fbpx
Wikipedia

Social norm

Social norms are shared standards of acceptable behavior by groups.[1][2] Social norms can both be informal understandings that govern the behavior of members of a society, as well as be codified into rules and laws.[3] Social normative influences or social norms, are deemed to be powerful drivers of human behavioural changes and well organized and incorporated by major theories which explain human behaviour.[4] Institutions are composed of multiple norms.[5] Norms are shared social beliefs about behavior; thus, they are distinct from "ideas", "attitudes", and "values", which can be held privately, and which do not necessarily concern behavior.[2] Norms are contingent on context, social group, and historical circumstances.[6]

Scholars distinguish between regulative norms (which constrain behavior), constitutive norms (which shape interests), and prescriptive norms (which prescribe what actors ought to do).[7][5][4] The effects of norms can be determined by a logic of appropriateness and logic of consequences; the former entails that actors follow norms because it is socially appropriate, and the latter entails that actors follow norms because of cost-benefit calculations.[8]

Three stages have been identified in the life cycle of a norm: (1) Norm emergence – norm entrepreneurs seek to persuade others of the desirability and appropriateness of certain behaviors; (2) Norm cascade – when a norm obtains broad acceptance; and (3) Norm internalization – when a norm acquires a "taken-for-granted" quality.[5] Norms are robust to various degrees: some norms are often violated whereas other norms are so deeply internalized that norm violations are infrequent.[2][4] Evidence for the existence of norms can be detected in the patterns of behavior within groups, as well as the articulation of norms in group discourse.[2]

Definition

 
Shaking hands after a sports match is an example of a social norm.

There are varied definitions of social norms, but there is agreement among scholars that norms are:[9]

  1. social and shared among members of a group,
  2. related to behaviors and shape decision-making,
  3. proscriptive or prescriptive
  4. socially acceptable way of living by a group of people in a society.

In 1965, Jack P. Gibbs identified three basic normative dimensions that all concepts of norms could be subsumed under:

  1. "a collective evaluation of behavior in terms of what it ought to be"
  2. "a collective expectation as to what behavior will be"
  3. "particular reactions to behavior" (including attempts sanction or induce certain conduct)[10]

According to Ronald Jepperson, Peter Katzenstein and Alexander Wendt, "norms are collective expectations about proper behavior for a given identity."[11] Wayne Sandholtz argues against this definition, as he writes that shared expectations are an effect of norms, not an intrinsic quality of norms.[12] Sandholtz, Martha Finnemore and Kathryn Sikkink define norms instead as "standards of appropriate behavior for actors with a given identity."[12][5] In this definition, norms have an "oughtness" quality to them.[12][5]

Michael Hechter and Karl-Dieter Opp define norms as "cultural phenomena that prescribe and proscribe behavior in specific circumstances."[13] Sociologists Christine Horne and Stefanie Mollborn define norms as "group-level evaluations of behavior."[14] This entails that norms are widespread expectations of social approval or disapproval of behavior.[14] Scholars debate whether social norms are individual constructs or collective constructs.[9]

Economist and game theorist Peyton Young defines norms as "patterns of behavior that are self-enforcing within a group."[6] He emphasizes that norms are driven by shared expectations: "Everyone conforms, everyone is expected to conform, and everyone wants to conform when they expect everyone else to conform."[6] He characterizes norms as devices that "coordinate people's expectations in interactions that possess multiple equilibria."[15]

Concepts such as "conventions", "customs", "morals", "mores", "rules", and "laws" have been characterized as equivalent to norms.[10] Institutions can be considered collections or clusters of multiple norms.[5] Rules and norms are not necessarily distinct phenomena: both are standards of conduct that can have varying levels of specificity and formality.[12][14] Laws are a highly formal version of norms.[16][12][17] Laws, rules and norms may be contradictory; for example, a law may prohibit something but norms still allow it.[14] Norms are not the equivalent of an aggregation of individual attitudes.[18] Ideas, attitudes and values are not necessarily norms, as these concepts do not necessarily concern behavior and may be held privately.[2][14] "Prevalent behaviors" and behavioral regularities are not necessarily norms.[14][9] Instinctual or biological reactions, personal tastes, and personal habits are not necessarily norms.[9]

Emergence and transmission

Groups may adopt norms in a variety of ways.

Some stable and self-reinforcing norms may emerge spontaneously without conscious human design.[19][13] Peyton Young goes as far as to say that "norms typically evolve without top-down direction... through interactions of individuals rather than by design."[6] Norms may develop informally, emerging gradually as a result of repeated use of discretionary stimuli to control behavior.[20][21] Not necessarily laws set in writing, informal norms represent generally accepted and widely sanctioned routines that people follow in everyday life.[22] These informal norms, if broken, may not invite formal legal punishments or sanctions, but instead encourage reprimands, warnings, or othering; incest, for example, is generally thought of as wrong in society, but many jurisdictions do not legally prohibit it.

Norms may also be created and advanced through conscious human design by norm entrepreneurs.[23][24] Norms can arise formally, where groups explicitly outline and implement behavioral expectations. Legal norms typically arise from design.[13][25] A large number of these norms we follow 'naturally' such as driving on the right side of the road in the US and on the left side in the UK, or not speeding in order to avoid a ticket.

Martha Finnemore and Kathryn Sikkink identify three stages in the life cycle of a norm:[5]

  1. Norm emergence: Norm entrepreneurs seek to persuade others to adopt their ideas about what is desirable and appropriate
  2. Norm cascade: When a norm has broad acceptance and reaches a tipping point, with norm leaders pressuring others to adopt and adhere to the norm
  3. Norm internalization: When the norm has acquired a "taken-for-granted" quality where compliance with the norm is nearly automatic

They argue that several factors may raise the influence of certain norms:[5]

  • Legitimation: Actors that feel insecure about their status and reputation may be more likely to embrace norms
  • Prominence: Norms that are held by actors seen as desirable and successful are more likely to diffuse to others
  • Intrinsic qualities of the norm: Norms that are specific, long-lasting, and universal are more likely to become prominent
  • Path dependency: Norms that are related to preexisting norms are more likely to be widely accepted
  • World time-context: Systemic shocks (such as wars, revolutions and economic crises) may motivate a search for new norms

Christina Horne and Stefanie Mollborn have identified two broad categories of arguments for the emergence of norms:[14]

  1. Consequentialism: norms are created when an individual's behavior has consequences and externalities for other members of the group.
  2. Relationalism: norms are created because people want to attract positive social reactions. In other words, norms do not necessarily contribute to the collective good.

Per consequentialism, norms contribute to the collective good. However, per relationalism, norms do not necessarily contribute to the collective good; norms may even be harmful to the collective.[14]

Some scholars have characterized norms as inherently unstable, thus creating possibilities for norm change.[12][26][27][28] According to Wayne Sandholtz, actors are more likely to persuade others to modify existing norms if they possess power, can reference existing foundational meta-norms, and can reference precedents.[29] Social proximity between actors has been characterized as a key component in sustaining social norms.[30]

Transfer of norms between groups

Individuals may also import norms from a previous organization to their new group, which can get adopted over time.[31][32] Without a clear indication of how to act, people typically rely on their history to determine the best course forward; what was successful before may serve them well again. In a group, individuals may all import different histories or scripts about appropriate behaviors; common experience over time will lead the group to define as a whole its take on the right action, usually with the integration of several members' schemas.[32] Under the importation paradigm, norm formation occurs subtly and swiftly[32] whereas with formal or informal development of norms may take longer.

Groups internalize norms by accepting them as reasonable and proper standards for behavior within the group. Once firmly established, a norm becomes a part of the group's operational structure and hence more difficult to change. While possible for newcomers to a group to change its norms, it is much more likely that the new individual will adopt the group's norms, values, and perspectives, rather than the other way around.[20]

Deviance from social norms

 
"Normal = bad word", a graffiti in Ljubljana, Slovenia

Deviance is defined as "nonconformity to a set of norms that are accepted by a significant number of people in a community or society."[33] More simply put, if group members do not follow a norm, they become labeled as a deviant. In the sociological literature, this can often lead to them being considered outcasts of society. Yet, deviant behavior amongst children is somewhat expected. Except the idea of this deviance manifesting as a criminal action, the social tolerance given in the example of the child is quickly withdrawn against the criminal. Crime is considered one of the most extreme forms of deviancy according to scholar Clifford R. Shaw.[34]

What is considered "normal" is relative to the location of the culture in which the social interaction is taking place. In psychology, an individual who routinely disobeys group norms runs the risk of turning into the "institutionalized deviant." Similar to the sociological definition, institutionalized deviants may be judged by other group members for their failure to adhere to norms. At first, group members may increase pressure on a non-conformist, attempting to engage the individual in conversation or explicate why he or she should follow their behavioral expectations. The role in which one decides on whether or not to behave is largely determined on how their actions will affect others.[35] Especially with new members who perhaps do not know any better, groups may use discretionary stimuli to bring an individual's behavior back into line. Over time, however, if members continue to disobey, the group will give up on them as a lost cause; while the group may not necessarily revoke their membership, they may give them only superficial consideration.[20] If a worker is late to a meeting, for example, violating the office norm of punctuality, a boss or other co-worker may wait for the individual to arrive and pull him aside later to ask what happened. If the behavior continues, eventually the group may begin meetings without him since the individual "is always late." The group generalizes the individual's disobedience and promptly dismisses it, thereby reducing the member's influence and footing in future group disagreements.

Group tolerance for deviation varies across membership; not all group members receive the same treatment for norm violations. Individuals may build up a "reserve" of good behavior through conformity, which they can borrow against later. These idiosyncrasy credits provide a theoretical currency for understanding variations in group behavioral expectations.[36] A teacher, for example, may more easily forgive a straight-A student for misbehaving—who has past "good credit" saved up—than a repeatedly disruptive student. While past performance can help build idiosyncrasy credits, some group members have a higher balance to start with.[36] Individuals can import idiosyncrasy credits from another group; childhood movie stars, for example, who enroll in college, may experience more leeway in adopting school norms than other incoming freshmen. Finally, leaders or individuals in other high-status positions may begin with more credits and appear to be "above the rules" at times.[20][36] Even their idiosyncrasy credits are not bottomless, however; while held to a more lenient standard than the average member, leaders may still face group rejection if their disobedience becomes too extreme.

Deviance also causes multiple emotions one experiences when going against a norm. One of those emotions widely attributed to deviance is guilt. Guilt is connected to the ethics of duty which in turn becomes a primary object of moral obligation. Guilt is followed by an action that is questioned after its doing.[37] It can be described as something negative to the self as well as a negative state of feeling. Used in both instances, it is both an unpleasant feeling as well as a form of self-punishment. Using the metaphor of "dirty hands",[38] it is the staining or tainting of oneself and therefore having to self cleanse away the filth. It is a form of reparation that confronts oneself as well as submitting to the possibility of anger and punishment from others. Guilt is a point in both action and feeling that acts as a stimulus for further "honorable" actions.

Behavior

Whereas ideas in general do not necessarily have behavioral implications, Martha Finnemore notes that "norms by definition concern behavior. One could say that they are collectively held ideas about behavior."[2]

Norms running counter to the behaviors of the overarching society or culture may be transmitted and maintained within small subgroups of society. For example, Crandall (1988) noted that certain groups (e.g., cheerleading squads, dance troupes, sports teams, sororities) have a rate of bulimia, a publicly recognized life-threatening disease, that is much higher than society as a whole. Social norms have a way of maintaining order and organizing groups.[39]

In the field of social psychology, the roles of norms are emphasized—which can guide behavior in a certain situation or environment as "mental representations of appropriate behavior".[40] It has been shown that normative messages can promote pro-social behavior, including decreasing alcohol use,[41] increasing voter turnout,[42] and reducing energy use.[43] According to the psychological definition of social norms' behavioral component, norms have two dimensions: how much a behavior is exhibited, and how much the group approves of that behavior.[44]

Social control

Although not considered to be formal laws within society, norms still work to promote a great deal of social control.[45] They are statements that regulate conduct. The cultural phenomenon that is the norm is the prescriber of acceptable behavior in specific instances. Ranging in variations depending on culture, race, religion, and geographical location, it is the foundation of the terms some know as acceptable as not to injure others, the golden rule, and to keep promises that have been pledged.[46] Without them, there would be a world without consensus, common ground, or restrictions. Even though the law and a state's legislation is not intended to control social norms, society and the law are inherently linked and one dictates the other. This is why it has been said that the language used in some legislation is controlling and dictating for what should or should not be accepted. For example, the criminalization of familial sexual relations is said to protect those that are vulnerable, however even consenting adults cannot have sexual relationships with their relatives. The language surrounding these laws conveys the message that such acts are supposedly immoral and should be condemned, even though there is no actual victim in these consenting relationships.[47]

Social norms can be enforced formally (e.g., through sanctions) or informally (e.g., through body language and non-verbal communication cues).[48] Because individuals often derive physical or psychological resources from group membership, groups are said to control discretionary stimuli; groups can withhold or give out more resources in response to members' adherence to group norms, effectively controlling member behavior through rewards and operant conditioning.[20] Social psychology research has found the more an individual values group-controlled resources or the more an individual sees group membership as central to his definition of self, the more likely he is to conform.[20] Social norms also allow an individual to assess what behaviors the group deems important to its existence or survival, since they represent a codification of belief; groups generally do not punish members or create norms over actions which they care little about.[20][31] Norms in every culture create conformity that allows for people to become socialized to the culture in which they live.[49]

As social beings, individuals learn when and where it is appropriate to say certain things, to use certain words, to discuss certain topics or wear certain clothes, and when it is not. Thus, knowledge about cultural norms is important for impressions,[50] which is an individual's regulation of their nonverbal behavior. One also comes to know through experience what types of people he/she can and cannot discuss certain topics with or wear certain types of dress around. Typically, this knowledge is derived through experience (i.e. social norms are learned through social interaction).[50] Wearing a suit to a job interview in order to give a great first impression represents a common example of a social norm in the white collar work force.

In his work "Order without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes", Robert Ellickson studies various interactions between members of neighbourhoods and communities to show how societal norms create order within a small group of people. He argues that, in a small community or neighborhood, many rules and disputes can be settled without a central governing body simply by the interactions within these communities.[51]

Sociology

In sociology, norms are seen as rules that bind an individual's actions to a specific sanction in one of two forms: a punishment or a reward. [52]Through regulation of behavior, social norms create unique patterns that allow for distinguishing characteristics to be made between social systems.[52] This creates a boundary that allows for a differentiation between those that belong in a specific social setting and those that do not.[52]

For Talcott Parsons of the functionalist school, norms dictate the interactions of people in all social encounters. On the other hand, Karl Marx believed that norms are used to promote the creation of roles in society which allows for people of different levels of social class structure to be able to function properly.[49] Marx claims that this power dynamic creates social order. James Coleman (sociologist) used both micro and macro conditions for his theory. [53]For Coleman, norms start out as goal oriented actions by actors on the micro level.[54] If the benefits do not outweigh the costs of the action for the actors, then a social norm would emerge. [55]The norm's effectiveness is then determined by its ability to enforce its sanctions against those who would not contribute to the "optimal social order."[56]

Heinrich Popitz is convinced that the establishment of social norms, that make the future actions of alter foreseeable for ego, solves the problem of contingency (Niklas Luhmann). In this way, ego can count on those actions as if they would already have been performed and does not have to wait for their actual execution; social interaction is thus accelerated. Important factors in the standardization of behavior are sanctions[57] and social roles.

Operant conditioning

The probability of these behaviours occurring again is discussed in the theories of B. F. Skinner, who states that operant conditioning plays a role in the process of social norm development. Operant conditioning is the process by which behaviours are changed as a function of their consequences. The probability that a behaviour will occur can be increased or decreased depending on the consequences of said behaviour.

In the case of social deviance, an individual who has gone against a norm will contact the negative contingencies associated with deviance, this may take the form of formal or informal rebuke, social isolation or censure, or more concrete punishments such as fines or imprisonment. If one reduces the deviant behavior after receiving a negative consequence, then they have learned via punishment. If they have engaged in a behavior consistent with a social norm after having an aversive stimulus reduced, then they have learned via negative reinforcement. Reinforcement increases behavior, while punishment decreases behavior.

As an example of this, consider a child who has painted on the walls of her house, if she has never done this before she may immediately seek a reaction from her mother or father. The form of reaction taken by the mother or father will affect whether the behaviour is likely to occur again in the future. If her parent is positive and approving of the behaviour it will likely reoccur (reinforcement) however, if the parent offers an aversive consequence (physical punishment, time-out, anger etc...) then the child is less likely to repeat the behaviour in future (punishment).

Skinner also states that humans are conditioned from a very young age on how to behave and how to act with those around us considering the outside influences of the society and location one is in.[58] Built to blend into the ambiance and attitude around us, deviance is a frowned upon action.

Focus theory of normative conduct

Cialdini, Reno, and Kallgren developed the focus theory of normative conduct to describe how individuals implicitly juggle multiple behavioral expectations at once. Expanding on conflicting prior beliefs about whether cultural, situational or personal norms motivate action, the researchers suggested the focus of an individual's attention will dictate what behavioral expectation they follow.[59]

Types

There is no clear consensus on how the term norm should be used.[60]

Martha Finnemore and Kathryn Sikkink distinguish between three types of norms:[5]

  1. Regulative norms: they "order and constrain behavior"
  2. Constitutive norms: they "create new actors, interests, or categories of action"
  3. Evaluative and prescriptive norms: they have an "oughtness" quality to them

Finnemore, Sikkink, Jeffrey W. Legro and others have argued that the robustness (or effectiveness) of norms can be measured by factors such as:

  • The specificity of the norm: norms that are clear and specific are more likely to be effective[5][4]
  • The longevity of the norm: norms with a history are more likely to be effective[5]
  • The universality of the norm: norms that make general claims (rather than localized and particularistic claims) are more likely to be effective[5]
  • The prominence of the norm: norms that are widely accepted among powerful actors are more likely to be effective[4]

Christina Horne argues that the robustness of a norm is shaped by the degree of support for the actors who sanction deviant behaviors; she refers to norms regulating how to enforce norms as "metanorms."[61] According to Beth G. Simmons and Hyeran Jo, diversity of support for a norm can be a strong indicator of robustness.[62] They add that institutionalization of a norm raises its robustness.[62] It has also been posited that norms that exist within broader clusters of distinct but mutually reinforcing norms may be more robust.[63]

Jeffrey Checkel argues that there are two common types of explanations for the efficacy of norms:[64]

  • Rationalism: actors comply with norms due to coercion, cost-benefit calculations, and material incentives
  • Constructivism: actors comply with norms due to social learning and socialization

According to Peyton Young, mechanisms that support normative behavior include:[6]

Descriptive versus injunctive

Descriptive norms depict what happens, while injunctive norms describe what should happen. Cialdini, Reno, and Kallgren (1990) define a descriptive norm as people's perceptions of what is commonly done in specific situations; it signifies what most people do, without assigning judgment. The absence of trash on the ground in a parking lot, for example, transmits the descriptive norm that most people there do not litter.[59][65] An Injunctive norm, on the other hand, transmits group approval about a particular behavior; it dictates how an individual should behave.[59][65][66][67] Watching another person pick up trash off the ground and throw it out, a group member may pick up on the injunctive norm that he ought to not litter.

Prescriptive and proscriptive norms

Prescriptive norms are unwritten rules that are understood and followed by society and indicate what we should do.[68] Expressing gratitude or writing a Thank You card when someone gives you a gift represents a prescriptive norm in American culture. Proscriptive norms, in contrast, comprise the other end of the same spectrum; they are similarly society's unwritten rules about what one should not do.[68] These norms can vary between cultures; while kissing someone you just met on the cheek is an acceptable greeting in some European countries, this is not acceptable, and thus represents a proscriptive norm in the United States.

Subjective norms

Subjective norms are determined by beliefs about the extent to which important others want a person to perform a behavior.When combined with attitude toward behavior, subjective norms shape an individuals intentions.[69]Social influences are conceptualized in terms of the pressure that people perceive from important others to perform, or not to perform, a behavior.[67]Social Psychologist Icek Azjen theorized that subjective norms are determined by the strength of a given normative belief and further weighted by the significance of a social referent, as represented in the following equation: SN ∝ Σnimi , where (n) is a normative belief and (m) is the motivation to comply with said belief. [70]

Mathematical representations

Over the last few decades, several theorists have attempted to explain social norms from a more theoretical point of view. By quantifying behavioral expectations graphically or attempting to plot the logic behind adherence, theorists hoped to be able to predict whether or not individuals would conform. The return potential model and game theory provide a slightly more economic conceptualization of norms, suggesting individuals can calculate the cost or benefit behind possible behavioral outcomes. Under these theoretical frameworks, choosing to obey or violate norms becomes a more deliberate, quantifiable decision.

Return potential model

 
Figure 1. The return potential model (reproduced from Jackson, 1965).

Developed in the 1960s, the return potential model provides a method for plotting and visualizing group norms. In the regular coordinate plane, the amount of behavior exhibited is plotted on the X-axis (label a in ) while the amount of group acceptance or approval gets plotted on the Y-axis (b in Figure 1).[44] The graph represents the potential return or positive outcome to an individual for a given behavioral norm. Theoretically, one could plot a point for each increment of behavior how much the group likes or dislikes that action. For example, it may be the case that among first-year graduate students, strong social norms exist around how many daily cups of coffee a student drinks. If the return curve in Figure 1 correctly displays the example social norm, we can see that if someone drinks 0 cups of coffee a day, the group strongly disapproves. The group disapproves of the behavior of any member who drinks fewer than four cups of coffee a day; the group disapproves of drinking more than seven cups, shown by the approval curve dipping back below zero. As seen in this example, the return potential model displays how much group approval one can expect for each increment of behavior.

  • Point of maximum return. The point with the greatest y-coordinate is called the point of maximum return, as it represents the amount of behavior the group likes the best.[44] While c in Figure 1 is labeling the return curve in general, the highlighted point just above it at X=6, represents the point of maximum return. Extending our above example, the point of maximum return for first-year graduate students would be 6 cups of coffee; they receive the most social approval for drinking exactly that many cups. Any more or any fewer cups would decrease the approval.
  • Range of tolerable behavior. Label d represents the range of tolerable behavior, or the amount of action the group finds acceptable.[44] It encompasses all the positive area under the curve. In Figure 1, the range of tolerable behavior extends is 3, as the group approves of all behavior from 4 to 7 and 7-4=3. Carrying over our coffee example again, we can see that first-years only approve of having a limited number of cups of coffee (between 4 and 7); more than 7 cups or fewer than 4 would fall outside the range of tolerable behavior. Norms can have a narrower or wider range of tolerable behavior. Typically, a narrower range of behavior indicates a behavior with greater consequences to the group.[20]
  • Intensity. The intensity of the norm tells how much the group cares about the norm, or how much group affect is at stake to be won or lost. It is represented in the return potential model by the total amount of area subsumed by the curve, regardless of whether the area is positive or negative.[44] A norm with low intensity would not vary far from the x-axis; the amount of approval or disapproval for given behaviors would be closer to zero. A high-intensity norm, however, would have more extreme approval ratings. In Figure 1, the intensity of the norm appears high, as few behaviors invoke a rating of indifference.
  • Crystallization. Finally, norm crystallization refers to how much variance exists within the curve; translated from the theoretical back to the actual norm, it shows how much agreement exists between group members about the approval for a given amount of behavior.[44] It may be that some members believe the norm more central to group functioning than others. A group norm like how many cups of coffee first years should drink would probably have low crystallization since a lot of individuals have varying beliefs about the appropriate amount of caffeine to imbibe; in contrast, the norm of not plagiarizing another student's work would likely have high crystallization, as people uniformly agree on the behavior's unacceptability. Showing the overall group norm, the return potential model in Figure 1 does not indicate the crystallization. However, a return potential model that plotted individual data points alongside the cumulative norm could demonstrate the variance and allow us to deduce crystallization.

Game theory

Another general formal framework that can be used to represent the essential elements of the social situation surrounding a norm is the repeated game of game theory. Rational choice, a branch of game theory, deals with the relations and actions socially committed among rational agents.[71] A norm gives a person a rule of thumb for how they should behave. However, a rational person acts according to the rule only if it is beneficial for them. The situation can be described as follows. A norm gives an expectation of how other people act in a given situation (macro). A person acts optimally given the expectation (micro). For a norm to be stable, people's actions must reconstitute the expectation without change (micro-macro feedback loop). A set of such correct stable expectations is known as a Nash equilibrium. Thus, a stable norm must constitute a Nash equilibrium.[72] In the Nash equilibrium, no one actor has any positive incentive in individually deviating from a certain action.[73] Social norms will be implemented if the actions of that specific norm come into agreement by the support of the Nash equilibrium in the majority of the game theoretical approaches.[73]

From a game-theoretical point of view, there are two explanations for the vast variety of norms that exist throughout the world. One is the difference in games. Different parts of the world may give different environmental contexts and different people may have different values, which may result in a difference in games. The other is equilibrium selection not explicable by the game itself. Equilibrium selection is closely related to coordination. For a simple example, driving is common throughout the world, but in some countries people drive on the right and in other countries people drive on the left (see coordination game). A framework called comparative institutional analysis is proposed to deal with the game theoretical structural understanding of the variety of social norms.

See also

References

  1. ^ Lapinski, M. K.; Rimal, R. N. (2005). "An explication of social norms". Communication Theory. 15 (2): 127–147. doi:10.1093/ct/15.2.127.
  2. ^ a b c d e f Finnemore, Martha (1996). National Interests in International Society. Cornell University Press. pp. 22–24, 26–27. JSTOR 10.7591/j.ctt1rv61rh.
  3. ^ Pristl, A-C; Kilian, S; Mann, A. (2020). "When does a social norm catch the worm? Disentangling socialnormative influences on sustainable consumption behaviour". Consumer Behav. 20 (3): 635–654. doi:10.1002/cb.1890. S2CID 228807152.
  4. ^ a b c d e Legro, Jeffrey W. (1997). "Which Norms Matter? Revisiting the "Failure" of Internationalism". International Organization. 51 (1): 31–63. doi:10.1162/002081897550294. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 2703951. S2CID 154368865.
  5. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l Finnemore, Martha; Sikkink, Kathryn (1998). "International Norm Dynamics and Political Change". International Organization. 52 (4): 887–917. doi:10.1162/002081898550789. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 2601361. S2CID 10950888.
  6. ^ a b c d e Young, H. Peyton (2015). "The Evolution of Social Norms". Annual Review of Economics. 7 (1): 359–387. doi:10.1146/annurev-economics-080614-115322. ISSN 1941-1383.
  7. ^ Tannenwald, Nina (1999). "The Nuclear Taboo: The United States and the Normative Basis of Nuclear Non-Use". International Organization. 53 (3): 433–468. doi:10.1162/002081899550959. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 2601286.
  8. ^ Herrmann, Richard K.; Shannon, Vaughn P. (2001). "Defending International Norms: The Role of Obligation, Material Interest, and Perception in Decision Making". International Organization. 55 (3): 621–654. doi:10.1162/00208180152507579. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 3078659. S2CID 145661726.
  9. ^ a b c d Legros, