risks over a large number of part-owners of the company.

Diversification with correlated returns via an equally weighted portfolio edit

The expected return on a portfolio is a weighted average of the expected returns on each individual asset:

 

where   is the proportion of the investor's total invested wealth in asset  .

The variance of the portfolio return is given by:

 

Inserting in the expression for  :

 

Rearranging:

 
 
 
 
 

where   is the variance on asset   and   is the covariance between assets   and  .

In an equally weighted portfolio,  . The portfolio variance then becomes:

 

where   is the average of the covariances   for   and   is the average of the variances. Simplifying, we obtain

 

As the number of assets grows we get the asymptotic formula:

 

Thus, in an equally weighted portfolio, the portfolio variance tends to the average of covariances between securities as the number of securities becomes arbitrarily large.

Diversifiable and non-diversifiable risk edit

The capital asset pricing model introduced the concepts of diversifiable and non-diversifiable risk. Synonyms for diversifiable risk are idiosyncratic risk, unsystematic risk, and security-specific risk. Synonyms for non-diversifiable risk are systematic risk, beta risk and market risk.

If one buys all the stocks in the S&P 500 one is obviously exposed only to movements in that index. If one buys a single stock in the S&P 500, one is exposed both to index movements and movements in the stock based on its underlying company. The first risk is called "non-diversifiable", because it exists however many S&P 500 stocks are bought. The second risk is called "diversifiable", because it can be reduced by diversifying among stocks.

In the presence of per-asset investment fees, there is also the possibility of overdiversifying to the point that the portfolio's performance will suffer because the fees outweigh the gains from diversification.

The capital asset pricing model argues that investors should only be compensated for non-diversifiable risk. Other financial models allow for multiple sources of non-diversifiable risk, but also insist that diversifiable risk should not carry any extra expected return. Still other models do not accept this contention.[13]

An empirical example relating diversification to risk reduction edit

In 1977 Edwin Elton and Martin Gruber[14] worked out an empirical example of the gains from diversification. Their approach was to consider a population of 3,290 securities available for possible inclusion in a portfolio, and to consider the average risk over all possible randomly chosen n-asset portfolios with equal amounts held in each included asset, for various values of n. Their results are summarized in the following table.

The result for n=30 is close to n=1,000, and even four stocks provide most of the reduction in risk compared with one stock.

Number of Stocks in Portfolio Average Standard Deviation of Annual Portfolio Returns Ratio of Portfolio Standard Deviation to Standard Deviation of a Single Stock
1 49.24% 1.00
2 37.36 0.76
4 29.69 0.60
6 26.64 0.54
8 24.98 0.51
10 23.93 0.49
20 21.68 0.44
30 20.87 0.42
40 20.46 0.42
50 20.20 0.41
400 19.29 0.39
500 19.27 0.39
1,000 19.21 0.39

Corporate diversification strategies edit

In corporate portfolio models, diversification is thought of as being vertical or horizontal. Horizontal diversification is thought of as expanding a product line or acquiring related companies. Vertical diversification is synonymous with integrating the supply chain or amalgamating distributions channels.

Non-incremental diversification is a strategy followed by conglomerates, where the individual business lines have little to do with one another, yet the company is attaining diversification from exogenous risk factors to stabilize and provide opportunity for active management of diverse resources.

Fallacy of time diversification edit

The argument is often made that time reduces variance in a portfolio: a "time diversification". A common belief is younger investors should avoid bonds and emphasize stocks, due to the belief investors will have time to recover from any downturns. Yet this belief has flaws, as John Norstad explains:

This kind of statement makes the implicit assumption that given enough time good returns will cancel out any possible bad returns. While the basic argument that the standard deviations of the annualized returns decrease as the time horizon increases is true, it is also misleading, and it fatally misses the point, because for an investor concerned with the value of his portfolio at the end of a period of time, it is the total return that matters, not the annualized return. Because of the effects of compounding, the standard deviation of the total return actually increases with time horizon. Thus, if we use the traditional measure of uncertainty as the standard deviation of return over the time period in question, uncertainty increases with time.[15]

