fbpx
Wikipedia

Price discrimination

Price discrimination is a microeconomic pricing strategy where identical or largely similar goods or services are sold at different prices by the same provider in different market segments.[1][2][3] Price discrimination is distinguished from product differentiation by the more substantial difference in production cost for the differently priced products involved in the latter strategy.[3] Price differentiation essentially relies on the variation in the customers' willingness to pay[2][3][4] and in the elasticity of their demand. For price discrimination to succeed, a firm must have market power, such as a dominant market share, product uniqueness, sole pricing power, etc.[5] All prices under price discrimination are higher than the equilibrium price in a perfectly competitive market. However, some prices under price discrimination may be lower than the price charged by a single-price monopolist. Price discrimination is utilised by the monopolist to recapture some deadweight loss.[6] This Pricing strategy enables firms to capture additional consumer surplus and maximize their profits while benefiting some consumers at lower prices. Price discrimination can take many forms and is prevalent in many industries, from education and telecommunications to healthcare.[7]

Student discounts, which participating businesses offer to individuals enrolled as full-time postsecondary students and who possess valid student identification (like this student discount card), are a common example of price discrimination.

The term differential pricing is also used to describe the practice of charging different prices to different buyers for the same quality and quantity of a product,[8] but it can also refer to a combination of price differentiation and product differentiation.[3] Other terms used to refer to price discrimination include "equity pricing", "preferential pricing",[9] "dual pricing"[4] and "tiered pricing".[10] Within the broader domain of price differentiation, a commonly accepted classification dating to the 1920s is:[11][12]

  • "Personalized pricing" (or first-degree price differentiation) — selling to each customer at a different price; this is also called one-to-one marketing.[11] The optimal incarnation of this is called "perfect price discrimination" and maximizes the price that each customer is willing to pay.[11] As such, in first degree price differentiation the entire consumer surplus is captured for each individual.[13]
  • "Product versioning"[2][14] or simply "versioning" (or second-degree price differentiation) — offering a product line[11] by creating slightly differentiated products for the purpose of price differentiation,[2][14] i.e. a vertical product line.[15] Another name given to versioning is "menu pricing".[12][16]
  • "Group pricing" (or third-degree price differentiation) — dividing the market into segments and charging a different price to each segment (but the same price to each member of that segment).[11][17] This is essentially a heuristic approximation that simplifies the problem in face of the difficulties with personalized pricing.[12][18] Typical examples include student discounts[17] and seniors' discounts.

Theoretical basis

In a theoretical market with perfect information, perfect substitutes, and no transaction costs or prohibition on secondary exchange (or re-selling) to prevent arbitrage, price discrimination can only be a feature of monopoly and oligopoly markets,[19] where market power can be exercised (see 'Price discrimination and monopoly power' below for more in-depth explanation). Without market power when the price is differentiated higher than the market equilibrium consumers will move to buy from other producers selling at the market equilibrium.[20] Moreover, when the seller tries to sell the same good at differentiating prices, the buyer at the lower price can arbitrage by selling to the consumer buying at the higher price with a small discount from the higher price.[21]

Price discrimination requires market segmentation and some means to discourage discount customers from becoming resellers and, by extension, competitors.[22] This usually entails using one or more means of preventing any resale: keeping the different price groups separate, making price comparisons difficult, or restricting pricing information.[21] The boundary set up by the marketer to keep segments separate is referred to as a rate fence (a rule that allow consumers to segment themselves into based on their needs, behaviour and willingness to pay).[23] Price discrimination is thus very common in services where resale is not possible; an example is student discounts at museums: In theory, students, for their condition as students, may get lower prices than the rest of the population for a certain product or service, and later will not become resellers, since what they received, may only be used or consumed by them because it is required to show their student identification card when making the purchase. Another example of price discrimination is intellectual property, enforced by law and by technology. In the market for DVDs, laws require DVD players to be designed and produced with hardware or software that prevents inexpensive copying or playing of content purchased legally elsewhere in the world at a lower price. In the US the Digital Millennium Copyright Act has provisions to outlaw circumventing of such devices to protect the enhanced monopoly profits that copyright holders can obtain from price discrimination against higher price market segments.

Price discrimination differentiates the willingness to pay of the customers, in order to eliminate as much consumer surplus as possible. By understanding the elasticity of the customer's demand, a business could use its market power to identify the customers' willingness to pay.[20] Different people would pay a different price for the same product when price discrimination exists in the market. When a company recognized a consumer that has a lower willingness to pay, the company could use the price discrimination strategy in order to maximized the firm's profit.[24]

Price discrimination and market power

Degrees of market power

Market Power refers to the ability of a firm to manipulate the price without losing shares (sales) in the market.[22] Some factors which affect the market power of a firm are listed below:[25]

  • Number of competitors in the market
  • Product differentiation between competitors
  • Entry restrictions

The degree of market power can usually be divided into 4 categories (listed in the table below in order of increasing market power):[22][26]

Type of Market Features Industry Examples
Perfect Competition
  • High competitor volume
  • Homogenous goods and services
  • No entry restrictions
Farmers selling vegetables at a market
Monopolistic Competition
  • Moderate competitor volume
  • Differentiated product
  • Low entry restrictions
Fast food industry
Oligopoly
  • Small competitor volume
  • Some product differentiation
  • Difficult entry
Airline industry
Monopoly
  • Sole producer
  • No substitutes
  • Impossible entry (i.e. patents, contracts which prevent entry)
Water Utility Company servicing the region


Since price discrimination is dependant on a firms market power generally monopolies use price discrimination, however, oligopolies can also use price discrimination when the risk of arbitrage and consumers moving to other competitors is low.[20]

Price discrimination in oligopolies

An oligopoly forms when a small group of business dominates an industry. When the dominating companies in an oligopoly model compete in prices, the motive for inter-temporal price discrimination would appear in the oligopoly market. Price discrimination can be facilitated by inventory controls in oligopoly.[27]

Whilst oligopolies hold more market power than perfectly competitive markets the use of price discrimination can lead to lower profits for oligopolies as they compete to hold greater shares of the market by lowering prices.[28] For instance, when Oligopolies use third degree price discrimination to offer a lower price to consumers with high price elasticity (lower disposable income) they compete with other firms to capture the market until a lower profit is retained.[28] Hence, Oligopolies may be dissuaded from using price discrimination.

Types of Price Discrimination

First degree (Perfect price discrimination)

Exercising first degree (or perfect or primary) price discrimination requires the monopoly seller of a good or service to know the absolute maximum price (or reservation price) that every consumer is willing to pay. By knowing the reservation price, the seller is able to sell the good or service to each consumer at the maximum price they are willing to pay (granted it is greater or equal to the marginal cost), and thus transform the consumer surplus into seller revenue.[13] Resultantly, the profit is equal to the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus.[20] First-degree price discrimination is the most profitable as it obtains all of the consumer surplus and each consumer buys the good at the highest price they are willing to pay.[20] The marginal consumer is the one whose reservation price equals the marginal cost of the product, meaning that the social surplus is entirely from producer surplus (no consumer surplus). If the seller engages in first degree price discrimination, then they will produce more product than they would with no price discrimination. Hence first degree price discrimination can eliminate deadweight loss that occurs in monopolistic markets.[20] Examples of first degree price discrimination can be observed in markets where consumers bid for tenders, though, in this case, the practice of collusive tendering could reduce the market efficiency.[29]

Second degree (Quantity discount)

In second-degree price discrimination, price of the same good varies according to quantity demanded. It usually comes in the form of quantity discount which recognises of the law of diminishing marginal utility. The Law of diminishing marginal utility stipulates that a consumers utility may decrease (diminish) with each successive unit.[22] For example, the marginal utility received from enjoying a ride at a theme park may gradually diminish after each time you go on the same ride. By offering a quantity discount for a larger quantity purchased the seller is able to capture some of the consumer surplus but not all.[20] This is because diminishing marginal utility may mean the consumer would not be willing to purchase an additional unit without a discount since the marginal utility received from the good or service is no longer greater than price.[22] However, by offering a discount the seller can capture some of consumers surplus by encouraging them to purchase an additional unit at a discounted price.[20] This is particularly widespread in sales to industrial customers, where bulk buyers enjoy discounts.[30]

Mobile phone plans and different subscriptions are often other instances of second-degree price discrimination. Consumers will usually believe a one-year subscription is more cost-effective than a monthly one. Whether or not consumers actually need such a long-time subscription, they are more likely to accept and pay the cost-effective one.[31] Besides, the producer will consequently see an increase in sales and profit. Second-price discrimination, also known as non-linear pricing, benefits consumers by allowing them to purchase at a cheaper price when they buy more instead of at the normal price.[32]

Third degree (Market Segregation)

Third-degree price discrimination means charging a different price to a group of consumers based on their different elasticities of demand, and the group with less elastic always be charged a higher price.[20] For example, rail and tube (subway) travelers can be subdivided into commuters and casual travelers, and cinema goers can be subdivided into adults and children, with some theatres also offering discounts to full-time students and seniors. Splitting the market into peak and off-peak use of service is very common and occurs with gas, electricity, and telephone supply, as well as gym membership and parking charges.[33]

In order to offer different prices for different groups of people in the aggregate market, the business has to use additional information to identify its consumers. It is crucial for the business to set prices according to the consumers' willingness to buy. Consequently, they will be involved in third-degree price discrimination.[34] With third-degree price discrimination, the firms try to generate sales by identifying different market segments, such as domestic and industrial users, with different price elasticities.[20] Markets must be kept separate by time, physical distance, and nature of use. For example, Microsoft Office Schools edition is available for a lower price to educational institutions than to other users. The markets cannot overlap so that consumers who purchase at a lower price in the elastic sub-market could resell at a higher price in the inelastic sub-market.

Two-part tariff

The two-part tariff is another form of price discrimination where the producer charges an initial fee and a secondary fee for the use of the product. This pricing strategy yields a result similar to second-degree price discrimination. In addition, the two-part tariff is desirable for welfare because the monopolistic markup can be eliminated. However, an upstream monopolist has the authority to set higher unit wholesale prices to the downstream firms in discriminatory two-part tariff, which is different from uniform two-part tariff pricing. As a result, the discriminatory two-part tariff for wholesale prices can harm social welfare.

An example of two-part tariff pricing is in the market for shaving razors.[35] The customer pays an initial cost for the razor and then pays again for the replacement blades. This pricing strategy works because it shifts the demand curve to the right: since the customer has already paid for the initial blade holder and will continue to buy the blades which are cheaper than buying disposable razors.

Combination

These types are not mutually exclusive. Thus a company may vary pricing by location, but then offer bulk discounts as well. Airlines use several different types of price discrimination, including:

  • Bulk discounts to wholesalers, consolidators, and tour operators
  • Incentive discounts for higher sales volumes to travel agents and corporate buyers
  • Seasonal discounts, incentive discounts, and even general prices that vary by location. The price of a flight from say, Singapore to Beijing can vary widely if one buys the ticket in Singapore compared to Beijing (or New York or Tokyo or elsewhere).
  • Discounted tickets requiring advance purchase and/or Saturday stays. Both restrictions have the effect of excluding business travelers, who typically travel during the workweek and arrange trips on shorter notice.
  • First degree price discrimination based on customer. Hotel or car rental firms may quote higher prices to their loyalty program's top tier members than to the general public.[36]

User-controlled price discrimination

While the conventional theory of price discrimination generally assumes that prices are set by the seller, there is a variant form in which prices are set by the buyer, such as in the form of pay what you want pricing. Such user-controlled price discrimination exploits similar ability to adapt to varying demand curves or individual price sensitivities, and may avoid the negative perceptions of price discrimination as imposed by a seller.

