fbpx
Wikipedia

Sharecropping

Sharecropping is a legal arrangement with regard to agricultural land in which a landowner allows a tenant to use the land in return for a share of the crops produced on that land.

Sharecropping has a long history and there are a wide range of different situations and types of agreements that have used a form of the system. Some are governed by tradition, and others by law. The French métayage, the Catalan masoveria, the Castilian mediero, the Slavic połownictwo and izdolshchina, the Italian mezzadria, and the Islamic system of muzara‘a (المزارعة), are examples of legal systems that have supported sharecropping.

Overview edit

 
A Farm Security Administration photo of a cropper family chopping the weeds from cotton near White Plains, in Georgia, US (1941)

Sharecropping has benefits and costs for both the owners and the tenant. Under a sharecropping system, the landowner provided a share of land to be worked by the sharecropper, and usually provided other necessities such as housing, tools, seed, or working animals.[1] Local merchants usually provided food and other supplies to the sharecropper on credit. In exchange for the land and supplies, the cropper would pay the owner a share of the crop at the end of the season, typically one-half to two-thirds. The cropper used his share to pay off his debt to the merchant.[2] If there was any cash left over, the cropper kept it—but if his share came to less than what he owed, he remained in debt.

Farmers who farmed land belonging to others but owned their own mule and plow were called tenant farmers; they owed the landowner a smaller share of their crops, as the landowner did not have to provide them with as much in the way of supplies.

In this system, the landowner encourages the cropper to remain on the land, solving the harvest rush problem.[clarification needed] Since the cropper pays in shares or portions of his harvest, owners and croppers both share the risks and benefits of harvests being large or small and of prices being high or low. Because both parties benefit from larger harvests, tenants have an incentive to work harder and invest in better methods than, for example, in a slave plantation system. However, by dividing the working force into many individual workers, large farms do not benefit from economies of scale.[citation needed] Though the arrangement protected sharecroppers from the negative effects of a bad crop, many sharecroppers (both white and black) remained quite poor.

Advantages edit

 
The commissary or company store for sharecroppers at Lake Providence, Louisiana, as it appeared in the 19th century

Sociologist Jeffery M. Paige made a distinction between centralized sharecropping found on cotton plantations and the decentralized sharecropping with other crops. The former is characterized by long lasting tenure. Tenants are tied to the landlord through the plantation store. This form of tenure tends to be replaced by paid salaries as markets penetrate. Decentralized sharecropping involves virtually no role for the landlord: plots are scattered, peasants manage their own labor and the landowners do not manufacture the crops. This form of tenure becomes more common when markets penetrate.[3]

Some economists have argued that sharecropping is not as exploitative as it is often perceived. John Heath and Hans P. Binswanger, contend that "evidence from around the world suggests that sharecropping is often a way for differently endowed enterprises to pool resources to mutual benefit, overcoming credit restraints and helping to manage risk."[4]

Sharecropping agreements can be made fairly, as a form of tenant farming or sharefarming that has a variable rental payment, paid in arrears. There are three different types of contracts.[5]

  1. Workers can rent plots of land from the owner for a certain sum and keep the whole crop.
  2. Workers work on the land and earn a fixed wage from the land owner but keep some of the crop.
  3. No money changes hands but the worker and land owner each keep a share of the crop.

It also gave sharecroppers a vested interest in the land, incentivizing hard work and care. American plantations were, however, wary of this interest, as they felt that would lead to African Americans demanding rights of partnership. Many black laborers denied the unilateral authority that landowners hoped to achieve, further complicating relations between landowners and sharecroppers.[6]

Landlords opt for sharecropping to avoid the administrative costs and shirking that occurs on plantations and haciendas. It is preferred to cash tenancy because cash tenants take all the risks, and any harvest failure will hurt them and not the landlord. Therefore, they tend to demand lower rents than sharecroppers.[7]

Another possible benefit to sharecropping is that it enables women to have access to arable land, albeit not as owners, in places where ownership rights are vested only in men.[8]

Disadvantages edit

The practice was harmful to tenants with many cases of high interest rates, unpredictable harvests, and unscrupulous landlords and merchants often keeping tenant farm families severely indebted. The debt was often compounded year on year leaving the cropper vulnerable to intimidation and shortchanging.[9] Nevertheless, it appeared to be inevitable, with no serious alternative unless the croppers left agriculture.[10][11]

A new system of credit, the crop lien, became closely associated with sharecropping. Under this system, a planter or merchant extended a line of credit to the sharecropper while taking the year's crop as collateral. The sharecropper could then draw food and supplies all year long. When the crop was harvested, the planter or merchants who held the lien sold the harvest for the sharecropper and settled the debt.

Sharecropping has more than a passing similarity to serfdom or indenture, particularly where associated with large debts at a plantation store that effectively ties down the workers and their family to the land. It has therefore been seen as an issue of land reform in contexts such as the Mexican Revolution.

Regions edit

Historically, sharecropping occurred extensively in Scotland, Ireland and colonial Africa. Use of the sharecropper system has also been identified in England (as the practice of "farming to halves").[12] It was widely used in the Southern United States during the Reconstruction era (1865–1877) that followed the American Civil War, which was economically devastating to the southern states.[13] It is still used in many rural poor areas of the world today, notably in Pakistan, India, and Bangladesh.[14][15][16]

Africa edit

In settler colonies of colonial Africa, sharecropping was a feature of the agricultural life. White farmers, who owned most of the land, were frequently unable to work the whole of their farm for lack of capital. They, therefore, had African farmers to work the excess on a sharecropping basis. In South Africa the 1913 Natives' Land Act[17] outlawed the ownership of land by Africans in areas designated for white ownership and effectively reduced the status of most sharecroppers to tenant farmers and then to farm laborers. In the 1960s, generous subsidies to white farmers meant that most farmers could afford to work their entire farms, and sharecropping faded out.

The arrangement has reappeared in other African countries in modern times, including Ghana[18] and Zimbabwe.[19]

Economic historian Pius S. Nyambara argued that Eurocentric historiographical devices such as 'feudalism' or 'slavery' often qualified by weak prefixes like 'semi-' or 'quasi-' are not helpful in understanding the antecedents and functions of sharecropping in Africa.[19]

United States edit

 
Sharecroppers on the roadside after they were evicted for membership in the Southern Tenant Farmers Union (January 1936)

Prior to the Civil War, sharecropping is known to have existed in Mississippi and is believed to have been in place in Tennessee.[20][21] However, it was not until the economic upheaval caused by the American Civil War and the end of slavery during and after Reconstruction that it became widespread in the South.[22][13] It is theorized that sharecropping in the United States originated in the Natchez District, roughly centered in Adams County, Mississippi with its county seat, Natchez.[23]

After the war, plantations and other lands throughout the South were seized by the federal government. In January 1865, General William T. Sherman issued Special Field Orders No. 15, which announced that he would temporarily grant newly freed families 40 acres of this seized land on the islands and coastal regions of Georgia. Many believed that this policy would be extended to all former slaves and their families as repayment for their treatment at the end of the war. In the summer of 1865, President Andrew Johnson, as one of the first acts of Reconstruction, instead ordered all land under federal control be returned to the owners from whom it had been seized.

 
An early 20th century Texas sharecropper's home diorama at the Audie Murphy American Cotton Museum, in Greenville, Texas 2015

Southern landowners thus found themselves with a great deal of land, but no liquid assets to pay for labor. Many former slaves, now called freedmen, having no land or other assets of their own, needed to work to support their families. A sharecropping system centered on cotton, a major cash crop, developed as a result. Large plantations were subdivided into plots that could be worked by sharecroppers. Initially, sharecroppers in the American South were almost all black former slaves, but eventually cash-strapped indigent white farmers were integrated into the system.[2][24] During Reconstruction, the federal Freedmen's Bureau ordered the arrangements for freedmen and wrote and enforced their contracts.[25]

American sharecroppers worked a section of the plantation independently, usually growing cotton, tobacco, rice, sugar, and other cash crops, and received half of the parcel's output.[26][27] Sharecroppers also often received their farming tools and all other goods from the landowner they were contracted with.[1] Landowners dictated decisions relating to the crop mix, and sharecroppers were often in agreements to sell their portion of the crop back to the landowner, thus being subjected to manipulated prices.[6] In addition to this, landowners, threatening to not renew the lease at the end of the growing season, were able to apply pressure to their tenants.[6] Sharecropping often proved economically problematic, as the landowners held significant economic control.[28]

 
Cotton sharecroppers, Hale County, Alabama, 1936

In the Reconstruction Era, sharecropping was one of few options for penniless freedmen to support themselves and their families. Other solutions included the crop-lien system (where the farmer was extended credit for seed and other supplies by the merchant), a rent labor system (where the former slave rents his land but keeps his entire crop), and the wage system (worker earns a fixed wage, but keeps none of their crop). Sharecropping was by far the most economically efficient, as it provided incentives for workers to produce a bigger harvest. It was a stage beyond simple hired labor because the sharecropper had an annual contract.[25] Sharecropping as historically practiced in the American South is considered more economically productive than the gang system of slave plantations, though less efficient than modern agricultural techniques.[29]

 
Sharecropper's cabin displayed at Louisiana State Cotton Museum in Lake Providence, Louisiana (2013 photo)

Sharecropping continued to be a significant institution in many states for decades following the Civil War. By the early 1930s, there were 5.5 million white tenant farmers, sharecroppers, and mixed cropping/laborers in the United States; and 3 million Blacks.[30][31] In Tennessee, sharecroppers operated approximately one-third of all farm units in the state in the 1930s, with white people making up two thirds or more of the sharecroppers.[21] In Mississippi, by 1900, 36% of all white farmers were tenants or sharecroppers, while 85% of black farmers were.[20] In Georgia, fewer than 16,000 farms were operated by black owners in 1910, while, at the same time, African-Americans managed 106,738 farms as tenants.[32]

Around this time, sharecroppers began to form unions protesting against poor treatment, beginning in Tallapoosa County, Alabama in 1931, and Arkansas in 1934. Membership in the Southern Tenant Farmers Union included both blacks and poor whites, who used meetings, protests, and labor strikes to push for better treatment. The success of these actions frightened and enraged landlords, who responded with aggressive tactics.[33] Landless farmers who fought the sharecropping system were socially denounced, harassed by legal and illegal means, and physically attacked by officials, landlords' agents, or in extreme cases, angry mobs.[34] Sharecroppers' strikes in Arkansas and the Missouri Bootheel, the 1939 Missouri Sharecroppers' Strike, were documented in the newsreel Oh Freedom After While.[35] The plight of a sharecropper was addressed in the song Sharecropper's Blues recorded by Charlie Barnet and His Orchestra in 1944.[36]

 
Sharecroppers' chapel at Cotton Museum in Lake Providence

The sharecropping system in the U.S. increased during the Great Depression with the creation of tenant farmers following the failure of many small farms throughout the Dustbowl. Traditional sharecropping declined after mechanization of farm work became economical beginning in the late 1930s and early 1940s.[21][37] As a result, many sharecroppers were forced off the farms, and migrated to cities to work in factories, or became migrant workers in the Western United States during World War II. By the end of the 1960s, sharecropping had disappeared in the United States.[citation needed]

Sharecropping and socioeconomic status edit

About two-thirds of sharecroppers were white, the rest black. Sharecroppers, the poorest of the poor, organized for better conditions. The racially integrated Southern Tenant Farmers Union made gains for sharecroppers in the 1930s. Sharecropping had diminished in the 1940s due to the Great Depression, farm mechanization, and other factors.[38]

Economic theories of share tenancy edit

 
A sharecropper family in Walker County, Alabama (c. 1937)

The theory of share tenancy was long dominated by Alfred Marshall's famous footnote in Book VI, Chapter X.14 of Principles[39] where he illustrated the inefficiency of agricultural share-contracting. Steven N.S. Cheung (1969),[40] challenged this view, showing that with sufficient competition and in the absence of transaction costs, share tenancy will be equivalent to competitive labor markets and therefore efficient.[41]

He also showed that in the presence of transaction costs, share-contracting may be preferred to either wage contracts or rent contracts—due to the mitigation of labor shirking and the provision of risk sharing. Joseph Stiglitz (1974,[42] 1988),[43] suggested that if share tenancy is only a labor contract, then it is only pairwise-efficient and that land-to-the-tiller reform would improve social efficiency by removing the necessity for labor contracts in the first place.

Reid (1973),[44] Murrel (1983),[45] Roumasset (1995)[46] and Allen and Lueck (2004)[47] provided transaction cost theories of share-contracting, wherein tenancy is more of a partnership than a labor contract and both landlord and tenant provide multiple inputs. It has also been argued that the sharecropping institution can be explained by factors such as informational asymmetry (Hallagan, 1978;[48] Allen, 1982;[49] Muthoo, 1998),[50] moral hazard (Reid, 1976;[51] Eswaran and Kotwal, 1985;[52] Ghatak and Pandey, 2000),[53] intertemporal discounting (Roy and Serfes, 2001),[54] price fluctuations (Sen, 2011)[55] or limited liability (Shetty, 1988;[56] Basu, 1992;[57] Sengupta, 1997;[58] Ray and Singh, 2001).[59]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b Mandle, Jay R. Not Slave, Not Free: The African American Economic Experience Since the Civil War. Duke University Press, 1992, 22.
  2. ^ a b Ronald L. F. Davis "The U. S. Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District—A Case Study" The Journal of Negro History, Vol. 62, No.1 (January 1977), pp. 60–80 in JSTOR
  3. ^ Jeffery Paige, Agrarian Revolution, page 373
  4. ^ Heath, John & Binswanger, Hans P. (October 1998). "Chapter 3: Policy-Induced Effects of Natural Resource Degradation: The Case of Colombia" (PDF). In Lutz, Ernest (ed.). Agriculture and the Environment: Perspectives on Sustainable Rural Development. Washington, DC: The World Bank. pp. 32. ISBN 0-8213-4249-5. Retrieved 2011-04-01.
  5. ^ Arthur F. Raper and Ira De A. Reid, Sharecroppers All (1941); Gavin Wright, Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy since the Civil War (1986).
  6. ^ a b c Royce, Edward (1993). "The Rise of Southern Sharecropping". In Royce, Edward (ed.). The Origins of Southern Sharecropping. Temple University Press. pp. 181–222. ISBN 9781566390699. JSTOR j.ctt14bt3nz.9.
  7. ^ Sharecropping and Sharecroppers, T J Byres
  8. ^ Bruce, John W.- Country Profiles of Land Tenure: Africa, 1996 (Lesotho, p. 221) Research Paper No. 130, December 1998, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin-Madison accessed at UMN.edu 2001-11-25 at the Wayback Machine June 19, 2006
  9. ^ "Sharecropping | Slavery By Another Name Bento | PBS". Sharecropping | Slavery By Another Name Bento | PBS.
  10. ^ Rufus B. Spain (1967). At Ease in Zion: Social History of Southern Baptists, 1865-1900. University of Alabama Press. p. 130. ISBN 9780817350383.
  11. ^ Johnny E. Williams (2008). African American Religion and the Civil Rights Movement in Arkansas. Univ. Press of Mississippi. p. 73. ISBN 9781604731866.
  12. ^ Griffiths, Liz Farming to Halves: A New Perspective on an Absurd and Miserable System in Rural History Today, Issue 6:2004 p.5, accessed at British Agricultural History Society, 16 February 2013.
  13. ^ a b Joseph D. Reid, "Sharecropping as an understandable market response: The postbellum South." Journal of Economic History (1973) 33#1 pp. 106–130. in JSTOR
  14. ^ Sanval, Nasim; Steven, Helfand (2016-01-15). Optimal groundwater management in Pakistan's Indus Water Basin. Intl Food Policy Res Inst.
  15. ^ Chaudhuri, Ananish; Maitra, Pushkar (2000-01-01). "Sharecropping contracts in rural India: A note". Journal of Contemporary Asia. 30 (1): 99–107. doi:10.1080/00472330080000071. ISSN 0047-2336. S2CID 154416728.
  16. ^ Byres, T. J. (2005-08-02). Sharecropping and Sharecroppers. Routledge. ISBN 978-1-135-78003-6.
  17. ^ . Sahistory.org.za. Archived from the original on 14 October 2010. Retrieved 22 October 2023.
  18. ^ Leonard, R. and Longbottom, J., Land Tenure Lexicon: A glossary of terms from English and French speaking West Africa[permanent dead link] International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), London, 2000
  19. ^ a b Pius S. Nyambara (2003). (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2006-03-26. Retrieved 2006-05-18., Centre for Applied Social Sciences, University of Zimbabwe and Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin–Madison, March 2003 (200Kb PDF)
  20. ^ a b Charles Bolton, "Farmers Without Land: The Plight of White Tenant Farmers and Sharecroppers 2016-03-04 at the Wayback Machine", Mississippi History Now, March 2004.
  21. ^ a b c Robert Tracy McKenzie, "Sharecropping", Tennessee Encyclopedia of History and Culture.
  22. ^ Sharon Monteith, ed. (2013). The Cambridge Companion to the Literature of the American South. Cambridge U.P. p. 94. ISBN 9781107036789.
  23. ^ Ronald L. F. Davis "The U. S. Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District—A Case Study" The Journal of Negro History, Vol. 62, No.1 (January, 1977), pp. 60–80 in JSTOR
  24. ^ Eva O'Donovan, Becoming Free in the Cotton South (2007); Gavin Wright, Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy Since the Civil War (1986); Roger L. Ransom and David Beckham, One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation (2nd ed. 2008)
  25. ^ a b Gregorie, Anne King (1954). History of Sumter County, South Carolina, p. 274. Library Board of Sumter County.
  26. ^ Woodman, Harold D. (1995). New South – New Law: The legal foundations of credit and labor relations in the Postbellum agricultural South. Louisiana State University Press. ISBN 0-8071-1941-5.
  27. ^ F. N. Boney (2004-02-06). . The New Georgia Encyclopedia. Archived from the original on 2012-08-29. Retrieved 2006-05-18.
  28. ^ Ransom, Roger L., and Richard Sutch. One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation. 2nd edition. Cambridge England ; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001, 149.
  29. ^ Larry J. Griffin; Don Harrison Doyle (1995). The South As an American Problem. U. of Georgia Press. p. 168. ISBN 9780820317526.
  30. ^ The Rockabilly Legends; They Called It Rockabilly Long Before they Called It Rock and Roll by Jerry Naylor and Steve Halliday DVD
  31. ^ The Devil's Music: A History of the Blues By Giles Oakley Edition: 2. Da Capo Press, 1997, p. 184. ISBN 0-306-80743-2, ISBN 978-0-306-80743-5
  32. ^ Geisen, James C. (January 26, 2007). "Sharecropping". New Georgia Encyclopedia. Retrieved April 23, 2019.
  33. ^ The Devil's Music: A History of the Blues By Giles Oakley Edition: 2. Da Capo Press, 1997, p. 185. ISBN 0-306-80743-2, ISBN 978-0-306-80743-5
  34. ^ Sharecroppers All. Arthur F. Raper and Ira De A. Reid. Chapell Hill 1941. The University of North Carolina Press, 2011, ISBN 978-0-8078-9817-8
  35. ^ "California Newsreel - Film and Video for Social Change Since 1968". Newsreel.org. Retrieved 22 October 2023.
  36. ^ Charlie Barnet - Sharecropper's Blues. YouTube. 26 August 2011. Archived from the original on 2021-11-09.
  37. ^ Gordon Marshall, "Sharecropping," Encyclopedia.com, 1998.
  38. ^ "Sharecropping". Slavery by Another Name. PBS. Retrieved 7 December 2021.
  39. ^ Alfred Marshall (1920). Principles of Economics (8th ed.). London: Macmillan and Co., Ltd.
  40. ^ Cheung, Steven N S (1969). "Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements". Journal of Law & Economics. 12 (1): 23–42. doi:10.1086/466658. S2CID 154860968. Retrieved 2009-06-14.
  41. ^ Formalized in Roumasset, James (1979). "Sharecropping, Production Externalities and the Theory of Contracts". American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 61 (4): 640–647. doi:10.2307/1239911. JSTOR 1239911.
  42. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph (1974). "Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping" (PDF). The Review of Economic Studies. 41 (2): 219–255 j. doi:10.2307/2296714. JSTOR 2296714.
  43. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph (1988). "Principal And Agent". Princeton, Woodrow Wilson School – Discussion Paper (12). Retrieved 2009-06-14.
  44. ^ Reid, Joseph D. Jr. (March 1973). "Sharecropping As An Understandable Market Response: The Post-Bellum South". The Journal of Economic History. 33 (1): 106–130. doi:10.1017/S0022050700076476. JSTOR 2117145. S2CID 155056632.
  45. ^ Murrell, Peter (Spring 1983). "The Economics of Sharing: A Transactions Cost Analysis of Contractual Choice in Farming". The Bell Journal of Economics. 14 (1): 283–293. doi:10.2307/3003555. JSTOR 3003555.
  46. ^ Roumasset, James (March 1995). "The nature of the agricultural firm". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 26 (2): 161–177. doi:10.1016/0167-2681(94)00007-2.
  47. ^ Allen, Douglas W.; Dean Lueck (2004). The Nature of the Farm: Contracts, Risk, and Organization in Agriculture. MIT Press. p. 258. ISBN 9780262511858.
  48. ^ Hallagan, William (1978). "Self-selection by contractual choice and the theory of sharecropping". Bell Journal of Economics. 9 (2): 344–354. doi:10.2307/3003586. JSTOR 3003586.
  49. ^ Allen, Franklin (1982). "On share contracts and screening". Bell Journal of Economics. 13 (2): 541–547. doi:10.2307/3003473. JSTOR 3003473.
  50. ^ Muthoo, Abhinay (1998). "Renegotiation-proof tenurial contracts as screening mechanisms". Journal of Development Economics. 56: 1–26. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(98)00050-9.
  51. ^ Reid, Joseph D. Jr. (1976). "Sharecropping and agricultural uncertainty". Economic Development and Cultural Change. 24 (3): 549–576. doi:10.1086/450897. JSTOR 1153005. S2CID 154402121.
  52. ^ Eswaran, Mukesh; Ashok Kotwal (1985). "A theory of contractual structure in agriculture". American Economic Review. 75 (3): 352–367. JSTOR 1814805.
  53. ^ Ghatak, Maitreesh; Priyanka Pandey (2000). "Contract choice in agriculture with joint moral hazard in effort and risk". Journal of Development Economics. 63 (2): 303–326. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(00)00116-4.
  54. ^ Roy, Jaideep; Konstantinos Serfes (2001). "Intertemporal discounting and tenurial contracts". Journal of Development Economics. 64 (2): 417–436. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(00)00144-9.
  55. ^ Sen, Debapriya (2011). "A theory of sharecropping: the role of price behavior and imperfect competition" (PDF). Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 80 (1): 181–199. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2011.03.006. S2CID 191253.
  56. ^ Shetty, Sudhir (1988). "Limited liability, wealth differences, and the tenancy ladder in agrarian economies". Journal of Development Economics. 29: 1–22. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(88)90068-5.
  57. ^ Basu, Kaushik (1992). "Limited liability and the existence of share tenancy" (PDF). Journal of Development Economics. 38: 203–220. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(92)90026-6.
  58. ^ Sengupta, Kunal (1997). "Limited liability, moral hazard and share tenancy". Journal of Development Economics. 52 (2): 393–407. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(96)00444-0.
  59. ^ Ray, Tridip; Nirvikar Singh (2001). "Limited liability, contractual choice and the tenancy ladder". Journal of Development Economics. 66: 289–303. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(01)00163-8.

Further reading edit

  • Adams, Jane; Gorton, D. (2009). "This Land Ain't My Land: The Eviction of Sharecroppers by the Farm Security Administration". Agricultural History. 83 (3): 323–51. doi:10.3098/ah.2009.83.3.323.
  • Agee, James; Evans, Walker (1941). Let Us Now Praise Famous Men: Three Tenant Families. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
  • Allen, D. W.; Lueck, D. (1992). "Contract Choice in Modern Agriculture: Cash Rent versus Cropshare". Journal of Law and Economics. 35 (2): 397–426. doi:10.1086/467260. S2CID 153707520.
  • Barbagallo, Tricia (June 1, 2005). (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on November 13, 2013. Retrieved 2008-06-04.
  • Davis, Ronald L. F. (1982). Good and Faithful Labor: From Slavery to Sharecropping in the Natchez District, 1860–1890. Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Press. ISBN 0-313-23134-6.
  • Ferleger, Louis (1993). "Sharecropping Contracts in the Late-Nineteenth-Century South". Agricultural History. 67 (3): 31–46. JSTOR 3744228.
  • Garrett, Martin A.; Xu, Zhenhui (2003). "The Efficiency of Sharecropping: Evidence from the Postbellum South". Southern Economic Journal. 69 (3): 578–595. doi:10.1002/j.2325-8012.2003.tb00514.x.
  • Grubbs, Donald H. (1971). Cry from the Cotton: The Southern Tenant Farmer's Union and the New Deal. University of North Carolina Press. ISBN 0-8078-1156-4.
  • Hurt, R. Douglas Hurt (2003). African American Life in the Rural South, 1900–1950. University of Missouri Press. ISBN 0-8262-1471-1.
  • Liebowitz, Jonathan J. (1989). "Tenants, Sharecroppers, and the French Agricultural Depression of the Late Nineteenth Century". Journal of Interdisciplinary History. 19 (3): 429–445. doi:10.2307/204363. JSTOR 204363.
  • Reid, Joseph D. Jr. (1975). "Sharecropping in History and Theory". Agricultural History. 49 (2): 426–440. JSTOR 3741281.
  • Roll, Jarod (March 16, 2010). . Southern Spaces. Archived from the original on January 10, 2011.
  • Shaban, R. A. (1987). "Testing Between Competing Models of Sharecropping". Journal of Political Economy. 95 (5): 893–920. doi:10.1086/261495. S2CID 55141070.
  • Singh, N. (1989). "Theories of Sharecropping". In Bardhan, P. (ed.). The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions. Clarendon Press. pp. 33–72. ISBN 0-19-828619-8.
  • Southworth, Caleb (2002). "Aid to Sharecroppers: How Agrarian Class Structure and Tenant-Farmer Politics Influenced Federal Relief in the South, 1933–1935". Social Science History. 26 (1): 33–70.
  • Stiglitz, J. (1974). "Incentives and Risk Sharing in Share Cropping" (PDF). Review of Economic Studies. 41 (2): 219–255. doi:10.2307/2296714. JSTOR 2296714.
  • Turner, Howard A. (1937). "Farm Tenancy Distribution and Trends in the United States". Law and Contemporary Problems. 4 (4): 424–433. doi:10.2307/1189524. JSTOR 1189524.
  • Virts, Nancy (1991). "The Efficiency of Southern Tenant Plantations, 1900–1945". Journal of Economic History. 51 (2): 385–395. doi:10.1017/S0022050700039012. JSTOR 2122582. S2CID 154991172.
  • Wayne, Michael (1983). The Reshaping of Plantation Society: The Natchez District, 1860–1880. Baton Rouge, Louisiana: Louisiana State University Press. ISBN 0-8071-1050-7.