Three notable contributions to the literature on the fallacy of time diversification have been from Paul Samuelson,[16] Zvi Bodie,[17] and Mark Kritzman.[18]

History edit

Diversification is mentioned in the Bible, in the book of Ecclesiastes which was written in approximately 935 B.C.:[19]

But divide your investments among many places,
for you do not know what risks might lie ahead.[20]

Diversification is also mentioned in the Talmud. The formula given there is to split one's assets into thirds: one third in business (buying and selling things), one third kept liquid (e.g. gold coins), and one third in land (real estate). This strategy of splitting wealth equally among available options is now known as "naive diversification", "Talmudic diversification" or "1/n diversification", a concept which has earned renewed attention since the year 2000 due to research showing it may offer advantages in some scenarios.[21][22]

Diversification is mentioned in Shakespeare's Merchant of Venice (ca. 1599):[23]

My ventures are not in one bottom trusted,
Nor to one place; nor is my whole estate
Upon the fortune of this present year:
Therefore, my merchandise makes me not sad.

Modern understanding of diversification dates back to the influential work of economist Harry Markowitz in the 1950s,[24] whose work pioneered modern portfolio theory (see Markowitz model).

An earlier precedent for diversification was economist John Maynard Keynes, who managed the endowment of King's College, Cambridge from the 1920s to his 1946 death with a stock-selection strategy similar to what was later called value investing.[25] While diversification in the modern sense was "not easily available in Keynes's day"[26] and Keynes typically held a small number of assets compared to later investment theories, he nonetheless is recognized as a pioneer of financial diversification. Keynes came to recognize the importance, "if possible", he wrote, of holding assets with "opposed risks [...] since they are likely to move in opposite directions when there are general fluctuations"[27] Keynes was a pioneer of "international diversification" due to substantial holdings in non-U.K. stocks, up to 75%, and avoiding home bias at a time when university endowments in the U.S. and U.K. were invested almost entirely in domestic assets.[28]