In the matching markets, the platforms will internalize the impacts in revenue to create a cross-side effects. In return, this cross-side effect will differentiate price discrimination in matching intermediation from the standard markets.[37][38][39]

Modern taxonomy

The first/second/third degree taxonomy of price discrimination is due to Pigou (Economics of Welfare, 3rd edition, 1929).[40] However, these categories are not mutually exclusive or exhaustive. Ivan Png (Managerial Economics, 1998: 301-315) suggests an alternative taxonomy:[41]

Complete discrimination

where the seller prices each unit at a different price, so that each user purchases up to the point where the user's marginal benefit equals the marginal cost of the item;

Direct segmentation

where the seller can condition price on some attribute (like age or gender) that directly segments the buyers;

Indirect segmentation

where the seller relies on some proxy (e.g., package size, usage quantity, coupon) to structure a choice that indirectly segments the buyers;

Uniform pricing

where the seller sets the same price for each unit of the product.

The hierarchy—complete/direct/indirect/uniform pricing—is in decreasing order of profitability and information requirement.[41] Complete price discrimination is most profitable, and requires the seller to have the most information about buyers. Next most profitable and in information requirement is direct segmentation, followed by indirect segmentation. Finally, uniform pricing is the least profitable and requires the seller to have the least information about buyers is.

Explanation

 
Sales revenue without and with Price Discrimination

The purpose of price discrimination is generally to capture the market's consumer surplus. This surplus arises because, in a market with a single clearing price, some customers (the very low price elasticity segment) would have been prepared to pay more than the market price. Price discrimination transfers some of this surplus from the consumer to the seller.[20] It is a way of increasing monopoly profit. In a perfectly competitive market, manufacturers make normal profit, but not monopoly profit, so they cannot engage in price discrimination.[22]

It can be argued that strictly, a consumer surplus need not exist, for example where fixed costs or economies of scale mean that the marginal cost of adding more consumers is less than the marginal profit from selling more product. This means that charging some consumers less than an even share of costs can be beneficial. An example is a high-speed internet connection shared by two consumers in a single building; if one is willing to pay less than half the cost of connecting the building, and the other willing to make up the rest but not to pay the entire cost, then price discrimination can allow the purchase to take place. However, this will cost the consumers as much or more than if they pooled their money to pay a non-discriminating price. If the consumer is considered to be the building, then a consumer surplus goes to the inhabitants.

It can be proved mathematically that a firm facing a downward sloping demand curve that is convex to the origin will always obtain higher revenues under price discrimination than under a single price strategy. This can also be shown geometrically.

In the top diagram, a single price   is available to all customers. The amount of revenue is represented by area  . The consumer surplus is the area above line segment   but below the demand curve  .

With price discrimination, (the bottom diagram), the demand curve is divided into two segments (  and  ). A higher price   is charged to the low elasticity segment, and a lower price   is charged to the high elasticity segment. The total revenue from the first segment is equal to the area  . The total revenue from the second segment is equal to the area  . The sum of these areas will always be greater than the area without discrimination assuming the demand curve resembles a rectangular hyperbola with unitary elasticity. The more prices that are introduced, the greater the sum of the revenue areas, and the more of the consumer surplus is captured by the producer.

The above requires both first and second degree price discrimination: the right segment corresponds partly to different people than the left segment, partly to the same people, willing to buy more if the product is cheaper.

It is very useful for the price discriminator to determine the optimum prices in each market segment. This is done in the next diagram where each segment is considered as a separate market with its own demand curve. As usual, the profit maximizing output (Qt) is determined by the intersection of the marginal cost curve (MC) with the marginal revenue curve for the total market (MRt).

 
Multiple Market Price Determination; splitting the demand line where it bends (bend: right; split: left and center)

The firm decides what amount of the total output to sell in each market by looking at the intersection of marginal cost with marginal revenue (profit maximization). This output is then divided between the two markets, at the equilibrium marginal revenue level. Therefore, the optimum outputs are   and  . From the demand curve in each market the profit can be determined maximizing prices of   and  .

The marginal revenue in both markets at the optimal output levels must be equal, otherwise the firm could profit from transferring output over to whichever market is offering higher marginal revenue.

Given that Market 1 has a price elasticity of demand of   and Market 2 of  , the optimal pricing ration in Market 1 versus Market 2 is  .

The price in a perfectly competitive market will always be lower than any price under price discrimination (including in special cases like the internet connection example above, assuming that the perfectly competitive market allows consumers to pool their resources). In a market with perfect competition, no price discrimination is possible, and the average total cost (ATC) curve will be identical to the marginal cost curve (MC). The price will be the intersection of this ATC/MC curve and the demand line (Dt). The consumer thus buys the product at the cheapest price at which any manufacturer can produce any quantity.

Price discrimination is a sign that the market is imperfect, the seller has some monopoly power, and that prices and seller profits are higher than they would be in a perfectly competitive market.

Advantages and disadvantages of price discrimination

Advantages of price discrimination

  1. Firms that hold some monopolistic or oliogopolistic power will be able to increase their revenue. In theory, they might also use the money for investment which benefit consumers, like research and development, though this is more common in a competitive market where innovation brings temporary market power.
  2. Lower prices (for some) than in a one-price monopoly. Even the lowest "discounted" prices will be higher than the price in a competitive market, which is equal to the cost of production. For example, trains tend to be near-monopolies (see natural monopoly). So old people may get lower train fares than they would if everyone got the same price, because the train company knows that old people are more likely to be poor. Also, customers willing to spend time in researching ‘special offers’ get lower prices; their effort acts as an honest signal of their price-sensitivity, by reducing their consumer surplus by the value of the time spent hunting.

True price discrimination occurs when exactly the same product is sold at multiple prices. It benefits only the seller, compared to a competitive market. It benefits some buyers at a (greater) cost to others, causing a net loss to consumers, compared to a single-price monopoly. For congestion pricing, which can benefit the buyer and is not price discrimination, see counterexamples below.

Disadvantages of price discrimination

  1. Higher prices. Under price discrimination, all consumers will pay higher prices than they would in a competitive market. Some consumers will end up paying higher prices than they would in a single-price monopoly. These higher prices are likely to be allocatively inefficient because P MC.
  2. Decline in consumer surplus. Price discrimination enables a transfer of money from consumers to firms – increasing wealth inequality.
  3. Potentially unfair. Those who pay higher prices may not be the richest. For example, adults paying full price could be unemployed, senior citizens can be very well off.
  4. Administration costs. There will be administration costs in separating the markets, which could lead to higher prices.
  5. Predatory pricing. Profits from price discrimination could be used to finance predatory pricing.[42] Predatory pricing can be used to maintain the monopolistic power needed to price-discriminate.

Examples

Retail price discrimination

Manufacturers may sell their products to similarly situated retailers at different prices based solely on the volume of products purchased. Sometimes, the firm investigate the consumers’ purchase histories which would show the customer's unobserved willingness to pay. Each customer has a purchasing score which indicates his or her preferences; consequently, the firm will be able to set the price for the individual customer at the point that minimizes the consumer surplus. Oftentimes, consumers are not aware of the ways to manipulate that score. If he or she wants to do to so, he or she could reduce the demand to reduce the average equilibrium price, which will reduce the firm's price discriminating strategy.[43]It's an instance of third-degree price discrimination.

Travel industry

Airlines and other travel companies use differentiated pricing regularly, as they sell travel products and services simultaneously to different market segments. This is often done by assigning capacity to various booking classes, which sell for different prices and which may be linked to fare restrictions. The restrictions or "fences" help ensure that market segments buy in the booking class range that has been established for them. For example, schedule-sensitive business passengers who are willing to pay $300 for a seat from city A to city B cannot purchase a $150 ticket because the $150 booking class contains a requirement for a Saturday-night stay, or a 15-day advance purchase, or another fare rule that discourages, minimizes, or effectively prevents a sale to business passengers.[44]

Notice however that in this example "the seat" is not always the same product. That is, the business person who purchases the $300 ticket may be willing to do so in return for a seat on a high-demand morning flight, for full refundability if the ticket is not used, and for the ability to upgrade to first class if space is available for a nominal fee. On the same flight are price-sensitive passengers who are not willing to pay $300, but who are willing to fly on a lower-demand flight (one leaving an hour earlier), or via a connection city (not a non-stop flight), and who are willing to forgo refundability.

On the other hand, an airline may also apply differential pricing to "the same seat" over time, e.g. by discounting the price for an early or late booking and for weekend purchases (without changing any other fare condition). It is part of an airline’s profit-maximizing strategy by segmenting price-sensitive leisure travellers from price inelastic business travellers as the former often have an incentive to buy in advance and often purchase on weekends.[45][46] This could present an arbitrage opportunity in the absence of any restriction on reselling. However, passenger name changes are typically prevented or financially penalized by contract.

In addition, an airline may apply directional price discrimination by charging passengers different roundtrip fares based on their origins. For example, the per capita income of City A is $30,000 higher than City B and the finding implies that passengers originating from City A will pay $5400 - $12900 more than those from City B. It is argued that this price discrimination method is the result of airlines segmenting passenger price sensitivity based on their income of route endpoints.[47]

Since airlines often fly multi-leg flights, and since no-show rates vary by segment, competition for the seat has to take in the spatial dynamics of the product. Someone trying to fly A-B is competing with people trying to fly A-C through city B on the same aircraft. This is one reason airlines use yield management technology to determine how many seats to allot for A-B passengers, B-C passengers, and A-B-C passengers, at their varying fares and with varying demands and no-show rates.

With the rise of the Internet and the growth of low fare airlines, airfare pricing transparency has become far more pronounced. Passengers discovered it is quite easy to compare fares across different flights or different airlines. This helped put pressure on airlines to lower fares. Meanwhile, in the recession following the September 11, 2001, attacks on the U.S., business travelers and corporate buyers made it clear to airlines that they were not going to be buying air travel at rates high enough to subsidize lower fares for non-business travelers. This prediction has come true, as vast numbers of business travelers are buying airfares only in economy class for business travel.

Mean while, there are sometimes group discounts on rail tickets and passes (second-degree price discrimination).

Coupons

The use of coupons in retail is an attempt to distinguish customers by their reserve price. The assumption is that people who go through the trouble of collecting coupons have greater price sensitivity than those who do not. Thus, making coupons available enables, for instance, breakfast cereal makers to charge higher prices to price-insensitive customers, while still making some profit off customers who are more price-sensitive.

Another example can also be seen in how to collect grocery store coupons before the existence of digital coupons. Grocery store coupons were usually available in the free newspapers or magazines placed at the entrance of the stores. As coupons have a negative relationship with time, customers with a high value of time will not find it worthwhile to spend 20 minutes in order to save $5 only. Meanwhile, customers with a low value of time will be satisfied by getting $5 less from their purchase as they tend to be more price-sensitive. [48]It's an instance of third-degree price discrimination.

Premium pricing

For certain products, premium products are priced at a level (compared to "regular" or "economy" products) that is well beyond their marginal cost of production. For example, a coffee chain may price regular coffee at $1, but "premium" coffee at $2.50 (where the respective costs of production may be $0.90 and $1.25). Economists such as Tim Harford in the Undercover Economist have argued that this is a form of price discrimination: by providing a choice between a regular and premium product, consumers are being asked to reveal their degree of price sensitivity (or willingness to pay) for comparable products. Similar techniques are used in pricing business class airline tickets and premium alcoholic drinks, for example.They are examples of the third-degree price discrimination.