External links edit

  •   Media related to Sharecropping at Wikimedia Commons
  • King Cotton's Slaves, 1936 newsreel by The March of Time about landless Southern farmers

sharecropping, confused, with, cropsharing, this, article, needs, additional, citations, verification, please, help, improve, this, article, adding, citations, reliable, sources, unsourced, material, challenged, removed, find, sources, news, newspapers, books,. Not to be confused with Cropsharing This article needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Sharecropping news newspapers books scholar JSTOR December 2020 Learn how and when to remove this template message Sharecropping is a legal arrangement with regard to agricultural land in which a landowner allows a tenant to use the land in return for a share of the crops produced on that land Sharecropping has a long history and there are a wide range of different situations and types of agreements that have used a form of the system Some are governed by tradition and others by law The French metayage the Catalan masoveria the Castilian mediero the Slavic polownictwo and izdolshchina the Italian mezzadria and the Islamic system of muzara a المزارعة are examples of legal systems that have supported sharecropping Contents 1 Overview 1 1 Advantages 1 2 Disadvantages 2 Regions 2 1 Africa 2 2 United States 2 3 Sharecropping and socioeconomic status 3 Economic theories of share tenancy 4 See also 5 References 6 Further reading 7 External linksOverview edit nbsp A Farm Security Administration photo of a cropper family chopping the weeds from cotton near White Plains in Georgia US 1941 Sharecropping has benefits and costs for both the owners and the tenant Under a sharecropping system the landowner provided a share of land to be worked by the sharecropper and usually provided other necessities such as housing tools seed or working animals 1 Local merchants usually provided food and other supplies to the sharecropper on credit In exchange for the land and supplies the cropper would pay the owner a share of the crop at the end of the season typically one half to two thirds The cropper used his share to pay off his debt to the merchant 2 If there was any cash left over the cropper kept it but if his share came to less than what he owed he remained in debt Farmers who farmed land belonging to others but owned their own mule and plow were called tenant farmers they owed the landowner a smaller share of their crops as the landowner did not have to provide them with as much in the way of supplies In this system the landowner encourages the cropper to remain on the land solving the harvest rush problem clarification needed Since the cropper pays in shares or portions of his harvest owners and croppers both share the risks and benefits of harvests being large or small and of prices being high or low Because both parties benefit from larger harvests tenants have an incentive to work harder and invest in better methods than for example in a slave plantation system However by dividing the working force into many individual workers large farms do not benefit from economies of scale citation needed Though the arrangement protected sharecroppers from the negative effects of a bad crop many sharecroppers both white and black remained quite poor Advantages edit nbsp The commissary or company store for sharecroppers at Lake Providence Louisiana as it appeared in the 19th centurySociologist Jeffery M Paige made a distinction between centralized sharecropping found on cotton plantations and the decentralized sharecropping with other crops The former is characterized by long lasting tenure Tenants are tied to the landlord through the plantation store This form of tenure tends to be replaced by paid salaries as markets penetrate Decentralized sharecropping involves virtually no role for the landlord plots are scattered peasants manage their own labor and the landowners do not manufacture the crops This form of tenure becomes more common when markets penetrate 3 Some economists have argued that sharecropping is not as exploitative as it is often perceived John Heath and Hans P Binswanger contend that evidence from around the world suggests that sharecropping is often a way for differently endowed enterprises to pool resources to mutual benefit overcoming credit restraints and helping to manage risk 4 Sharecropping agreements can be made fairly as a form of tenant farming or sharefarming that has a variable rental payment paid in arrears There are three different types of contracts 5 Workers can rent plots of land from the owner for a certain sum and keep the whole crop Workers work on the land and earn a fixed wage from the land owner but keep some of the crop No money changes hands but the worker and land owner each keep a share of the crop It also gave sharecroppers a vested interest in the land incentivizing hard work and care American plantations were however wary of this interest as they felt that would lead to African Americans demanding rights of partnership Many black laborers denied the unilateral authority that landowners hoped to achieve further complicating relations between landowners and sharecroppers 6 Landlords opt for sharecropping to avoid the administrative costs and shirking that occurs on plantations and haciendas It is preferred to cash tenancy because cash tenants take all the risks and any harvest failure will hurt them and not the landlord Therefore they tend to demand lower rents than sharecroppers 7 Another possible benefit to sharecropping is that it enables women to have access to arable land albeit not as owners in places where ownership rights are vested only in men 8 Disadvantages edit The practice was harmful to tenants with many cases of high interest rates unpredictable harvests and unscrupulous landlords and merchants often keeping tenant farm families severely indebted The debt was often compounded year on year leaving the cropper vulnerable to intimidation and shortchanging 9 Nevertheless it appeared to be inevitable with no serious alternative unless the croppers left agriculture 10 11 A new system of credit the crop lien became closely associated with sharecropping Under this system a planter or merchant extended a line of credit to the sharecropper while taking the year s crop as collateral The sharecropper could then draw food and supplies all year long When the crop was harvested the planter or merchants who held the lien sold the harvest for the sharecropper and settled the debt Sharecropping has more than a passing similarity to serfdom or indenture particularly where associated with large debts at a plantation store that effectively ties down the workers and their family to the land It has therefore been seen as an issue of land reform in contexts such as the Mexican Revolution Regions editHistorically sharecropping occurred extensively in Scotland Ireland and colonial Africa Use of the sharecropper system has also been identified in England as the practice of farming to halves 12 It was widely used in the Southern United States during the Reconstruction era 1865 1877 that followed the American Civil War which was economically devastating to the southern states 13 It is still