See also edit

 
Asset Allocation on Wikibook

References edit

  1. ^ O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Pearson Prentice Hall. p. 273. ISBN 0-13-063085-3.
  2. ^ (in French) (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2010-05-08. Retrieved 2009-04-02.
  3. ^ (in English) "see Michael Prahl, "Asian Private Equity – Will it Deliver on its Promise?", INSEAD Global Private Equity Initiative (GPEI)" (PDF). Retrieved 2011-06-15.
  4. ^ Goetzmann, William N. An Introduction to Investment Theory 2017-03-31 at the Wayback Machine. II. Portfolios of Assets. Retrieved on November 20, 2008.
  5. ^ Investment Guide Beginners Introduction
  6. ^ James Lorie; Peter Dodd; Mary Kimpton (1985). The Stock Market: Theories and Evidence (2nd ed.). p. 85. ISBN 9780870946189.
  7. ^ How Many Stocks Make a Diversified Portfolio? The Journal of Finance and Quantitative Analysis
  8. ^ Asness, Cliff; David Kabiller and Michael Mendelson Using Derivatives and Leverage To Improve Portfolio Performance, Institutional Investor, May 13, 2010. Retrieved on June 21, 2010.
  9. ^ Schoen, Robert Parity Strategies and Maximum Diversification, Putnam Investments, June, 2013 2015-04-02 at the Wayback Machine.
  10. ^ Samuelson, Paul, "General Proof that Diversification Pays", Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 2, March 1967, 1-13.
  11. ^ Samuelson, Paul, "Risk and uncertainty: A fallacy of large numbers", Scientia 98, 1963, 108-113.
  12. ^ Ross, Stephen, "Adding risks: Samuelson's fallacy of large numbers revisited" Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 34, September 1999, 323-339.
  13. ^ .Fama, Eugene F.; Merton H. Miller (June 1972). The Theory of Finance. Holt Rinehart & Winston. ISBN 978-0-15-504266-7.
  14. ^ E. J. Elton and M. J. Gruber, "Risk Reduction and Portfolio Size: An Analytic Solution," Journal of Business 50 (October 1977), pp. 415–437
  15. ^ John Norstad (2012-12-22). . Archived from the original on 2017-09-11. Retrieved 2019-05-30.
  16. ^ Samuelson, Paul (1963). "Risk and Uncertainty: A Fallacy of Large Numbers". Scientia. 98 (4): 108–113.
  17. ^ Bodie, Zvi (May–June 1995). "On the Risk of Stocks in the Long Run". Financial Analysts Journal: 18–22.
  18. ^ Kritzman, Mark (October 2005). "A New Twist on Time Diversification". InvestmentNews.
  19. ^ Life Application Study Bible: New Living Translation. Wheaton, Illinois: Tyndale House Publishers, Inc. 1996. p. 1024. ISBN 0-8423-3267-7.
  20. ^ . Archived from the original on 2011-07-18. Retrieved 2010-01-09.
  21. ^ Ran Duchin, Haim Levy. Markowitz Versus the Talmudic Portfolio Diversification Strategies. The Journal of Portfolio Management Jan 2009, 35 (2) 71-74; DOI: 10.3905/JPM.2009.35.2.071
  22. ^ Prince C Nwakanma1, Monday Aberiate Gbanador. Talmud and Markowitz Diversification Strategies: Evidence from the Nigerian Stock Market. Accounting and Finance Research Vol. 3, No. 2; 2014
  23. ^ The Only Guide to a Winning Investment Strategy You'll Ever Need
  24. ^ Markowitz, Harry M. (1952). "Portfolio Selection". Journal of Finance. 7 (1): 77–91. doi:10.2307/2975974. JSTOR 2975974.
  25. ^ Chambers, David and Dimson, Elroy, John Maynard Keynes, Investment Innovator (June 30, 2013). Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2013, Vol 27, No 3, pages 1–18, Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2287262 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2287262
  26. ^ M. Lawlor (2016). The Economics of Keynes in Historical Context: An Intellectual History of the General Theory, Palgrave Macmillan UK, ISBN 9780230288775, p. 316
  27. ^ Kenneth L. Fisher (2007). 100 Minds That Made the Market. Wiley, ISBN 9780470139516
  28. ^ David Chambers, Elroy Dimson, Justin Foo (2015). Keynes, King's, and Endowment Asset Management, in How the Financial Crisis and Great Recession Affected Higher Education (2015), Jeffrey R. Brown and Caroline M. Hoxby, editors (p. 127–150). Conference held September 27–28, 2012.

External links edit

diversification, finance, finance, diversification, process, allocating, capital, that, reduces, exposure, particular, asset, risk, common, path, towards, diversification, reduce, risk, volatility, investing, variety, assets, asset, prices, change, perfect, sy. In finance diversification is the process of allocating capital in a way that reduces the exposure to any one particular asset or risk A common path towards diversification is to reduce risk or volatility by investing in a variety of assets If asset prices do not change in perfect synchrony a diversified portfolio will have less variance than the weighted average variance of its constituent assets and often less volatility than the least volatile of its constituents 1 Diversification is one of two general techniques for reducing investment risk The other is hedging Contents 1 Examples 2 Return expectations while diversifying 3 Amount of diversification 4 Effect of diversification on variance 5 Diversification with correlated returns via an equally weighted portfolio 6 Diversifiable and non diversifiable risk 7 An empirical example relating diversification to risk reduction 8 Corporate diversification strategies 9 Fallacy of time diversification 10 History 11 See also 12 References 13 External linksExamples editThe simplest example of diversification is provided by the proverb Don t put all your eggs in one basket Dropping the basket will break all the eggs Placing each egg in a different basket is more diversified There is more risk of losing one egg but less risk of losing all of them On the other hand having a lot of baskets may increase costs In finance an example of an undiversified portfolio is to hold only one stock This is risky it is not unusual for a single stock to go down 50 in one year It is less common for a portfolio of 20 stocks to go down that much especially if they are selected at random If the stocks are selected from a variety of industries company sizes and asset types it is even less likely to experience a 50 drop since it will mitigate any trends in that industry company class or asset type Since the mid 1970s it has also been argued that geographic diversification would generate superior risk adjusted returns for large institutional investors by reducing overall portfolio risk while capturing some of the higher rates of return offered by the emerging markets of Asia and Latin America 2 3 Return expectations while diversifying editIf the prior expectations of the returns on all assets in the portfolio are identical the expected return on a diversified portfolio will be identical to that on an undiversified portfolio Some assets will do better than others but since one does not know in advance which assets will perform better this fact cannot be exploited in advance The return on a diversified portfolio can never exceed that of the top performing investment and indeed will always be lower than the highest return unless all returns are identical Conversely the diversified portfolio s return will always be higher than that of the worst performing investment So by diversifying one loses the chance of having invested solely in the single asset that comes out best but one also avoids having invested solely in the asset that comes out worst That is the role of diversification it narrows the range of possible outcomes Diversification need not either help or hurt expected returns unless the alternative non diversified portfolio has a higher expected return 4 Amount of diversification editThere is no magic number of stocks that is diversified versus not Sometimes quoted is 30 although it can be as low as 10 provided they are carefully chosen This is based on a result from John Evans and Stephen Archer 5 Similarly a 1985 book reported that most value from diversification comes from the first 15 or 20 different stocks in a portfolio 6 More stocks give lower price volatility Given the advantages of diversification many experts who recommend maximum diversification also known as buying the market portfolio Identifying that portfolio is not straightforward The earliest definition comes from the capital asset pricing model which argues the maximum diversification comes from buying a pro rata share of all available assets This is the idea underlying index funds Diversification has no maximum so long as more assets are available 7 Every equally weighted uncorrelated asset added to a portfolio can add to that portfolio s measured diversification When assets are not uniformly uncorrelated a weighting approach that puts assets in proportion to their relative correlation can maximize the available diversification Risk parity is an alternative idea This weights assets in inverse proportion to risk so the portfolio has equal risk in all asset classes This is justified both on theoretical grounds and with the pragmatic argument that future risk is much easier to forecast than either future market price or future economic footprint 8 Correlation parity is an extension of risk parity and is the solution whereby each asset in a portfolio has an equal correlation with the portfolio and is therefore the most diversified portfolio Risk parity is the special case of correlation parity when all pair wise correlations are equal 9 Effect of diversification on variance editOne simple measure of financial risk is variance of the return on the portfolio Diversification can lower the variance of a portfolio s return below what it would be if the entire portfolio were invested in the asset with the lowest variance of return even if the assets returns are uncorrelated For example let asset X have stochastic return x displaystyle x nbsp and asset Y have stochastic return y displaystyle y nbsp with respective return variances s x 2 displaystyle sigma x 2 nbsp and s y 2 displaystyle sigma y 2 nbsp If the fraction q displaystyle q nbsp of a one unit e g one million dollar portfolio is placed in asset X and the fraction 1 q displaystyle 1 q nbsp is placed in Y the stochastic portfolio return is q x 1 q y displaystyle qx 1 q y nbsp If x displaystyle x nbsp and y displaystyle y nbsp are uncorrelated the variance of portfolio return is var q x 1 q y q 2 s x 2 1 q 2 s y 2 displaystyle text var qx 1 q y q 2 sigma x 2 1 q 2 sigma y 2 nbsp The variance minimizing value of q displaystyle q nbsp is q s y 2 s x 2 s y 2 displaystyle q sigma y 2 sigma x 2 sigma y 2 nbsp which is strictly between 0 displaystyle 0 nbsp and 1 displaystyle 1 nbsp Using this value of q displaystyle q nbsp in the expression for the variance of portfolio return gives the latter as s x 2 s y 2 s x 2 s y 2 displaystyle sigma x 2 sigma y 2 sigma x 2 sigma y 2 nbsp which is less than what it would be at either of the undiversified values q 1 displaystyle q 1 nbsp and q 0 displaystyle q 0 nbsp which respectively give portfolio return variance of s x 2 displaystyle sigma x 2 nbsp and s y 2 displaystyle sigma y 2 nbsp Note that the favorable effect of diversification on portfolio variance would be enhanced if x displaystyle x nbsp and y displaystyle y nbsp were negatively correlated but diminished though not eliminated if they were positively correlated In general the presence of more assets in a portfolio leads to greater diversification benefits as can be seen by considering portfolio variance as a function of n displaystyle n nbsp the number of assets For example if all assets returns are mutually uncorrelated and have identical variances s x 2 displaystyle sigma x 2 nbsp portfolio variance is minimized by holding all assets in the equal proportions 1 n displaystyle 1 n nbsp 10 Then the portfolio return s variance equals var 1 n x 1 1 n x 2 1 n x n displaystyle text var 1 n x 1 1 n x 2 1 n x n nbsp n 1 n 2 s x 2 displaystyle n 1 n 2 sigma x 2 nbsp s x 2 n displaystyle sigma x 2 n nbsp which is monotonically decreasing in n displaystyle n nbsp The latter analysis can be adapted to show why adding uncorrelated volatile assets to a portfolio 11 12 thereby increasing the portfolio s size is not diversification which involves subdividing the portfolio among many smaller investments In the case of adding investments the portfolio s return is x 1 x 2 x n displaystyle x 1 x 2 dots x n nbsp instead of 1 n x 1 1 n x 2 1 n x n displaystyle 1 n x 1 1 n x 2 1 n x n nbsp and the variance of the portfolio return if the assets are uncorrelated is var x 1 x 2 x n s x 2 s x 2 s x 2 n s x 2 displaystyle text var x 1 x 2 dots x n sigma x 2 sigma x 2 dots sigma x 2 n sigma x 2 nbsp which is increasing in n rather than decreasing Thus for example when an insurance company adds more and more uncorrelated policies to its portfolio this expansion does not itself represent diversification the diversification occurs in the spreading of the insurance company s risks over a large number of part owners of the company Diversification with correlated returns via an equally weighted portfolio editThe expected return on a portfolio is a weighted average of the expected returns on each individual asset E R P i 1 n x i E R i displaystyle mathbb E R P sum i 1 n x i mathbb E R i nbsp where x i displaystyle x i nbsp is the proportion of the investor s total invested wealth in asset i displaystyle i nbsp The variance of the portfolio return is given by Var R P s P 2 E R P E R P 2 displaystyle underbrace text Var R P equiv sigma P 2 mathbb E R P mathbb E R P 2 nbsp Inserting in the expression for E R P displaystyle mathbb E R P nbsp s P 2 E i 1 n x i R i i 1 n x i E R i 2 displaystyle sigma P 2 mathbb E left sum i 1 n x i R i sum i 1 n x i mathbb E R i right 2 nbsp Rearranging s P 2 E i 1 n x i R i E R i 2 displaystyle sigma P 2 mathbb E left sum i 1 n x i R i mathbb E R i right 2 nbsp s P 2 E i 1 n j 1 n x i x j R i E R i R j E R j displaystyle sigma P 2 mathbb E left sum i 1 n sum j 1 n x i x j R i mathbb E R i R j mathbb E R j right nbsp s P 2 E i 1 n x i 2 R i E R i 2 i 1 n j 1 i j n x i x j R i E R i R j E R j displaystyle sigma P 2 mathbb E left sum i 1 n x i 2 R i mathbb E R i 2 sum i 1 n sum j 1 i neq j n x i x j R i mathbb E R i R j mathbb E R j right nbsp s P 2 i 1 n x i 2 E R i E R i 2 s i 2 i 1 n j 1 i j n x i x j E R i E R i R j E R j s i j displaystyle sigma P 2 sum i 1 n x i 2 underbrace mathbb E left R i mathbb E R i right 2 equiv sigma i 2 sum i 1 n sum j 1 i neq j n x i x j underbrace mathbb E left R i mathbb E R i R j mathbb E R j right equiv sigma ij nbsp s P 2 i 1 n x i 2 s i 2 i 1 n j 1 i j n x i x j s i j displaystyle sigma P 2 sum i 1 n x i 2 sigma i 2 sum i 1 n sum j 1 i neq j n x i x j sigma ij nbsp where s i 2 displaystyle sigma i 2 nbsp is the variance on asset i displaystyle i nbsp and s i j displaystyle sigma ij nbsp is the covariance between assets i displaystyle i nbsp and j displaystyle j nbsp In an equally weighted portfolio x i x j 1 n i j displaystyle x i x j frac 1 n forall i j nbsp The portfolio variance then becomes s P 2 1 n 2 n s i 2 n n 1 1 n 1 n s i j displaystyle sigma P 2 frac 1 n 2 n bar sigma i 2 n n 1 frac 1 n frac 1 n bar sigma ij nbsp where s i j displaystyle bar sigma ij nbsp is the average of the covariances s i j displaystyle sigma ij nbsp for i j displaystyle i neq j nbsp and s i 2 displaystyle bar sigma i 2 nbsp is the average of the variances Simplifying we obtain s P 2 1 n s i 2 n 1 n s i j displaystyle sigma P 2 frac 1 n bar sigma i 2 frac n 1 n bar sigma ij nbsp As the number of assets grows we get the asymptotic formula lim n s P 2 s i j displaystyle lim n rightarrow infty sigma P 2 bar sigma ij nbsp Thus in an equally weighted portfolio the portfolio variance tends to the average of covariances between securities as the number of securities becomes arbitrarily large Diversifiable and non diversifiable risk editThe capital asset pricing model introduced the concepts of diversifiable and non diversifiable risk Synonyms for diversifiable risk are idiosyncratic risk unsystematic risk and security specific risk Synonyms for non diversifiable risk are systematic risk beta risk and market risk If one buys all the stocks in the S amp P 500 one is obviously exposed only to movements in that index If one buys a single stock in the S amp P 500 one is exposed both to index movements and movements in the stock based on its underlying company The first risk is called non diversifiable because it exists however many S amp P 500 stocks are bought The second risk is called diversifiable because it can be reduced by diversifying among stocks In the presence of per asset investment fees there is also the possibility of overdiversifying to the point that the portfolio s performance will suffer because the fees outweigh the gains from diversification The capital asset pricing model argues that investors should only be compensated for non diversifiable risk Other financial models allow for multiple sources of non diversifiable risk but also insist that diversifiable risk should not carry any extra expected return Still other models do not accept this contention 13 An empirical example relating diversification to risk reduction editIn 1977 Edwin Elton and Martin Gruber 14 worked out an empirical example of the gains from diversification Their approach was to consider a population of 3 290 securities available for possible inclusion in a portfolio