This effect can lead to (seemingly) perverse incentives for the producer. If, for example, potential business class customers will pay a large price differential only if economy class seats are uncomfortable while economy class customers are more sensitive to price than comfort, airlines may have substantial incentives to purposely make economy seating uncomfortable. In the example of coffee, a restaurant may gain more economic profit by making poor quality regular coffee—more profit is gained from up-selling to premium customers than is lost from customers who refuse to purchase inexpensive but poor quality coffee. In such cases, the net social utility should also account for the "lost" utility to consumers of the regular product, although determining the magnitude of this foregone utility may not be feasible.

Segmentation by age group, student status, ethnicity and citizenship

Many movie theaters, amusement parks, tourist attractions, and other places have different admission prices per market segment: typical groupings are Youth/Child, Student, Adult, Senior Citizen, Local and Foreigner. Each of these groups typically have a much different demand curve. Children, people living on student wages, and people living on retirement generally have much less disposable income. Foreigners may be perceived as being more wealthy than locals and therefore being capable of paying more for goods and services - sometimes this can be even 35 times as much.[4] Market stall-holders and individual public transport providers may also insist on higher prices for their goods and services when dealing with foreigners (sometimes called the "White Man Tax").[49][50] Some goods - such as housing - may be offered at cheaper prices for certain ethnic groups.[51]

Besides, public transport fare is also an example of price discrimination. Kids, senior citizens, and students are eligible to receive concessions for their public transport fare. In Queensland, for example, these three groups of people get to use public transport by paying only half of the actual price. Thus, other public transport users may find it not fair for them to pay less for the same service. It's the example of the third-price discrimination.

Discounts for members of certain occupations

Some businesses may offer reduced prices members of some occupations, such as school teachers (see below), police and military personnel. In addition to increased sales to the target group, businesses benefit from the resulting positive publicity, leading to increased sales to the general public.

Incentives for industrial buyers

Many methods exist to incentivize wholesale or industrial buyers. These may be quite targeted, as they are designed to generate specific activity, such as buying more frequently, buying more regularly, buying in bigger quantities, buying new products with established ones, and so on. They may also be designed to reduce the administrative and finance costs of processing each transaction. Thus, there are bulk discounts, special pricing for long-term commitments, non-peak discounts, discounts on high-demand goods to incentivize buying lower-demand goods, rebates, and many others. This can help the relations between the firms involved. It's the example of the second-price discrimination.

Gender-based examples

Gender-based price discrimination is the practice of offering identical or similar services and products to men and women at different prices when the cost of producing the products and services is the same.[52] In the United States, gender-based price discrimination has been a source of debate.[53] In 1992, the New York City Department of Consumer Affairs (“DCA”) conducted an investigation of “price bias against women in the marketplace”.[54] The DCA's investigation concluded that women paid more than men at used car dealers, dry cleaners, and hair salons.[54] The DCA's research on gender pricing in New York City brought national attention to gender-based price discrimination and the financial impact it has on women.

With consumer products, differential pricing is usually not based explicitly on the actual gender of the purchaser, but is achieved implicitly by the use of differential packaging, labelling, or colour schemes designed to appeal to male or female consumers. In many cases, where the product is marketed to make an attractive gift, the gender of the purchaser may be different from that of the end user.

In 1995, California Assembly's Office of Research studied the issue of gender-based price discrimination of services and estimated that women effectively paid an annual “gender tax” of approximately $1,351.00 for the same services as men.[55] It was also estimated that women, over the course of their lives, spend thousands of dollars more than men to purchase similar products.[55] For example, prior to the enactment of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act[56] (“Affordable Care Act”), health insurance companies charged women higher premiums for individual health insurance policies than men. Under the Affordable Care Act, health insurance companies are now required to offer the same premium price to all applicants of the same age and geographical locale without regard to gender.[57] However, there is no federal law banning gender-based price discrimination in the sale of products.[58] Instead, several cities and states have passed legislation prohibiting gender-based price discrimination on products and services.

In Europe, motor insurance premiums have historically been higher for men than for women, a practice that the insurance industry attempts to justify on the basis of different levels of risk. The EU has banned this practice; however, there is evidence that it is being replaced by "proxy discrimination", that is, discrimination on the basis of factors that are strongly correlated with gender: for example, charging construction workers more than midwives.[59]

In Chinese retail automobile market, researchers found that male buyers pay less than female buyers for cars with the same characteristics. Although this research documented the existence of price discrimination between locals and non-locals, local men still receive $221.63 discount more than local women and non-local men receive $330.19 discount more than non-local women. The discount represents approximately 10% of average personal budget, considering the per capita GDP for 2018.[60]

International price discrimination

Pharmaceutical companies may charge customers living in wealthier countries a much higher price than for identical drugs in poorer nations, as is the case with the sale of antiretroviral drugs in Africa. Since the purchasing power of African consumers is much lower, sales would be extremely limited without price discrimination. The ability of pharmaceutical companies to maintain price differences between countries is often either reinforced or hindered by national drugs laws and regulations, or the lack thereof.[61]

Even online sales for non material goods, which do not have to be shipped, may change according to the geographic location of the buyer, such as music streaming services by Spotify and Apple Music. The users in lower-income countries benefit from price discrimination by paying fewer subscription fees than those in higher-income countries. The researchers also found that the cross-national price differences actually raise the revenue of those companies by about 6% while reducing world users’ welfare by 1%.[62]

It's the example of the third-price discrimination.

Academic pricing

Companies will often offer discounted goods and software to students and faculty at school and university levels. These may be labeled as academic versions, but perform the same as the full price retail software. Some academic software may have differing licenses than retail versions, usually disallowing their use in activities for profit or expiring the license after a given number of months. This also has the characteristics of an "initial offer" - that is, the profits from an academic customer may come partly in the form of future non-academic sales due to vendor lock-in.

Sliding scale fees

Sliding scale fees are when different customers are charged different prices based on their income, which is used as a proxy for their willingness or ability to pay. For example, some nonprofit law firms charge on a sliding scale based on income and family size. Thus the clients paying a higher price at the top of the fee scale help subsidize the clients at the bottom of the scale. This differential pricing enables the nonprofit to serve a broader segment of the market than they could if they only set one price.[63]

Weddings

Goods and services for weddings are sometimes priced at a higher rate than identical goods for normal customers.[64][48][65] The wedding venues and services are usually priced differently depending on the wedding date. For instance, if the wedding is held during the peak seasons (school holidays or festive seasons), the price will be higher than in the off-season wedding months.

Obstetric service

The welfare consequences of price discrimination were assessed by testing the differences in mean prices paid by patients from three income groups: low, middle and high. The results suggest that two different forms of price discrimination for obstetric services occurred in both these hospitals. First, there was price discrimination according to income, with the poorer users benefiting from a higher discount rate than richer ones. Secondly, there was price discrimination according to social status, with three high status occupational groups (doctors, senior government officials, and large businessmen) having the highest probability of receiving some level of discount.[39]

Pharmaceutical industry

Price discrimination is common in the pharmaceutical industry. Drug-makers charge more for drugs in wealthier countries. For example, drug prices in the United States are some of the highest in the world. Europeans, on average, pay only 56% of what Americans pay for the same prescription drugs.[66]

Textbooks

Price discrimination is also prevalent within the textbook publishing industry. Prices for textbooks are much higher in the United States despite the fact that they are produced in the country. Copyright protection laws increase the price of textbooks. Also, textbooks are mandatory in the United States while schools in other countries see them as study aids.[67]

Two necessary conditions for price discrimination

There are two conditions that must be met if a price discrimination scheme is to work. First the firm must be able to identify market segments by their price elasticity of demand and second the firms must be able to enforce the scheme.[68] For example, airlines routinely engage in price discrimination by charging high prices for customers with relatively inelastic demand - business travelers - and discount prices for tourist who have relatively elastic demand. The airlines enforce the scheme by enforcing a no resale policy on the tickets preventing a tourist from buying a ticket at a discounted price and selling it to a business traveler (arbitrage). Airlines must also prevent business travelers from directly buying discount tickets. Airlines accomplish this by imposing advance ticketing requirements or minimum stay requirements — conditions that would be difficult for the average business traveler to meet.[69][70][66]

Concession and student discounts

Firms often use third degree price discrimination concession and student segments in the market. By offering a perceived discount to market segments which generally have less disposable income, and hence are more price sensitive, the firm is able to capture the revenue from those with higher price sensitivity whilst also charging higher prices and capturing the consumer surplus of the segments with less price sensitivity.[20][71]

Counterexamples

Some pricing patterns appear to be price discrimination but are not.

Congestion pricing

Price discrimination only happens when the same product is sold at more than one price. Congestion pricing is not price discrimination. Peak and off-peak fares on a train are not the same product; some people have to travel during rush hour, and travelling off-peak is not equivalent to them.

Some companies have high fixed costs (like a train company, which owns a railway and rolling stock, or a restaurant, which has to pay for premises and equipment). If these fixed costs permit the company to additionally provide less-preferred products (like mid-morning meals or off-peak rail travel) at little additional cost, it can profit both seller and buyer to offer them at lower prices. Providing more product from the same fixed costs increases both producer and consumer surplus. This is not technically price discrimination (unlike, say, giving menus with higher prices to richer-looking customers, which the poorer-looking ones get an ordinary menu).

If different prices are charged for products that only some consumers will see as equivalent, the differential pricing can be used to manage demand. For instance, airlines can use price discrimination to encourage people to travel at unpopular times (early in the morning). This helps avoid over-crowding and helps to spread out demand.[70] The airline gets better use out of planes and airports, and can thus charge less (or profit more) than if it only flew peak hours.

See also

References

  1. ^ Krugman, Paul R.; Maurice Obstfeld (2003). "Chapter 6: Economies of Scale, Imperfect Competition and International Trade". International Economics - Theory and Policy (6th ed.). p. 142.
  2. ^ a b c d Robert Phillips (2005). Pricing and Revenue Optimization. Stanford University Press. p. 74. ISBN 978-0-8047-4698-4.
  3. ^ a b c d Peter Belobaba; Amedeo Odoni; Cynthia Barnhart (2009). The Global Airline Industry. John Wiley & Sons. p. 77. ISBN 978-0-470-74472-7.
  4. ^ a b c Apollo, M. (2014). Dual Pricing–Two Points of View (Citizen and Non-citizen) Case of Entrance Fees in Tourist Facilities in Nepal. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences, 120, 414-422. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.sbspro.2014.02.119
  5. ^ Lott, John R.; Roberts, Russell D. (January 1991). "A Guide to the Pitfalls of Identifying Price Discrimination". Economic Inquiry. 29 (1): 14–23. doi:10.1111/j.1465-7295.1991.tb01249.x. ISSN 0095-2583.
  6. ^ Pettinger, Tejvan. "Price Discrimination". Economics Help. Retrieved 2023-04-21.
  7. ^ Tirole, Jean (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge.
  8. ^ William M. Pride; O. C. Ferrell (2011). Foundations of Marketing, 5th ed. Cengage Learning. p. 374. ISBN 978-1-111-58016-2.
  9. ^ Ruth Macklin (2004). Double Standards in Medical Research in Developing Countries. Cambridge University Press. p. 166. ISBN 978-0-521-54170-1.
  10. ^ Bernard M. Hoekman; Aaditya Mattoo; Philip English (2002). Development, Trade, and the WTO: A Handbook. World Bank Publications. p. 378. ISBN 978-0-8213-4997-7.
  11. ^ a b c d e Carl Shapiro; Hal Varian (1999). Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy. Harvard Business School Press. p. 39. ISBN 978-0-87584-863-1.
  12. ^ a b c Paul Belleflamme; Martin Peitz (2010). Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies. Cambridge University Press. p. 196. ISBN 978-0-521-86299-8.
  13. ^ a b Mance, Davor; Mance, Diana; Vitezić, Dinko (2019), "Personalized Medicine and Personalized Pricing: Degrees of Price Discrimination", Personalized Medicine in Healthcare Systems, Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 171–180, doi:10.1007/978-3-030-16465-2_14, ISBN 978-3-030-16464-5, S2CID 157911717, retrieved 2023-04-21
  14. ^ a b David K. Hayes; Allisha Miller (2011). Revenue Management for the Hospitality Industry. John Wiley and Sons. p. 115. ISBN 978-1-118-13692-8.
  15. ^ Robert Phillips (2005). Pricing and Revenue Optimization. Stanford University Press. pp. 82–83. ISBN 978-0-8047-4698-4.
  16. ^ Lynne Pepall; Dan Richards; George Norman (2011). Contemporary Industrial Organization: A Quantitative Approach. John Wiley and Sons. p. 87. ISBN 978-1-118-13898-4.
  17. ^ a b Robert Phillips (2005). Pricing and Revenue Optimization. Stanford University Press. p. 78. ISBN 978-0-8047-4698-4.
  18. ^ Robert Phillips (2005). Pricing and Revenue Optimization. Stanford University Press. p. 77. ISBN 978-0-8047-4698-4.
  19. ^ ("Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition", Lars A. Stole)
  20. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l Marburger, Daniel (2012-08-09). Innovative Pricing Strategies to Increase Profits. Business Expert Press. doi:10.4128/9781606493823. ISBN 978-1-60649-382-3.
  21. ^ a b Allingham, Michael (1991). Arbitrage : elements of financial economics. London. ISBN 978-1-349-21385-6. OCLC 1004672634.
  22. ^ a b c d e f Marshall, Alfred (2013). Principles of Economics. New York: PALGRAVE MACMILLAN. ISBN 9780230249271.
  23. ^ Bragg, Steven. "Rate fence definition". AccountingTools. Retrieved 2023-04-21.
  24. ^ Anderson, Eric T.; Dana, James D. (June 2009). "When Is Price Discrimination Profitable?". Management Science. 55 (6): 980–989. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1080.0979. hdl:10419/38645. ISSN 0025-1909.
  25. ^ "Monopoly and competition | Definition, Structures, Performance, & Facts | Britannica". www.britannica.com. Retrieved 2023-04-22.
  26. ^ "Market Power". Corporate Finance Institute. Retrieved 2023-04-22.
  27. ^ Dana, James; Williams, Kevin (February 2020). "Intertemporal Price Discrimination in Sequential Quantity-Price Games" (PDF). Cambridge, MA: w26794. doi:10.3386/w26794. S2CID 229171191. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  28. ^ a b Corts, Kenneth (1998). "Third-degree price discrimination in oligopoly: all-out competition and strategic commitment". The RAND Journal of Economics. 29 (2): 306–323. doi:10.2307/2555890. JSTOR 2555890 – via JSTOR.
  29. ^ Frank, Robert H. (2010): Microeconomics and Behavior, 8th Ed., McGraw-Hill Irwin, pp. 393-394.
  30. ^ Frank, Robert H. (2010): Microeconomics and Behavior, 8th Ed., McGraw-Hill Irwin, p. 395.
  31. ^ Lahiri, Atanu; Dewan, Rajiv M; Freimer, Marshall (2013). "Pricing of Wireless Services: Service Pricing vs. Traffic Pricing". Information Systems Research. 24 (2): 418–435. doi:10.1287/isre.1120.0434. JSTOR 42004312 – via JSTOR.
  32. ^ Emerson, Patrick M. (2019). "Pricing Strategies". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  33. ^ "8.4: Third-Degree Price Discrimination". Social Sci LibreTexts. 2020-03-17. Retrieved 2023-04-21.
  34. ^ Bergemann, Dirk; Brooks, Benjamin; Morris, Stephen (2015-03-01). "The Limits of Price Discrimination". American Economic Review. 105 (3): 921–957. doi:10.1257/aer.20130848. ISSN 0002-8282.
  35. ^ Hayes, Beth (1987). "Competition and Two-Part Tariffs". Journal of Business. 60 (1): 41–54. doi:10.1086/296384 – via University of Chicago Press.
  36. ^ "Is Ctrip reliable to book international flights? - Air Travel Forum - Tripadvisor". www.tripadvisor.com.au. Retrieved 2023-04-21.
  37. ^ Gomes, Renato; Pavan, Alessandro (September 2016). "Many-to-many matching and price discrimination: Many-to-many matching and price discrimination". Theoretical Economics. 11 (3): 1005–1052. doi:10.3982/TE1904.
  38. ^ Timothy J., Brennan (2010). "Decoupling in electric utilities". Journal of Regulatory Economics. 38: 38(1), 49–69. doi:10.1007/s11149-010-9120-5. S2CID 154139838.
  39. ^ a b Amin, Mohammad; Hanson, Kara; Mills, Anne (2004). "Price discrimination in obstetric services – a case study in Bangladesh". Health Economics. 13 (6): 597–604. doi:10.1002/hec.848. ISSN 1099-1050. PMID 15185389.
  40. ^ Pigou, A.C. (1929). Economics of Welfare (3 ed.). London: Macmillan.
  41. ^ a b Png, Ivan (1998). Managerial Economics (1 ed.). Malden, MA: Blackwell. pp. 301–315. ISBN 1-55786-927-8.
  42. ^ Jing, Bing (30 June 2016). "Behavior-Based Pricing, Production Efficiency, and Quality Differentiation". Management Science. 63 (7): 2365–2376. doi:10.1287/mnsc.2016.2463. ISSN 0025-1909.
  43. ^ Bonatti, Alessandro; Cisternas, Gonzalo (2020-03-01). "Consumer Scores and Price Discrimination". The Review of Economic Studies. 87 (2): 750–791. doi:10.1093/restud/rdz046. hdl:1721.1/129703. ISSN 0034-6527.
  44. ^ Stavins, Joanna (2001-02-01). "Price Discrimination in the Airline Market: The Effect of Market Concentration". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 83 (1): 200–202. doi:10.1162/rest.2001.83.1.200. ISSN 0034-6535. S2CID 15287234.
  45. ^ Dana Jr., J.D. (1998-04-01). "Advance-Purchase Discounts and Price Discrimination in Competitive Markets". Journal of Political Economy. 106 (2): 395–422. doi:10.1086/250014. ISSN 0022-3808. S2CID 222454180.
  46. ^ Puller, Steven L.; Taylor, Lisa M. (2012-12-01). "Price discrimination by day-of-week of purchase: Evidence from the U.S. airline industry". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 84 (3): 801–812. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2012.09.022. ISSN 0167-2681.
  47. ^ Luttmann, Alexander (2019-01-01). "Evidence of directional price discrimination in the U.S. airline industry". International Journal of Industrial Organization. 62: 291–329. doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2018.03.013. ISSN 0167-7187. S2CID 158868627.
  48. ^ a b Rampell, Catherine (3 December 2013). "The Wedding Fix Is In". The New York Times. Retrieved 29 March 2017.
  49. ^ karenbryson (19 February 2015). "The "White Man's" Tax". Retrieved 29 March 2017.
  50. ^ thebeijinger (18 June 2014). "Beijing's 'White Man Tax' Pegged at a Median 16% in Unscientific Survey". Retrieved 29 March 2017.
  51. ^ "Bumiputera discount: A sensitive topic that must be addressed". 6 August 2013. Retrieved 29 March 2017.
  52. ^ See generally PRICE DISCRIMINATION, Black's Law Dictionary (10th ed. 2014).
  53. ^ See, e.g.., Civil Rights--Gender Discrimination--California Prohibits Gender-Based Pricing--Cal. Civ. Code. § 51.6 (West Supp. 1996), 109 HARV. L. REV. 1839, 1839 (1996) (“Differential pricing of services is one of America's last remaining vestiges of formal gender-based discrimination.”); Joyce McClements and Cheryl Thomas, Public Accommodations Statutes: Is Ladies' Night Out?, 37 MERCER L. REV. 1605, 1618 (1986); Heidi Paulson, Ladies' Night Discounts: Should We Bar Them or Promote Them?, 32 B.C. L. Rev. 487, 528 (1991) (arguing that ladies' night promotions encourage paternalistic attitudes toward women and encourage stereotypes of both men and women).
  54. ^ a b Bessendorf, Anna (December 2015). "From Cradle to Cane: The Cost of Being a Female Consumer" (PDF). New York City Department of Consumer Affairs. Retrieved August 25, 2018.
  55. ^ a b California State Senate, Gender Tax Repeal Act of 1995, AB 1100 (Aug. 31, 1995).
  56. ^ Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, Pub. L. No. 111-148, 124 Stat. 119 (2010) (to be codified in scattered titles and sections)[hereinafter Affordable Care Act].
  57. ^ Affordable Care Act § 2701, 124 Stat. 119, 37-38
  58. ^ Danielle Paquette, Why you should always buy the men's version of almost anything, The Washington Post (December 22, 2015), https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2015/12/22/women-really-do-pay-more-for-razors-and-almost-everything-else/. 2016-03-16 at the Wayback Machine
  59. ^ Collinson, Patrick (14 January 2017). "EU's gender ruling on car insurance has made inequality worse". the Guardian.
  60. ^ Chen, Li-Zhong; Hu, Wei-Min; Szulga, Radek; Zhou, Xiaolan (2018-02-01). "Demographics, gender and local knowledge-Price discrimination in China's car market". Economics Letters. 163: 172–174. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2017.11.026. ISSN 0165-1765.
  61. ^ Pogge, Thomas (2008). World poverty and human rights : cosmopolitan responsibilities and reforms (PDF) (2. ed.). Cambridge [u.a.]: Polity Press. ISBN 978-0745641447.
  62. ^ Waldfogel, Joel (2020-06-01). "The Welfare Effects of Spotify's Cross-Country Price Discrimination". Review of Industrial Organization. 56 (4): 593–613. doi:10.1007/s11151-020-09748-0. ISSN 1573-7160. S2CID 212834250.
  63. ^ Zuckerman, Michael (August 7, 2014). "The Utah Lawyers Who Are Making Legal Services Affordable". The Atlantic. Retrieved 4 December 2014.
  64. ^ Dubner, Stephen J. (3 October 2011). "Getting Married? Then Get Ready for Price Discrimination". Retrieved 29 March 2017.
  65. ^ "Wedding costs - Shopping for special occasions". 7 January 2015. Retrieved 29 March 2017.
  66. ^ a b DANZON, PATRICIA M. (1 November 1997). "Price Discrimination for Pharmaceuticals: Welfare Effects in the US and the EU". International Journal of the Economics of Business. 4 (3): 301–322. doi:10.1080/758523212. ISSN 1357-1516.
  67. ^ Cabolis, Christos, Clerides, Sofronis, Ioannou, Ioannis, & Senft, Daniel. (1 April 2007). "A textbook example of international price discrimination". Economics Letters. 95 (1): 91–95. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2006.09.019. ISSN 0165-1765. S2CID 40568157.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  68. ^ Samuelson & Marks, Managerial Economics 4th ed. (Wiley 2003)
  69. ^ Samuelson & Marks, Managerial Economics 4th ed. (Wiley 2003) Airlines typically attempt to maximize revenue rather than profits because airlines variable costs are small. Thus airlines use pricing strategies designed to fill seats rather than equate marginal revenue and marginal costs.
  70. ^ a b Xu, Man; Tang, Wansheng; Zhou, Chi (1 February 2020). "Price discrimination based on purchase behavior and service cost in competitive channels". Soft Computing. 24 (4): 2567–2588. doi:10.1007/s00500-019-03760-7. ISSN 1433-7479. S2CID 67905768.
  71. ^ "How Do Companies Use Price Discrimination?". Investopedia. Retrieved 2023-04-21.
Cite error: A list-defined reference named "Brennan" is not used in the content (see the help page).
  • Geradin, Damien; Petit, Nicolas (1 September 2006). "Price Discrimination Under Ec Competition Law: Another Antitrust Doctrine in Search of Limiting Principles?". Journal of Competition Law & Economics. 2 (3): 479–531. doi:10.1093/joclec/nhl013. ISSN 1744-6422.
  • Amin, Mohammad; Hanson, Kara; Mills, Anne (2004). "Price discrimination in obstetric services – a case study in Bangladesh". Health Economics. 13 (6): 597–604. doi:10.1002/hec.848. ISSN 1099-1050. PMID 15185389.

External links

  • Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition Lars Stole
  • Hal Varian.
  • Price Discrimination for Digital Goods Arun Sundararajan.
  • Price Discrimination Discussion piece from The Filter
  • Joelonsoftware's blog entry on Price Discrimination
  • Taken to the Cleaners? Steven Landsburg's explanation of Dry Cleaner pricing.

price, discrimination, confused, with, congestion, pricing, microeconomic, pricing, strategy, where, identical, largely, similar, goods, services, sold, different, prices, same, provider, different, market, segments, distinguished, from, product, differentiati. Not to be confused with Congestion pricing Price discrimination is a microeconomic pricing strategy where identical or largely similar goods or services are sold at different prices by the same provider in different market segments 1 2 3 Price discrimination is distinguished from product differentiation by the more substantial difference in production cost for the differently priced products involved in the latter strategy 3 Price differentiation essentially relies on the variation in the customers willingness to pay 2 3 4 and in the elasticity of their demand For price discrimination to succeed a firm must have market power such as a dominant market share product uniqueness sole pricing power etc 5 All prices under price discrimination are higher than the equilibrium price in a perfectly competitive market However some prices under price discrimination may be lower than the price charged by a single price monopolist Price discrimination is utilised by the monopolist to recapture some deadweight loss 6 This Pricing strategy enables firms to capture additional consumer surplus and maximize their profits while benefiting some consumers at lower prices Price discrimination can take many forms and is prevalent in many industries from education and telecommunications to healthcare 7 Student discounts which participating businesses offer to individuals enrolled as full time postsecondary students and who possess valid student identification like this student discount card are a common example of price discrimination The term differential pricing is also used to describe the practice of charging different prices to different buyers for the same quality and quantity of a product 8 but it can also refer to a combination of price differentiation and product differentiation 3 Other terms used to refer to price discrimination include equity pricing preferential pricing 9 dual pricing 4 and tiered pricing 10 Within the broader domain of price differentiation a commonly accepted classification dating to the 1920s is 11 12 Personalized pricing or first degree price differentiation selling to each customer at a different price this is also called one to one marketing 11 The optimal incarnation of this is called perfect price discrimination and maximizes the price that each customer is willing to pay 11 As such in first degree price differentiation the entire consumer surplus is captured for each individual 13 Product versioning 2 14 or simply versioning or second degree price differentiation offering a product line 11 by creating slightly differentiated products for the purpose of price differentiation 2 14 i e a vertical product line 15 Another name given to versioning is menu pricing 12 16 Group pricing or third degree price differentiation dividing the market into segments and charging a different price to each segment but the same price to each member of that segment 11 17 This is essentially a heuristic approximation that simplifies the problem in face of the difficulties with personalized pricing 12 18 Typical examples include student discounts 17 and seniors discounts Contents 1 Theoretical basis 2 Price discrimination and market power 2 1 Degrees of market power 2 2 Price discrimination in oligopolies 3 Types of Price Discrimination 3 1 First degree Perfect price discrimination 3 2 Second degree Quantity discount 3 3 Third degree Market Segregation 3 4 Two part tariff 3 5 Combination 3 6 User controlled price discrimination 4 Modern taxonomy 4 1 Complete discrimination 4 2 Direct segmentation 4 3 Indirect segmentation 4 4 Uniform pricing 5 Explanation 6 Advantages and disadvantages of price discrimination 6 1 Advantages of price discrimination 6 2 Disadvantages of price discrimination 7 Examples 7 1 Retail price discrimination 7 2 Travel industry 7 3 Coupons 7 4 Premium pricing 7 5 Segmentation by age group student status ethnicity and citizenship 7 6 Discounts for members of certain occupations 7 7 Incentives for industrial buyers 7 8 Gender based examples 7 9 International price discrimination 7 10 Academic pricing 7 11 Sliding scale fees 7 12 Weddings 7 13 Obstetric service 7 14 Pharmaceutical industry 7 15 Textbooks 7 16 Two necessary conditions for price discrimination 7 17 Concession and student discounts 7 18 Counterexamples 7 18 1 Congestion pricing 8 See also 9 References 10 External linksTheoretical basis EditIn a theoretical market with perfect information perfect substitutes and no transaction costs or prohibition on secondary exchange or re selling to prevent arbitrage price discrimination can only be a feature of monopoly and oligopoly markets 19 where market power can be exercised see Price discrimination and monopoly power below for more in depth explanation Without market power when the price is differentiated higher than the market equilibrium consumers will move to buy from other producers selling at the market equilibrium 20 Moreover when the seller tries to sell the same good at differentiating prices the buyer at the lower price can arbitrage by selling to the consumer buying at the higher price with a small discount from the higher price 21 Price discrimination requires market segmentation and some means to discourage discount customers from becoming resellers and by extension competitors 22 This usually entails using one or more means of preventing any resale keeping the different price groups separate making price comparisons difficult or restricting pricing information 21 The boundary set up by the marketer to keep segments separate is referred to as a rate fence a rule that allow consumers to segment themselves into based on their needs behaviour and willingness to pay 23 Price discrimination is thus very common in services where resale is not possible an example is student discounts at museums In theory students for their condition as students may get lower prices than the rest of the population for a certain product or service and later will not become resellers since what they received may only be used or consumed by them because it is required to show their student identification card when making the purchase Another example of price discrimination is intellectual property enforced by law and by technology In the market for DVDs laws require DVD players to be designed and produced with hardware or software that prevents inexpensive copying or playing of content purchased legally elsewhere in the world at a lower price In the US the Digital Millennium Copyright Act has provisions to outlaw circumventing of such devices to protect the enhanced monopoly profits that copyright holders can obtain from price discrimination against higher price market segments Price discrimination differentiates the willingness to pay of the customers in order to eliminate as much consumer surplus as possible By understanding the elasticity of the customer s demand a business could use its market power to identify the customers willingness to pay 20 Different people would pay a different price for the same product when price discrimination exists in the market When a company recognized a consumer that has a lower willingness to pay the company could use the price discrimination strategy in order to maximized the firm s profit 24 Price discrimination and market power EditDegrees of market power Edit Market Power refers to the ability of a firm to manipulate the price without losing shares sales in the market 22 Some factors which affect the market power of a firm are listed below 25 Number of competitors in the market Product differentiation between competitors Entry restrictionsThe degree of market power can usually be divided into 4 categories listed in the table below in order of increasing market power 22 26 Type of Market Features Industry ExamplesPerfect Competition High competitor volume Homogenous goods and services No entry restrictions Farmers selling vegetables at a marketMonopolistic Competition Moderate competitor volume Differentiated product Low entry restrictions Fast food industryOligopoly Small competitor volume Some product differentiation Difficult entry Airline industryMonopoly Sole producer No substitutes Impossible entry i e patents contracts which prevent entry Water Utility Company servicing the regionSince price discrimination is dependant on a firms market power generally monopolies use price discrimination however oligopolies can also use price discrimination when the risk of arbitrage and consumers moving to other competitors is low 20 Price discrimination in oligopolies Edit An oligopoly forms when a small group of business dominates an industry When the dominating companies in an oligopoly model compete in prices the motive for inter temporal price discrimination would appear in the oligopoly market Price discrimination can be facilitated by inventory controls in oligopoly 27 Whilst oligopolies hold more market power than perfectly competitive markets the use of price discrimination can lead to lower profits for oligopolies as they compete to hold greater shares of the market by lowering prices 28 For instance when Oligopolies use third degree price discrimination to offer a lower price to consumers with high price elasticity lower disposable income they compete with other firms to capture the market until a lower profit is retained 28 Hence Oligopolies may be dissuaded from using price discrimination Types of Price Discrimination EditFirst degree Perfect price discrimination Edit Exercising first degree or perfect or primary price discrimination requires the monopoly seller of a good or service to know the absolute maximum price or reservation price that every consumer is willing to pay By knowing the reservation price the seller is able to sell the good or service to each consumer at the maximum price they are willing to pay granted it is greater or equal to the marginal cost and thus transform the consumer surplus into seller revenue 13 Resultantly the profit is equal to the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus 20 First degree price discrimination is the most profitable as it obtains all of the consumer surplus and each consumer buys the good at the highest price they are willing to pay 20 The marginal consumer is the one whose reservation price equals the marginal cost of the product meaning that the social surplus is entirely from producer surplus no consumer surplus If the seller engages in first degree price discrimination then they will produce more product than they would with no price discrimination Hence first degree price discrimination can eliminate deadweight loss that occurs in monopolistic markets 20 Examples of first degree price discrimination can be observed in markets where consumers bid for tenders though in this case the practice of collusive tendering could reduce the market efficiency 29 Second degree Quantity discount Edit In second degree price discrimination price of the same good varies according to quantity demanded It usually comes in the form of quantity discount which recognises of the law of diminishing marginal utility The Law of diminishing marginal utility stipulates that a consumers utility may decrease diminish with each successive unit 22 For example the marginal utility received from enjoying a ride at a theme park may gradually diminish after each time you go on the same ride By offering a quantity discount for a larger quantity purchased the seller is able to capture some of the consumer surplus but not all 20 This is because diminishing marginal utility may mean the consumer would not be willing to purchase an additional unit without a discount since the marginal utility received from the good or service is no longer greater than price 22 However by offering a discount the seller can capture some of consumers surplus by encouraging them to purchase an additional unit at a discounted price 20 This is particularly widespread in sales to industrial customers where bulk buyers enjoy discounts 30 Mobile phone plans and different subscriptions are often other instances of second degree price discrimination Consumers will usually believe a one year subscription is more cost effective than a monthly one Whether or not consumers actually need such a long time subscription they are more likely to accept and pay the cost effective one 31 Besides the producer will consequently see an increase in sales and profit Second price discrimination also known as non linear pricing benefits consumers by allowing them to purchase at a cheaper price when they buy more instead of at the normal price 32 Third degree Market Segregation Edit Third degree price discrimination means charging a different price to a group of consumers based on their different elasticities of demand and the group with less elastic always be charged a higher price 20 For example rail and tube subway travelers can be subdivided into commuters and casual travelers and cinema goers can be subdivided into adults and children with some theatres also offering discounts to full time students and seniors Splitting the market into peak and off peak use of service is very common and occurs with gas electricity and telephone supply as well as gym membership and parking charges 33 In order to offer different prices for different groups of people in the aggregate market the business has to use additional information to identify its consumers It is crucial for the business to set prices according to the consumers willingness to buy Consequently they will be involved in third degree price discrimination 34 With third degree price discrimination the firms try to generate sales by identifying different market segments such as domestic and industrial users with different price elasticities 20 Markets must be kept separate by time physical distance and nature of use For example Microsoft Office Schools edition is available for a lower price to educational institutions