used in many rural poor areas of the world today notably in Pakistan India and Bangladesh 14 15 16 Africa edit In settler colonies of colonial Africa sharecropping was a feature of the agricultural life White farmers who owned most of the land were frequently unable to work the whole of their farm for lack of capital They therefore had African farmers to work the excess on a sharecropping basis In South Africa the 1913 Natives Land Act 17 outlawed the ownership of land by Africans in areas designated for white ownership and effectively reduced the status of most sharecroppers to tenant farmers and then to farm laborers In the 1960s generous subsidies to white farmers meant that most farmers could afford to work their entire farms and sharecropping faded out The arrangement has reappeared in other African countries in modern times including Ghana 18 and Zimbabwe 19 Economic historian Pius S Nyambara argued that Eurocentric historiographical devices such as feudalism or slavery often qualified by weak prefixes like semi or quasi are not helpful in understanding the antecedents and functions of sharecropping in Africa 19 United States edit nbsp Sharecroppers on the roadside after they were evicted for membership in the Southern Tenant Farmers Union January 1936 Further information Black land loss in the United States African American history of agriculture in the United States and Jim Crow economy Prior to the Civil War sharecropping is known to have existed in Mississippi and is believed to have been in place in Tennessee 20 21 However it was not until the economic upheaval caused by the American Civil War and the end of slavery during and after Reconstruction that it became widespread in the South 22 13 It is theorized that sharecropping in the United States originated in the Natchez District roughly centered in Adams County Mississippi with its county seat Natchez 23 After the war plantations and other lands throughout the South were seized by the federal government In January 1865 General William T Sherman issued Special Field Orders No 15 which announced that he would temporarily grant newly freed families 40 acres of this seized land on the islands and coastal regions of Georgia Many believed that this policy would be extended to all former slaves and their families as repayment for their treatment at the end of the war In the summer of 1865 President Andrew Johnson as one of the first acts of Reconstruction instead ordered all land under federal control be returned to the owners from whom it had been seized nbsp An early 20th century Texas sharecropper s home diorama at the Audie Murphy American Cotton Museum in Greenville Texas 2015Southern landowners thus found themselves with a great deal of land but no liquid assets to pay for labor Many former slaves now called freedmen having no land or other assets of their own needed to work to support their families A sharecropping system centered on cotton a major cash crop developed as a result Large plantations were subdivided into plots that could be worked by sharecroppers Initially sharecroppers in the American South were almost all black former slaves but eventually cash strapped indigent white farmers were integrated into the system 2 24 During Reconstruction the federal Freedmen s Bureau ordered the arrangements for freedmen and wrote and enforced their contracts 25 American sharecroppers worked a section of the plantation independently usually growing cotton tobacco rice sugar and other cash crops and received half of the parcel s output 26 27 Sharecroppers also often received their farming tools and all other goods from the landowner they were contracted with 1 Landowners dictated decisions relating to the crop mix and sharecroppers were often in agreements to sell their portion of the crop back to the landowner thus being subjected to manipulated prices 6 In addition to this landowners threatening to not renew the lease at the end of the growing season were able to apply pressure to their tenants 6 Sharecropping often proved economically problematic as the landowners held significant economic control 28 nbsp Cotton sharecroppers Hale County Alabama 1936In the Reconstruction Era sharecropping was one of few options for penniless freedmen to support themselves and their families Other solutions included the crop lien system where the farmer was extended credit for seed and other supplies by the merchant a rent labor system where the former slave rents his land but keeps his entire crop and the wage system worker earns a fixed wage but keeps none of their crop Sharecropping was by far the most economically efficient as it provided incentives for workers to produce a bigger harvest It was a stage beyond simple hired labor because the sharecropper had an annual contract 25 Sharecropping as historically practiced in the American South is considered more economically productive than the gang system of slave plantations though less efficient than modern agricultural techniques 29 nbsp Sharecropper s cabin displayed at Louisiana State Cotton Museum in Lake Providence Louisiana 2013 photo Sharecropping continued to be a significant institution in many states for decades following the Civil War By the early 1930s there were 5 5 million white tenant farmers sharecroppers and mixed cropping laborers in the United States and 3 million Blacks 30 31 In Tennessee sharecroppers operated approximately one third of all farm units in the state in the 1930s with white people making up two thirds or more of the sharecroppers 21 In Mississippi by 1900 36 of all white farmers were tenants or sharecroppers while 85 of black farmers were 20 In Georgia fewer than 16 000 farms were operated by black owners in 1910 while at the same time African Americans managed 106 738 farms as tenants 32 Around this time sharecroppers began to form unions protesting against poor treatment beginning in Tallapoosa County Alabama in 1931 and Arkansas in 1934 Membership in the Southern Tenant Farmers Union included both blacks and poor whites who used meetings protests and labor strikes to push for better treatment The success of these actions frightened and enraged landlords who responded with aggressive tactics 33 Landless farmers who fought the sharecropping system were socially denounced harassed by legal and illegal means and physically attacked by officials landlords agents or in extreme cases angry mobs 34 Sharecroppers strikes in Arkansas and the Missouri Bootheel the 1939 Missouri Sharecroppers Strike were documented in the newsreel Oh Freedom After While 35 The plight of a sharecropper was addressed in the song Sharecropper s Blues recorded by Charlie Barnet and His Orchestra in 1944 36 nbsp Sharecroppers chapel at Cotton Museum in Lake ProvidenceThe sharecropping system in the U S increased during the Great Depression with the creation of tenant farmers following the failure of many small farms throughout the Dustbowl Traditional sharecropping declined after mechanization of farm work became economical beginning in the late 1930s and early 1940s 21 37 As a result many sharecroppers were forced off the farms and migrated to cities to work in factories or became migrant workers in the Western United States during World War II By the end of the 1960s sharecropping had disappeared in the United States citation needed Sharecropping and socioeconomic status edit About two thirds of sharecroppers were white the rest black Sharecroppers the poorest of the poor organized for better conditions The racially integrated Southern Tenant Farmers Union made gains for sharecroppers in the 1930s Sharecropping had diminished in the 1940s due to the Great Depression farm mechanization and other factors 38 Economic theories of share tenancy edit nbsp A sharecropper family in Walker County Alabama c 1937 The theory of share tenancy was long dominated by Alfred Marshall s famous footnote in Book VI Chapter X 14 of Principles 39 where he illustrated the inefficiency of agricultural share contracting Steven N S Cheung 1969 40 challenged this view showing that with sufficient competition and in the absence of transaction costs share tenancy will be equivalent to competitive labor markets and therefore efficient 41 He also showed that in the presence of transaction costs share contracting may be preferred to either wage contracts or rent contracts due to the mitigation of labor shirking and the provision of risk sharing Joseph Stiglitz 1974 42 1988 43 suggested that if share tenancy is only a labor contract then it is only pairwise efficient and that land to the tiller reform would improve social efficiency by removing the necessity for labor contracts in the first place Reid 1973 44 Murrel 1983 45 Roumasset 1995 46 and Allen and Lueck 2004 47 provided transaction cost theories of share contracting wherein tenancy is more of a partnership than a labor contract and both landlord and tenant provide multiple inputs It has also been argued that the sharecropping institution can be explained by factors such as informational asymmetry Hallagan 1978 48 Allen 1982 49 Muthoo 1998 50 moral hazard Reid 1976 51 Eswaran and Kotwal 1985 52 Ghatak and Pandey 2000 53 intertemporal discounting Roy and Serfes 2001 54 price fluctuations Sen 2011 55 or limited liability Shetty 1988 56 Basu 1992 57 Sengupta 1997 58 Ray and Singh 2001 59 See also editCoolie Convict lease Peonage Rent seeking Rural tenancy Sharefarming Sharemilking Tenant farmer Wage slaveryReferences edit a b Mandle Jay R Not Slave Not Free The African American Economic Experience Since the Civil War Duke University Press 1992 22 a b Ronald L F Davis The U S Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District A Case Study The Journal of Negro History Vol 62 No 1 January 1977 pp 60 80 in JSTOR Jeffery Paige Agrarian Revolution page 373 Heath John amp Binswanger Hans P October 1998 Chapter 3 Policy Induced Effects of Natural Resource Degradation The Case of Colombia PDF In Lutz Ernest ed Agriculture and the Environment Perspectives on Sustainable Rural Development Washington DC The World Bank pp 32 ISBN 0 8213 4249 5 Retrieved 2011 04 01 Arthur F Raper and Ira De A Reid Sharecroppers All 1941 Gavin Wright Old South New South Revolutions in the Southern Economy since the Civil War 1986 a b c Royce Edward 1993 The Rise of Southern Sharecropping In Royce Edward ed The Origins of Southern Sharecropping Temple University Press pp 181 222 ISBN 9781566390699 JSTOR j ctt14bt3nz 9 Sharecropping and Sharecroppers T J Byres Bruce John W Country Profiles of Land Tenure Africa 1996 Lesotho p 221 Research Paper No 130 December 1998 Land Tenure Center University of Wisconsin Madison accessed at UMN edu Archived 2001 11 25 at the Wayback Machine June 19 2006 Sharecropping Slavery By Another Name Bento PBS Sharecropping Slavery By Another Name Bento PBS Rufus B Spain 1967 At Ease in Zion Social History of Southern Baptists 1865 1900 University of Alabama Press p 130 ISBN 9780817350383 Johnny E Williams 2008 African American Religion and the Civil Rights Movement in Arkansas Univ Press of Mississippi p 73 ISBN 9781604731866 Griffiths Liz Farming to Halves A New Perspective on an Absurd and Miserable System in Rural History Today Issue 6 2004 p 5 accessed at British Agricultural History Society 16 February 2013 a b Joseph D Reid Sharecropping as an understandable market response The postbellum South Journal of Economic History 1973 33 1 pp 106 130 in JSTOR Sanval Nasim Steven Helfand 2016 01 15 Optimal groundwater management in Pakistan s Indus Water Basin Intl Food Policy Res Inst Chaudhuri Ananish Maitra Pushkar 2000 01 01 Sharecropping contracts in rural India A note Journal of Contemporary Asia 30 1 99 107 doi 10 1080 00472330080000071 ISSN 0047 2336 S2CID 154416728 Byres T J 2005 08 02 Sharecropping and Sharecroppers Routledge ISBN 978 1 135 78003 6 The Native Land Act is passed South African History Online Sahistory org za Archived from the original on 14 October 2010 Retrieved 22 October 2023 Leonard R and Longbottom J Land Tenure Lexicon A glossary of terms from English and French speaking West Africa permanent dead link International Institute for Environment and Development IIED London 2000 a b Pius S Nyambara 2003 Rural Landlords Rural Tenants and the Sharecropping Complex in Gokwe Northwestern Zimbabwe 1980s 2002 PDF Archived from the original PDF on 2006 03 26 Retrieved 2006 05 18 Centre for Applied Social Sciences University of Zimbabwe and Land Tenure Center University of Wisconsin Madison March 2003 200Kb PDF a b Charles Bolton Farmers Without Land The Plight of White Tenant Farmers and Sharecroppers Archived 2016 03 04 at the Wayback Machine Mississippi History Now March 2004 a b c Robert Tracy McKenzie Sharecropping Tennessee Encyclopedia of History and Culture Sharon Monteith ed 2013 The Cambridge Companion to the Literature of the American South Cambridge U P p 94 ISBN 9781107036789 Ronald L F Davis The U S Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District A Case Study The Journal of Negro History Vol 62 No 1 January 1977 pp 60 80 in JSTOR Eva O Donovan Becoming Free in the Cotton South 2007 Gavin Wright Old South New South Revolutions in the Southern Economy Since the Civil War 1986 Roger L Ransom and David Beckham One Kind of Freedom The Economic Consequences of Emancipation 2nd ed 2008 a b Gregorie Anne King 1954 History of Sumter County South Carolina p 274 Library Board of Sumter County Woodman Harold D 1995 New South New Law The legal foundations of credit and labor relations in the Postbellum agricultural South Louisiana State University Press ISBN 0 8071 1941 5 F N Boney 2004 02 06 Poor Whites The New Georgia Encyclopedia Archived from the original on 2012 08 29 Retrieved 2006 05 18 Ransom Roger L and Richard Sutch One Kind of Freedom The Economic Consequences of Emancipation 2nd edition Cambridge England New York Cambridge University Press 2001 149 Larry J Griffin Don Harrison Doyle 1995 The South As an American Problem U of Georgia Press p 168 ISBN 9780820317526 The Rockabilly Legends They Called It Rockabilly Long Before they Called It Rock and Roll by Jerry Naylor and Steve Halliday DVD The Devil s Music A History of the Blues By Giles Oakley Edition 2 Da Capo Press 1997 p 184 ISBN 0 306 80743 2 ISBN 978 0 306 80743 5 Geisen James C January 26 2007 Sharecropping New Georgia Encyclopedia Retrieved April 23 2019 The Devil s Music A History of the Blues By Giles Oakley Edition 2 Da Capo Press 1997 p 185 ISBN 0 306 80743 2 ISBN 978 0 306 80743 5 Sharecroppers All Arthur F Raper and Ira De A Reid Chapell Hill 1941 The University of North Carolina Press 2011 ISBN 978 0 8078 9817 8 California Newsreel Film and Video for Social Change Since 1968 Newsreel org Retrieved 22 October 2023 Charlie Barnet Sharecropper s Blues YouTube 26 August 2011 Archived from the original on 2021 11 09 Gordon Marshall Sharecropping Encyclopedia com 1998 Sharecropping Slavery by Another Name PBS Retrieved 7 December 2021 Alfred Marshall 1920 Principles of Economics 8th ed London Macmillan and Co Ltd Cheung Steven N S 1969 Transaction Costs Risk Aversion and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements Journal of Law amp Economics 12 1 23 42 doi 10 1086 466658 S2CID 154860968 Retrieved 2009 06 14 Formalized in Roumasset James 1979 Sharecropping Production Externalities and the Theory of Contracts American Journal of Agricultural Economics 61 4 640 647 doi 10 2307 1239911 JSTOR 1239911 Stiglitz Joseph 1974 Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping PDF The Review of Economic Studies 41 2 219 255 j doi 10 2307 2296714 JSTOR 2296714 Stiglitz Joseph 1988 Principal And Agent Princeton Woodrow Wilson School Discussion Paper 12 Retrieved 2009 06 14 Reid Joseph D Jr March 1973 Sharecropping As An Understandable Market Response The Post Bellum South The Journal of Economic History 33 1 106 130 doi 10 1017 S0022050700076476 JSTOR 2117145 S2CID 155056632 Murrell Peter Spring 1983 The Economics of Sharing A Transactions Cost Analysis of Contractual Choice in Farming The Bell Journal of Economics 14 1 283 293 doi 10 2307 3003555 JSTOR 3003555 Roumasset James March 1995 The nature of the agricultural firm Journal of Economic Behavior amp Organization 26 2 161 177 doi 10 1016 0167 2681 94 00007 2 Allen Douglas W Dean Lueck 2004 The Nature of the Farm Contracts Risk and Organization in Agriculture MIT Press p 258 ISBN 9780262511858 Hallagan William 1978 Self selection by contractual choice and the theory of sharecropping Bell Journal of Economics 9 2 344 354 doi 10 2307 3003586 JSTOR 3003586 Allen Franklin 1982 On share contracts and screening Bell Journal of Economics 13 2 541 547 doi 10 2307 3003473 JSTOR 3003473 Muthoo Abhinay 1998 Renegotiation proof tenurial contracts as screening mechanisms Journal of Development Economics 56 1 26 doi 10 1016 S0304 3878 98 00050 9 Reid Joseph D Jr 1976 Sharecropping and agricultural uncertainty Economic Development and Cultural Change 24 3 549 576 doi 10 1086 450897 JSTOR 1153005 S2CID 154402121 Eswaran Mukesh Ashok Kotwal 1985 A theory of contractual structure in agriculture American Economic Review 75 3 352 367 JSTOR 1814805 Ghatak Maitreesh Priyanka Pandey 2000 Contract choice in agriculture with joint moral hazard in effort and risk Journal of Development Economics 63 2 303 326 doi 10 1016 S0304 3878 00 00116 4 Roy Jaideep Konstantinos Serfes 2001 Intertemporal discounting and tenurial contracts Journal of Development Economics 64 2 417 436 doi 10 1016 S0304 3878 00 00144 9 Sen Debapriya 2011 A theory of sharecropping the role of price behavior and imperfect competition PDF Journal of Economic Behavior amp Organization 80 1 181 199 doi 10 1016 j jebo 2011 03 006 S2CID 191253 Shetty Sudhir 1988 Limited liability wealth differences and the tenancy ladder in agrarian economies Journal of Development Economics 29 1 22 doi 10 1016 0304 3878 88 90068 5 Basu Kaushik 1992 Limited liability and the existence of share tenancy PDF Journal of Development Economics 38 203 220 doi 10 1016 0304 3878 92 90026 6 Sengupta Kunal 1997 Limited liability moral hazard and share tenancy Journal of Development Economics 52 2 393 407 doi 10 1016 S0304 3878 96 00444 0 Ray Tridip Nirvikar Singh 2001 Limited liability contractual choice and the tenancy ladder Journal of Development Economics 66 289 303 doi 10 1016 S0304 3878 01 00163 8 Further reading editAdams Jane Gorton D 2009 This Land Ain t My Land The Eviction of Sharecroppers by the Farm Security Administration Agricultural History 83 3 323 51 doi 10 3098 ah 2009 83 3 323 Agee James Evans Walker 1941 Let Us Now Praise Famous Men Three Tenant Families Boston Houghton Mifflin Allen D W Lueck D 1992 Contract Choice in Modern Agriculture Cash Rent versus Cropshare Journal of Law and Economics 35 2 397 426 doi 10 1086 467260 S2CID 153707520 Barbagallo Tricia June 1 2005 Black Beach The Mucklands of Canastota New York PDF Archived from the original PDF on November 13 2013 Retrieved 2008 06 04 Davis Ronald L F 1982 Good and Faithful Labor From Slavery to Sharecropping in the Natchez District 1860 1890 Westport Connecticut Greenwood Press ISBN 0 313 23134 6 Ferleger Louis 1993 Sharecropping Contracts in the Late Nineteenth Century South Agricultural History 67 3 31 46 JSTOR 3744228 Garrett Martin A Xu Zhenhui 2003 The Efficiency of Sharecropping Evidence from the Postbellum South Southern Economic Journal 69 3 578 595 doi 10 1002 j 2325 8012 2003 tb00514 x Grubbs Donald H 1971 Cry from the Cotton The Southern Tenant Farmer s Union and the New Deal University of North Carolina Press ISBN 0 8078 1156 4 Hurt R Douglas Hurt 2003 African American Life in the Rural South 1900 1950 University of Missouri Press ISBN 0 8262 1471 1 Liebowitz Jonathan J 1989 Tenants Sharecroppers and the French Agricultural Depression of the Late Nineteenth Century Journal of Interdisciplinary History 19 3 429 445 doi 10 2307 204363 JSTOR 204363 Reid Joseph D Jr 1975 Sharecropping in History and Theory Agricultural History 49 2 426 440 JSTOR 3741281 Roll Jarod March 16 2010 Out Yonder on the Road Working Class Self Representation and the 1939 Roadside Demonstration in Southeast Missouri Southern Spaces Archived from the original on January 10 2011 Shaban R A 1987 Testing Between Competing Models of Sharecropping Journal of Political Economy 95 5 893 920 doi 10 1086 261495 S2CID 55141070 Singh N 1989 Theories of Sharecropping In Bardhan P ed The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions Clarendon Press pp 33 72 ISBN 0 19 828619 8 Southworth Caleb 2002 Aid to Sharecroppers How Agrarian Class Structure and Tenant Farmer Politics Influenced Federal Relief in the South 1933 1935 Social Science History 26 1 33 70 Stiglitz J 1974 Incentives and Risk Sharing in Share Cropping PDF Review of Economic Studies 41 2 219 255 doi 10 2307 2296714 JSTOR 2296714 Turner Howard A 1937 Farm Tenancy Distribution and Trends in the United States Law and Contemporary Problems 4 4 424 433 doi 10 2307 1189524 JSTOR 1189524 Virts Nancy 1991 The Efficiency of Southern Tenant Plantations 1900 1945 Journal of Economic History 51 2 385 395 doi 10 1017 S0022050700039012 JSTOR 2122582 S2CID 154991172 Wayne Michael 1983 The Reshaping of Plantation Society The Natchez District 1860 1880 Baton Rouge Louisiana Louisiana State University Press ISBN 0 8071 1050 7 External links edit nbsp Media related to Sharecropping at Wikimedia Commons King Cotton s Slaves 1936 newsreel by The March of Time about landless Southern farmers Portal nbsp Agriculture and agronomy Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Sharecropping amp oldid 1181349604, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.