and to consider the average risk over all possible randomly chosen n asset portfolios with equal amounts held in each included asset for various values of n Their results are summarized in the following table The result for n 30 is close to n 1 000 and even four stocks provide most of the reduction in risk compared with one stock Number of Stocks in Portfolio Average Standard Deviation of Annual Portfolio Returns Ratio of Portfolio Standard Deviation to Standard Deviation of a Single Stock 1 49 24 1 00 2 37 36 0 76 4 29 69 0 60 6 26 64 0 54 8 24 98 0 51 10 23 93 0 49 20 21 68 0 44 30 20 87 0 42 40 20 46 0 42 50 20 20 0 41 400 19 29 0 39 500 19 27 0 39 1 000 19 21 0 39Corporate diversification strategies editIn corporate portfolio models diversification is thought of as being vertical or horizontal Horizontal diversification is thought of as expanding a product line or acquiring related companies Vertical diversification is synonymous with integrating the supply chain or amalgamating distributions channels Non incremental diversification is a strategy followed by conglomerates where the individual business lines have little to do with one another yet the company is attaining diversification from exogenous risk factors to stabilize and provide opportunity for active management of diverse resources Fallacy of time diversification editThe argument is often made that time reduces variance in a portfolio a time diversification A common belief is younger investors should avoid bonds and emphasize stocks due to the belief investors will have time to recover from any downturns Yet this belief has flaws as John Norstad explains This kind of statement makes the implicit assumption that given enough time good returns will cancel out any possible bad returns While the basic argument that the standard deviations of the annualized returns decrease as the time horizon increases is true it is also misleading and it fatally misses the point because for an investor concerned with the value of his portfolio at the end of a period of time it is the total return that matters not the annualized return Because of the effects of compounding the standard deviation of the total return actually increases with time horizon Thus if we use the traditional measure of uncertainty as the standard deviation of return over the time period in question uncertainty increases with time 15 Three notable contributions to the literature on the fallacy of time diversification have been from Paul Samuelson 16 Zvi Bodie 17 and Mark Kritzman 18 History editDiversification is mentioned in the Bible in the book of Ecclesiastes which was written in approximately 935 B C 19 But divide your investments among many places for you do not know what risks might lie ahead 20 Diversification is also mentioned in the Talmud The formula given there is to split one s assets into thirds one third in business buying and selling things one third kept liquid e g gold coins and one third in land real estate This strategy of splitting wealth equally among available options is now known as naive diversification Talmudic diversification or 1 n diversification a concept which has earned renewed attention since the year 2000 due to research showing it may offer advantages in some scenarios 21 22 Diversification is mentioned in Shakespeare s Merchant of Venice ca 1599 23 My ventures are not in one bottom trusted Nor to one place nor is my whole estate Upon the fortune of this present year Therefore my merchandise makes me not sad Modern understanding of diversification dates back to the influential work of economist Harry Markowitz in the 1950s 24 whose work pioneered modern portfolio theory see Markowitz model An earlier precedent for diversification was economist John Maynard Keynes who managed the endowment of King s College Cambridge from the 1920s to his 1946 death with a stock selection strategy similar to what was later called value investing 25 While diversification in the modern sense was not easily available in Keynes s day 26 and Keynes typically held a small number of assets compared to later investment theories he nonetheless is recognized as a pioneer of financial diversification Keynes came to recognize the importance if possible he wrote of holding assets with opposed risks since they are likely to move in opposite directions when there are general fluctuations 27 Keynes was a pioneer of international diversification due to substantial holdings in non U K stocks up to 75 and avoiding home bias at a time when university endowments in the U S and U K were invested almost entirely in domestic assets 28 See also edit nbsp Asset Allocation on Wikibook Central limit theorem Coherent risk measure Dollar cost averaging Equity repositioning Financial correlation Outline of finance Modern portfolio theory Systematic riskReferences edit O Sullivan Arthur Sheffrin Steven M 2003 Economics Principles in Action Upper Saddle River New Jersey Pearson Prentice Hall p 273 ISBN 0 13 063085 3 in French see M Nicolas J Firzli Asia Pacific Funds as Diversification Tools for Institutional Investors Revue Analyse Financiere The French Society of Financial Analysts SFAF PDF Archived from the original PDF on 2010 05 08 Retrieved 2009 04 02 in English see Michael Prahl Asian Private Equity Will it Deliver on its Promise INSEAD Global Private Equity Initiative GPEI PDF Retrieved 2011 06 15 Goetzmann William N An Introduction to Investment Theory Archived 2017 03 31 at the Wayback Machine II Portfolios of Assets Retrieved on November 20 2008 Investment Guide Beginners Introduction James Lorie Peter Dodd Mary Kimpton 1985 The Stock Market Theories and Evidence 2nd ed p 85 ISBN 9780870946189 How Many Stocks Make a Diversified Portfolio The Journal of Finance and Quantitative Analysis Asness Cliff David Kabiller and Michael Mendelson Using Derivatives and Leverage To Improve Portfolio Performance Institutional Investor May 13 2010 Retrieved on June 21 2010 Schoen Robert Parity Strategies and Maximum Diversification Putnam Investments June 2013 Archived 2015 04 02 at the Wayback Machine Samuelson Paul General Proof that Diversification Pays Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 2 March 1967 1 13 Samuelson Paul Risk and uncertainty A fallacy of large numbers Scientia 98 1963 108 113 Ross Stephen Adding risks Samuelson s fallacy of large numbers revisited Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 34 September 1999 323 339 Fama Eugene F Merton H Miller June 1972 The Theory of Finance Holt Rinehart amp Winston ISBN 978 0 15 504266 7 E J Elton and M J Gruber Risk Reduction and Portfolio Size An Analytic Solution Journal of Business 50 October 1977 pp 415 437 John Norstad 2012 12 22 Risk and Time Archived from the original on 2017 09 11 Retrieved 2019 05 30 Samuelson Paul 1963 Risk and Uncertainty A Fallacy of Large Numbers Scientia 98 4 108 113 Bodie Zvi May June 1995 On the Risk of Stocks in the Long Run Financial Analysts Journal 18 22 Kritzman Mark October 2005 A New Twist on Time Diversification InvestmentNews Life Application Study Bible New Living Translation Wheaton Illinois Tyndale House Publishers Inc 1996 p 1024 ISBN 0 8423 3267 7 Ecclesiastes 11 2 NLT Archived from the original on 2011 07 18 Retrieved 2010 01 09 Ran Duchin Haim Levy Markowitz Versus the Talmudic Portfolio Diversification Strategies The Journal of Portfolio Management Jan 2009 35 2 71 74 DOI 10 3905 JPM 2009 35 2 071 Prince C Nwakanma1 Monday Aberiate Gbanador Talmud and Markowitz Diversification Strategies Evidence from the Nigerian Stock Market Accounting and Finance Research Vol 3 No 2 2014 The Only Guide to a Winning Investment Strategy You ll Ever Need Markowitz Harry M 1952 Portfolio Selection Journal of Finance 7 1 77 91 doi 10 2307 2975974 JSTOR 2975974 Chambers David and Dimson Elroy John Maynard Keynes Investment Innovator June 30 2013 Journal of Economic Perspectives 2013 Vol 27 No 3 pages 1 18 Available at SSRN https ssrn com abstract 2287262 or http dx doi org 10 2139 ssrn 2287262 M Lawlor 2016 The Economics of Keynes in Historical Context An Intellectual History of the General Theory Palgrave Macmillan UK ISBN 9780230288775 p 316 Kenneth L Fisher 2007 100 Minds That Made the Market Wiley ISBN 9780470139516 David Chambers Elroy Dimson Justin Foo 2015 Keynes King s and Endowment Asset Management in How the Financial Crisis and Great Recession Affected Higher Education 2015 Jeffrey R Brown and Caroline M Hoxby editors p 127 150 Conference held September 27 28 2012 External links editMacro Investment Analysis Prof William F Sharpe Stanford University An Introduction to Investment Theory Prof William N Goetzmann Yale School of Management Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Diversification finance amp oldid 1222058867, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.