than to other users The markets cannot overlap so that consumers who purchase at a lower price in the elastic sub market could resell at a higher price in the inelastic sub market Two part tariff Edit The two part tariff is another form of price discrimination where the producer charges an initial fee and a secondary fee for the use of the product This pricing strategy yields a result similar to second degree price discrimination In addition the two part tariff is desirable for welfare because the monopolistic markup can be eliminated However an upstream monopolist has the authority to set higher unit wholesale prices to the downstream firms in discriminatory two part tariff which is different from uniform two part tariff pricing As a result the discriminatory two part tariff for wholesale prices can harm social welfare An example of two part tariff pricing is in the market for shaving razors 35 The customer pays an initial cost for the razor and then pays again for the replacement blades This pricing strategy works because it shifts the demand curve to the right since the customer has already paid for the initial blade holder and will continue to buy the blades which are cheaper than buying disposable razors Combination Edit These types are not mutually exclusive Thus a company may vary pricing by location but then offer bulk discounts as well Airlines use several different types of price discrimination including Bulk discounts to wholesalers consolidators and tour operators Incentive discounts for higher sales volumes to travel agents and corporate buyers Seasonal discounts incentive discounts and even general prices that vary by location The price of a flight from say Singapore to Beijing can vary widely if one buys the ticket in Singapore compared to Beijing or New York or Tokyo or elsewhere Discounted tickets requiring advance purchase and or Saturday stays Both restrictions have the effect of excluding business travelers who typically travel during the workweek and arrange trips on shorter notice First degree price discrimination based on customer Hotel or car rental firms may quote higher prices to their loyalty program s top tier members than to the general public 36 User controlled price discrimination Edit While the conventional theory of price discrimination generally assumes that prices are set by the seller there is a variant form in which prices are set by the buyer such as in the form of pay what you want pricing Such user controlled price discrimination exploits similar ability to adapt to varying demand curves or individual price sensitivities and may avoid the negative perceptions of price discrimination as imposed by a seller In the matching markets the platforms will internalize the impacts in revenue to create a cross side effects In return this cross side effect will differentiate price discrimination in matching intermediation from the standard markets 37 38 39 Modern taxonomy EditThe first second third degree taxonomy of price discrimination is due to Pigou Economics of Welfare 3rd edition 1929 40 However these categories are not mutually exclusive or exhaustive Ivan Png Managerial Economics 1998 301 315 suggests an alternative taxonomy 41 Complete discrimination Edit where the seller prices each unit at a different price so that each user purchases up to the point where the user s marginal benefit equals the marginal cost of the item Direct segmentation Edit where the seller can condition price on some attribute like age or gender that directly segments the buyers Indirect segmentation Edit where the seller relies on some proxy e g package size usage quantity coupon to structure a choice that indirectly segments the buyers Uniform pricing Edit where the seller sets the same price for each unit of the product The hierarchy complete direct indirect uniform pricing is in decreasing order of profitability and information requirement 41 Complete price discrimination is most profitable and requires the seller to have the most information about buyers Next most profitable and in information requirement is direct segmentation followed by indirect segmentation Finally uniform pricing is the least profitable and requires the seller to have the least information about buyers is Explanation Edit Sales revenue without and with Price Discrimination The purpose of price discrimination is generally to capture the market s consumer surplus This surplus arises because in a market with a single clearing price some customers the very low price elasticity segment would have been prepared to pay more than the market price Price discrimination transfers some of this surplus from the consumer to the seller 20 It is a way of increasing monopoly profit In a perfectly competitive market manufacturers make normal profit but not monopoly profit so they cannot engage in price discrimination 22 It can be argued that strictly a consumer surplus need not exist for example where fixed costs or economies of scale mean that the marginal cost of adding more consumers is less than the marginal profit from selling more product This means that charging some consumers less than an even share of costs can be beneficial An example is a high speed internet connection shared by two consumers in a single building if one is willing to pay less than half the cost of connecting the building and the other willing to make up the rest but not to pay the entire cost then price discrimination can allow the purchase to take place However this will cost the consumers as much or more than if they pooled their money to pay a non discriminating price If the consumer is considered to be the building then a consumer surplus goes to the inhabitants It can be proved mathematically that a firm facing a downward sloping demand curve that is convex to the origin will always obtain higher revenues under price discrimination than under a single price strategy This can also be shown geometrically In the top diagram a single price P displaystyle P is available to all customers The amount of revenue is represented by area P A Q O displaystyle P A Q O The consumer surplus is the area above line segment P A displaystyle P A but below the demand curve D displaystyle D With price discrimination the bottom diagram the demand curve is divided into two segments D 1 displaystyle D1 and D 2 displaystyle D2 A higher price P 1 displaystyle P1 is charged to the low elasticity segment and a lower price P 2 displaystyle P2 is charged to the high elasticity segment The total revenue from the first segment is equal to the area P 1 B Q 1 O displaystyle P1 B Q1 O The total revenue from the second segment is equal to the area E C Q 2 Q 1 displaystyle E C Q2 Q1 The sum of these areas will always be greater than the area without discrimination assuming the demand curve resembles a rectangular hyperbola with unitary elasticity The more prices that are introduced the greater the sum of the revenue areas and the more of the consumer surplus is captured by the producer The above requires both first and second degree price discrimination the right segment corresponds partly to different people than the left segment partly to the same people willing to buy more if the product is cheaper It is very useful for the price discriminator to determine the optimum prices in each market segment This is done in the next diagram where each segment is considered as a separate market with its own demand curve As usual the profit maximizing output Qt is determined by the intersection of the marginal cost curve MC with the marginal revenue curve for the total market MRt Multiple Market Price Determination splitting the demand line where it bends bend right split left and center The firm decides what amount of the total output to sell in each market by looking at the intersection of marginal cost with marginal revenue profit maximization This output is then divided between the two markets at the equilibrium marginal revenue level Therefore the optimum outputs are Q a displaystyle Q a and Q b displaystyle Q b From the demand curve in each market the profit can be determined maximizing prices of P a displaystyle P a and P b displaystyle P b The marginal revenue in both markets at the optimal output levels must be equal otherwise the firm could profit from transferring output over to whichever market is offering higher marginal revenue Given that Market 1 has a price elasticity of demand of E 1 displaystyle E 1 and Market 2 of E 2 displaystyle E 2 the optimal pricing ration in Market 1 versus Market 2 is P 1 P 2 1 1 E 2 1 1 E 1 displaystyle P 1 P 2 1 1 E 2 1 1 E 1 The price in a perfectly competitive market will always be lower than any price under price discrimination including in special cases like the internet connection example above assuming that the perfectly competitive market allows consumers to pool their resources In a market with perfect competition no price discrimination is possible and the average total cost ATC curve will be identical to the marginal cost curve MC The price will be the intersection of this ATC MC curve and the demand line Dt The consumer thus buys the product at the cheapest price at which any manufacturer can produce any quantity Price discrimination is a sign that the market is imperfect the seller has some monopoly power and that prices and seller profits are higher than they would be in a perfectly competitive market Advantages and disadvantages of price discrimination EditAdvantages of price discrimination Edit Firms that hold some monopolistic or oliogopolistic power will be able to increase their revenue In theory they might also use the money for investment which benefit consumers like research and development though this is more common in a competitive market where innovation brings temporary market power Lower prices for some than in a one price monopoly Even the lowest discounted prices will be higher than the price in a competitive market which is equal to the cost of production For example trains tend to be near monopolies see natural monopoly So old people may get lower train fares than they would if everyone got the same price because the train company knows that old people are more likely to be poor Also customers willing to spend time in researching special offers get lower prices their effort acts as an honest signal of their price sensitivity by reducing their consumer surplus by the value of the time spent hunting True price discrimination occurs when exactly the same product is sold at multiple prices It benefits only the seller compared to a competitive market It benefits some buyers at a greater cost to others causing a net loss to consumers compared to a single price monopoly For congestion pricing which can benefit the buyer and is not price discrimination see counterexamples below Disadvantages of price discrimination Edit Higher prices Under price discrimination all consumers will pay higher prices than they would in a competitive market Some consumers will end up paying higher prices than they would in a single price monopoly These higher prices are likely to be allocatively inefficient because P MC Decline in consumer surplus Price discrimination enables a transfer of money from consumers to firms increasing wealth inequality Potentially unfair Those who pay higher prices may not be the richest For example adults paying full price could be unemployed senior citizens can be very well off Administration costs There will be administration costs in separating the markets which could lead to higher prices Predatory pricing Profits from price discrimination could be used to finance predatory pricing 42 Predatory pricing can be used to maintain the monopolistic power needed to price discriminate Examples EditRetail price discrimination Edit Manufacturers may sell their products to similarly situated retailers at different prices based solely on the volume of products purchased Sometimes the firm investigate the consumers purchase histories which would show the customer s unobserved willingness to pay Each customer has a purchasing score which indicates his or her preferences consequently the firm will be able to set the price for the individual customer at the point that minimizes the consumer surplus Oftentimes consumers are not aware of the ways to manipulate that score If he or she wants to do to so he or she could reduce the demand to reduce the average equilibrium price which will reduce the firm s price discriminating strategy 43 It s an instance of third degree price discrimination Travel industry Edit Airlines and other travel companies use differentiated pricing regularly as they sell travel products and services simultaneously to different market segments This is often done by assigning capacity to various booking classes which sell for different prices and which may be linked to fare restrictions The restrictions or fences help ensure that market segments buy in the booking class range that has been established for them For example schedule sensitive business passengers who are willing to pay 300 for a seat from city A to city B cannot purchase a 150 ticket because the 150 booking class contains a requirement for a Saturday night stay or a 15 day advance purchase or another fare rule that discourages minimizes or effectively prevents a sale to business passengers 44 Notice however that in this example the seat is not always the same product That is the business person who purchases the 300 ticket may be willing to do so in return for a seat on a high demand morning flight for full refundability if the ticket is not used and for the ability to upgrade to first class if space is available for a nominal fee On the same flight are price sensitive passengers who are not willing to pay 300 but who are willing to fly on a lower demand flight one leaving an hour earlier or via a connection city not a non stop flight and who are willing to forgo refundability On the other hand an airline may also apply differential pricing to the same seat over time e g by discounting the price for an early or late booking and for weekend purchases without changing any other fare condition It is part of an airline s profit maximizing strategy by segmenting price sensitive leisure travellers from price inelastic business travellers as the former often have an incentive to buy in advance and often purchase on weekends 45 46 This could present an arbitrage opportunity in the absence of any restriction on reselling However passenger name changes are typically prevented or financially penalized by contract In addition an airline may apply directional price discrimination by charging passengers different roundtrip fares based on their origins For example the per capita income of City A is 30 000 higher than City B and the finding implies that passengers originating from City A will pay 5400 12900 more than those from City B It is argued that this price discrimination method is the result of airlines segmenting passenger price sensitivity based on their income of route endpoints 47 Since airlines often fly multi leg flights and since no show rates vary by segment competition for the seat has to take in the spatial dynamics of the product Someone trying to fly A B is competing with people trying to fly A C through city B on the same aircraft This is one reason airlines use yield management technology to determine how many seats to allot for A B passengers B C passengers and A B C passengers at their varying fares and with varying demands and no show rates With the rise of the Internet and the growth of low fare airlines airfare pricing transparency has become far more pronounced Passengers discovered it is quite easy to compare fares across different flights or different airlines This helped put pressure on airlines to lower fares Meanwhile in the recession following the September 11 2001 attacks on the U S business travelers and corporate buyers made it clear to airlines that they were not going to be buying air travel at rates high enough to subsidize lower fares for non business travelers This prediction has come true as vast numbers of business travelers are buying airfares only in economy class for business travel Mean while there are sometimes group discounts on rail tickets and passes second degree price discrimination Coupons Edit The use of coupons in retail is an attempt to distinguish customers by their reserve price The assumption is that people who go through the trouble of collecting coupons have greater price sensitivity than those who do not Thus making coupons available enables for instance breakfast cereal makers to charge higher prices to price insensitive customers while still making some profit off customers who are more price sensitive Another example can also be seen in how to collect grocery store coupons before the existence of digital coupons Grocery store coupons were usually available in the free newspapers or magazines placed at the entrance of the stores As coupons have a negative relationship with time customers with a high value of time will not find it worthwhile to spend 20 minutes in order to save 5 only Meanwhile customers with a low value of time will be satisfied by getting 5 less from their purchase as they tend to be more price sensitive 48 It s an instance of third degree price discrimination Premium pricing Edit For certain products premium products are priced at a level compared to regular or economy products that is well beyond their marginal cost of production For example a coffee chain may price regular coffee at 1 but premium coffee at 2 50 where the respective costs of production may be 0 90 and 1 25 Economists such as Tim Harford in the Undercover Economist have argued that this is a form of price discrimination by providing a choice between a regular and premium product consumers are being asked to reveal their degree of price sensitivity or willingness to pay for comparable products Similar techniques are used in pricing business class airline tickets and premium alcoholic drinks for example They are examples of the third degree price discrimination This effect can lead to seemingly perverse incentives for the producer If for example potential business class customers will pay a large price differential only if economy class seats are uncomfortable while economy class customers are more sensitive to price than comfort airlines may have substantial incentives to purposely make economy seating uncomfortable In the example of coffee a restaurant may gain more economic profit by making poor quality regular coffee more profit is gained from up selling to premium customers than is lost from customers who refuse to purchase inexpensive but poor quality coffee In such cases the net social utility should also account for the lost utility to consumers of the regular product although determining the magnitude of this foregone utility may not be feasible Segmentation by age group student status ethnicity and citizenship Edit Many movie theaters amusement parks tourist attractions and other places have different admission prices per market segment typical groupings are Youth Child Student Adult Senior Citizen Local and Foreigner Each of these groups typically have a much different demand curve Children people living on student wages and people living on retirement generally have much less disposable income Foreigners may be perceived as being more wealthy than locals and therefore being capable of paying more for goods and services sometimes this can be even 35 times as much 4 Market stall holders and individual public transport providers may also insist on higher prices for their goods and services when dealing with foreigners sometimes called the White Man Tax 49 50 Some goods such as housing may be offered at cheaper prices for certain ethnic groups 51 Besides public transport fare is also an example of price discrimination Kids senior citizens and students are eligible to receive concessions for their public transport fare In Queensland for example these three groups of people get to use public transport by paying only half of the actual price Thus other public transport users may find it not fair for them to pay less for the same service It s the example of the third price discrimination Discounts for members of certain occupations Edit Some businesses may offer reduced prices members of some occupations such as school teachers see below police and military personnel In addition to increased sales to the target group businesses benefit from the resulting positive publicity leading to increased sales to the general public Incentives for industrial buyers Edit Many methods exist to incentivize wholesale or industrial buyers These may be quite targeted as they are designed to generate specific activity such as buying more frequently buying more regularly buying in bigger quantities buying new products with established ones and so on They may also be designed to reduce the administrative and finance costs of processing each transaction Thus there are bulk discounts special pricing for long term commitments non peak discounts discounts on high demand goods to incentivize buying lower demand goods rebates and many others This can help the relations between the firms involved It s the example of the second price discrimination Gender based examples Edit Main article Gender based price discrimination in the United States Gender based price discrimination is the practice of offering identical or similar services and products to men and women at different prices when the cost of producing the products and services is the same 52 In the United States gender based price discrimination has been a source of debate 53 In 1992 the New York City Department of Consumer Affairs DCA conducted an investigation of price bias against women in the marketplace 54 The DCA s investigation concluded that women paid more than men at used car dealers dry cleaners and hair salons 54 The DCA s research on gender pricing in New York City brought national attention to gender based price discrimination and the financial impact it has on women With consumer products differential pricing is usually not based explicitly on the actual gender of the purchaser but is achieved implicitly by the use of differential packaging labelling or colour schemes designed to appeal to male or female consumers In many cases where the product is marketed to make an attractive gift the gender of the purchaser may be different from that of the end user In 1995 California Assembly s Office of Research studied the issue of gender based price discrimination of services and estimated that women effectively paid an annual gender tax of approximately 1 351 00 for the same services as men 55 It was also estimated that women over the course of their lives spend thousands of dollars more than men to purchase similar products 55 For example prior to the enactment of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act 56 Affordable Care Act health insurance companies charged women higher premiums for individual health insurance policies than men Under the Affordable Care Act health insurance companies are now required to offer the same premium price to all applicants of the same age and geographical locale without regard to gender 57 However there is no federal law banning gender based price discrimination in the sale of products 58 Instead several cities and states have passed legislation prohibiting gender based price discrimination on products and services In Europe motor insurance premiums have historically been higher for men than for women a practice that the insurance industry attempts to justify on the basis of different levels of risk The EU has banned this practice however there is evidence that it is being replaced by proxy discrimination that is discrimination on the basis of factors that are strongly correlated with gender for example charging construction workers more than midwives 59 In Chinese retail automobile market researchers found that male buyers pay less than female buyers for cars with the same characteristics Although this research documented the existence of price discrimination between locals and non locals local men still receive 221 63 discount more than local women and non local men receive 330 19 discount more than non local women The discount represents approximately 10 of average personal budget considering the per capita GDP for 2018 60 International price discrimination Edit Pharmaceutical companies may charge customers living in wealthier countries a much higher price than for identical drugs in poorer nations as is the case with the sale of antiretroviral drugs in Africa Since the purchasing power of African consumers is much lower sales would be extremely limited without price discrimination The ability of pharmaceutical companies to maintain price differences between countries is often either reinforced or hindered by national drugs laws and regulations or the lack thereof 61 Even online sales for non material goods which do not have to be shipped may change according to the geographic location of the buyer such as music streaming services by Spotify and Apple Music The users in lower income countries benefit from price discrimination by paying fewer subscription fees than those in higher income countries The researchers also found that the cross national price differences actually raise the revenue of those companies by about 6 while reducing world users welfare by 1 62 It s the example of the third price discrimination Academic pricing Edit Companies will often offer discounted goods and software to students and faculty at school and university levels These may be labeled as academic versions but perform the same as the full price retail software Some academic software may have differing licenses than retail versions usually disallowing their use in activities for profit or expiring the license after a given number of months This also has the characteristics of an initial offer that is the profits from an academic customer may come partly in the form of future non academic sales due to vendor lock in Sliding scale fees Edit Sliding scale fees are when different customers are charged different prices based on their income which is used as a proxy for their willingness or ability to pay For example some nonprofit law firms charge on a sliding scale based on income and family size Thus the clients paying a higher price at the top of the fee scale help subsidize the clients at the bottom of the scale This differential pricing enables the nonprofit to serve a broader segment of the market than they could if they only set one price 63 Weddings Edit Goods and services for weddings are sometimes priced at a higher rate than identical goods for normal customers 64 48 65 The wedding venues and services are usually priced differently depending on the wedding date For instance if the wedding is held during the peak seasons school holidays or festive seasons the price will be higher than in the off season wedding months Obstetric service Edit The welfare consequences of price discrimination were assessed by testing the differences in mean prices paid by patients from three income groups low middle and high The results suggest that two different forms of price discrimination for obstetric services occurred in both these hospitals First there was price discrimination according to income with the poorer users benefiting from a higher discount rate than richer ones Secondly there was price discrimination according to social status with three high status occupational groups doctors senior government officials and large businessmen having the highest probability of receiving some level of discount 39 Pharmaceutical industry Edit Price discrimination is common in the pharmaceutical industry Drug makers charge more for drugs in wealthier countries For example drug prices in the United States are some of the highest in the world Europeans on average pay only 56 of what Americans pay for the same prescription drugs 66 Textbooks Edit Price discrimination is also prevalent within the textbook publishing industry Prices for textbooks are much higher in the United States despite the fact that they are produced in the country Copyright protection laws increase the price of textbooks Also textbooks are mandatory in the United States while schools in other countries see them as study aids 67 Two necessary conditions for price discrimination Edit There are two conditions that must be met if a price discrimination scheme is to work First the firm must be able to identify market segments by their price elasticity of demand and second the firms must be able to enforce the scheme 68 For example airlines routinely engage in price discrimination by charging high prices for customers with relatively inelastic demand business travelers and discount prices for tourist who have relatively elastic demand The airlines enforce the scheme by enforcing a no resale policy on the tickets preventing a tourist from buying a ticket at a discounted price and selling it to a business traveler arbitrage Airlines must also prevent business travelers from directly buying discount tickets Airlines accomplish this by imposing advance ticketing requirements or minimum stay requirements conditions that would be difficult for the average business traveler to meet 69 70 66 Concession and student discounts Edit Firms often use third degree price discrimination concession and student segments in the market By offering a perceived discount to market segments which generally have less disposable income and hence are more price sensitive the firm is able to capture the revenue from those with higher price sensitivity whilst also charging higher prices and capturing the consumer surplus of the segments with less price sensitivity 20 71 Counterexamples Edit Some pricing patterns appear to be price discrimination but are not Congestion pricing Edit Main article Congestion pricing Price discrimination only happens when the same product is sold at more than one price Congestion pricing is not price discrimination Peak and off peak fares on a train are not the same product some people have to travel during rush hour and travelling off peak is not equivalent to them Some companies have high fixed costs like a train company which owns a railway and rolling stock or a restaurant which has to pay for premises and equipment If these fixed costs permit the company to additionally provide less preferred products like mid morning meals or off peak rail travel at little additional cost it can profit both seller and buyer to offer them at lower prices Providing more product from the same fixed costs increases both producer and consumer surplus This is not technically price discrimination unlike say giving menus with higher prices to richer looking customers which the poorer looking ones get an ordinary menu If different prices are charged for products that only some consumers will see as equivalent the differential pricing can be used to manage demand For instance airlines can use price discrimination to encourage people to travel at unpopular times early in the morning This helps avoid over crowding and helps to spread out demand 70 The airline gets better use out of planes and airports and can thus charge less or profit more than if it only flew peak hours See also EditDynamic pricing Frugal innovation Geo marketing Interstate Commerce Act of 1887 Marketing Market segmentation Microeconomics Outline of industrial organization Value based pricing Pay what you want Pricing strategies Ramsey problem Redlining Resale price maintenance Robinson Patman Act Sliding scale fees Ticket resale Variable pricing Yield managementReferences Edit Krugman Paul R Maurice Obstfeld 2003 Chapter 6 Economies of Scale Imperfect Competition and International Trade International Economics Theory and Policy 6th ed p 142 a b c d Robert Phillips 2005 Pricing and Revenue Optimization Stanford University Press p 74 ISBN 978 0 8047 4698 4 a b c d Peter Belobaba Amedeo Odoni Cynthia Barnhart 2009 The Global Airline Industry John Wiley amp Sons p 77 ISBN 978 0 470 74472 7 a b c Apollo M 2014 Dual Pricing Two Points of View Citizen and Non citizen Case of Entrance Fees in Tourist Facilities in Nepal Procedia Social and Behavioral Sciences 120 414 422 https doi org 10 1016 j sbspro 2014 02 119 Lott John R Roberts Russell D January 1991 A Guide to the Pitfalls of Identifying Price Discrimination Economic Inquiry 29 1 14 23 doi 10 1111 j 1465 7295 1991 tb01249 x ISSN 0095 2583 Pettinger Tejvan Price Discrimination Economics Help Retrieved 2023 04 21 Tirole Jean 1988 The Theory of Industrial Organization Cambridge William M Pride O C Ferrell 2011 Foundations of Marketing 5th ed Cengage Learning p 374 ISBN 978 1 111 58016 2 Ruth Macklin 2004 Double Standards in Medical Research in Developing Countries Cambridge University Press p 166 ISBN 978 0 521 54170 1 Bernard M Hoekman Aaditya Mattoo Philip English 2002 Development Trade and the WTO A Handbook World Bank Publications p 378 ISBN 978 0 8213 4997 7 a b c d e Carl Shapiro Hal Varian 1999 Information Rules A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy Harvard Business School Press p 39 ISBN 978 0 87584 863 1 a b c Paul Belleflamme Martin Peitz 2010 Industrial Organization Markets and Strategies Cambridge University Press p 196 ISBN 978 0 521 86299 8 a b Mance Davor Mance Diana Vitezic Dinko 2019 Personalized Medicine and Personalized Pricing Degrees of Price Discrimination Personalized Medicine in Healthcare Systems Cham Springer International Publishing pp 171 180 doi 10 1007 978 3 030 16465 2 14 ISBN 978 3 030 16464 5 S2CID 157911717 retrieved 2023 04 21 a b David K Hayes Allisha Miller 2011 Revenue Management for the Hospitality Industry John Wiley and Sons p 115 ISBN 978 1 118 13692 8 Robert Phillips 2005 Pricing and Revenue Optimization Stanford University Press pp 82 83 ISBN 978 0 8047 4698 4 Lynne Pepall Dan Richards George Norman 2011 Contemporary Industrial Organization A Quantitative Approach John Wiley and Sons p 87 ISBN 978 1 118 13898 4 a b Robert Phillips 2005 Pricing and Revenue Optimization Stanford University Press p 78 ISBN 978 0 8047 4698 4 Robert Phillips 2005 Pricing and Revenue Optimization Stanford University Press p 77 ISBN 978 0 8047 4698 4 Price Discrimination and Imperfect Competition Lars A Stole a b c d e f g h i j k l Marburger Daniel 2012 08 09 Innovative Pricing Strategies to Increase Profits Business Expert Press doi 10 4128 9781606493823 ISBN 978 1 60649 382 3 a b Allingham Michael 1991 Arbitrage elements of financial economics London ISBN 978 1 349 21385 6 OCLC 1004672634 a b c d e f Marshall Alfred 2013 Principles of Economics New York PALGRAVE MACMILLAN ISBN 9780230249271 Bragg Steven Rate fence definition AccountingTools Retrieved 2023 04 21 Anderson Eric T Dana James D June 2009 When Is Price Discrimination Profitable Management Science 55 6 980 989 doi 10 1287 mnsc 1080 0979 hdl 10419 38645 ISSN 0025 1909 Monopoly and competition Definition Structures Performance amp Facts Britannica www britannica com Retrieved 2023 04 22 Market Power Corporate Finance Institute Retrieved 2023 04 22 Dana James Williams Kevin February 2020 Intertemporal Price Discrimination in Sequential Quantity Price Games PDF Cambridge MA w26794 doi 10 3386 w26794 S2CID 229171191 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help a b Corts Kenneth 1998 Third degree price discrimination in oligopoly all out competition and strategic commitment The RAND Journal of Economics 29 2 306 323 doi 10 2307 2555890 JSTOR 2555890 via JSTOR Frank Robert H 2010 Microeconomics and Behavior 8th Ed McGraw Hill Irwin pp 393 394 Frank Robert H 2010 Microeconomics and Behavior 8th Ed McGraw Hill Irwin p 395 Lahiri Atanu Dewan Rajiv M Freimer Marshall 2013 Pricing of Wireless Services Service Pricing vs Traffic Pricing Information Systems Research 24 2 418 435 doi 10 1287 isre 1120 0434 JSTOR 42004312 via JSTOR Emerson Patrick M 2019 Pricing Strategies a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help 8 4 Third Degree Price Discrimination Social Sci LibreTexts 2020 03 17 Retrieved 2023 04 21 Bergemann Dirk Brooks Benjamin Morris Stephen 2015 03 01 The Limits of Price Discrimination American Economic Review 105 3 921 957 doi 10 1257 aer 20130848 ISSN 0002 8282 Hayes Beth 1987 Competition and Two Part Tariffs Journal of Business 60 1 41 54 doi 10 1086 296384 via University of Chicago Press Is Ctrip reliable to book international flights Air Travel Forum Tripadvisor www tripadvisor com au Retrieved 2023 04 21 Gomes Renato Pavan Alessandro September 2016 Many to many matching and price discrimination Many to many matching and price discrimination Theoretical Economics 11 3 1005 1052 doi 10 3982 TE1904 Timothy J Brennan 2010 Decoupling in electric utilities Journal of Regulatory Economics 38 38 1 49 69 doi 10 1007 s11149 010 9120 5 S2CID 154139838 a b Amin Mohammad Hanson Kara Mills Anne 2004 Price discrimination in obstetric services a case study in Bangladesh Health Economics 13 6 597 604 doi 10 1002 hec 848 ISSN 1099 1050 PMID 15185389 Pigou A C 1929 Economics of Welfare 3 ed London Macmillan a b Png Ivan 1998 Managerial Economics 1 ed Malden MA Blackwell pp 301 315 ISBN 1 55786 927 8 Jing Bing 30 June 2016 Behavior Based Pricing Production Efficiency and Quality Differentiation Management Science 63 7 2365 2376 doi 10 1287 mnsc 2016 2463 ISSN 0025 1909 Bonatti Alessandro Cisternas Gonzalo 2020 03 01 Consumer Scores and Price Discrimination The Review of Economic Studies 87 2 750 791 doi 10 1093 restud rdz046 hdl 1721 1 129703 ISSN 0034 6527 Stavins Joanna 2001 02 01 Price Discrimination in the Airline Market The Effect of Market Concentration The Review of Economics and Statistics 83 1 200 202 doi 10 1162 rest 2001 83 1 200 ISSN 0034 6535 S2CID 15287234 Dana Jr J D 1998 04 01 Advance Purchase Discounts and Price Discrimination in Competitive Markets Journal of Political Economy 106 2 395 422 doi 10 1086 250014 ISSN 0022 3808 S2CID 222454180 Puller Steven L Taylor Lisa M 2012 12 01 Price discrimination by day of week of purchase Evidence from the U S airline industry Journal of Economic Behavior amp Organization 84 3 801 812 doi 10 1016 j jebo 2012 09 022 ISSN 0167 2681 Luttmann Alexander 2019 01 01 Evidence of directional price discrimination in the U S airline industry International Journal of Industrial Organization 62 291 329 doi 10 1016 j ijindorg 2018 03 013 ISSN 0167 7187 S2CID 158868627 a b Rampell Catherine 3 December 2013 The Wedding Fix Is In The New York Times Retrieved 29 March 2017 karenbryson 19 February 2015 The White Man s Tax Retrieved 29 March 2017 thebeijinger 18 June 2014 Beijing s White Man Tax Pegged at a Median 16 in Unscientific Survey Retrieved 29 March 2017 Bumiputera discount A sensitive topic that must be addressed 6 August 2013 Retrieved 29 March 2017 See generally PRICE DISCRIMINATION Black s Law Dictionary 10th ed 2014 See e g Civil Rights Gender Discrimination California Prohibits Gender Based Pricing Cal Civ Code 51 6 West Supp 1996 109 HARV L REV 1839 1839 1996 Differential pricing of services is one of America s last remaining vestiges of formal gender based discrimination Joyce McClements and Cheryl Thomas Public Accommodations Statutes Is Ladies Night Out 37 MERCER L REV 1605 1618 1986 Heidi Paulson Ladies Night Discounts Should We Bar Them or Promote Them 32 B C L Rev 487 528 1991 arguing that ladies night promotions encourage paternalistic attitudes toward women and encourage stereotypes of both men and women a b Bessendorf Anna December 2015 From Cradle to Cane The Cost of Being a Female Consumer PDF New York City Department of Consumer Affairs Retrieved August 25 2018 a b California State Senate Gender Tax Repeal Act of 1995 AB 1100 Aug 31 1995 Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act Pub L No 111 148 124 Stat 119 2010 to be codified in scattered titles and sections hereinafter Affordable Care Act Affordable Care Act 2701 124 Stat 119 37 38 Danielle Paquette Why you should always buy the men s version of almost anything The Washington Post December 22 2015 https www washingtonpost com news wonk wp 2015 12 22 women really do pay more for razors and almost everything else Archived 2016 03 16 at the Wayback Machine Collinson Patrick 14 January 2017 EU s gender ruling on car insurance has made inequality worse the Guardian Chen Li Zhong Hu Wei Min Szulga Radek Zhou Xiaolan 2018 02 01 Demographics gender and local knowledge Price discrimination in China s car market Economics Letters 163 172 174 doi 10 1016 j econlet 2017 11 026 ISSN 0165 1765 Pogge Thomas 2008 World poverty and human rights cosmopolitan responsibilities and reforms PDF 2 ed Cambridge u a Polity Press ISBN 978 0745641447 Waldfogel Joel 2020 06 01 The Welfare Effects of Spotify s Cross Country Price Discrimination Review of Industrial Organization 56 4 593 613 doi 10 1007 s11151 020 09748 0 ISSN 1573 7160 S2CID 212834250 Zuckerman Michael August 7 2014 The Utah Lawyers Who Are Making Legal Services Affordable The Atlantic Retrieved 4 December 2014 Dubner Stephen J 3 October 2011 Getting Married Then Get Ready for Price Discrimination Retrieved 29 March 2017 Wedding costs Shopping for special occasions 7 January 2015 Retrieved 29 March 2017 a b DANZON PATRICIA M 1 November 1997 Price Discrimination for Pharmaceuticals Welfare Effects in the US and the EU International Journal of the Economics of Business 4 3 301 322 doi 10 1080 758523212 ISSN 1357 1516 Cabolis Christos Clerides Sofronis Ioannou Ioannis amp Senft Daniel 1 April 2007 A textbook example of international price discrimination Economics Letters 95 1 91 95 doi 10 1016 j econlet 2006 09 019 ISSN 0165 1765 S2CID 40568157 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Samuelson amp Marks Managerial Economics 4th ed Wiley 2003 Samuelson amp Marks Managerial Economics 4th ed Wiley 2003 Airlines typically attempt to maximize revenue rather than profits because airlines variable costs are small Thus airlines use pricing strategies designed to fill seats rather than equate marginal revenue and marginal costs a b Xu Man Tang Wansheng Zhou Chi 1 February 2020 Price discrimination based on purchase behavior and service cost in competitive channels Soft Computing 24 4 2567 2588 doi 10 1007 s00500 019 03760 7 ISSN 1433 7479 S2CID 67905768 How Do Companies Use Price Discrimination Investopedia Retrieved 2023 04 21 Cite error A list defined reference named Brennan is not used in the content see the help page Geradin Damien Petit Nicolas 1 September 2006 Price Discrimination Under Ec Competition Law Another Antitrust Doctrine in Search of Limiting Principles Journal of Competition Law amp Economics 2 3 479 531 doi 10 1093 joclec nhl013 ISSN 1744 6422 Amin Mohammad Hanson Kara Mills Anne 2004 Price discrimination in obstetric services a case study in Bangladesh Health Economics 13 6 597 604 doi 10 1002 hec 848 ISSN 1099 1050 PMID 15185389 External links EditPrice Discrimination and Imperfect Competition Lars Stole Pricing Information Hal Varian Price Discrimination for Digital Goods Arun Sundararajan Price Discrimination Discussion piece from The Filter Joelonsoftware s blog entry on Price Discrimination Taken to the Cleaners Steven Landsburg s explanation of Dry Cleaner pricing Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Price discrimination amp oldid 1152435017, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.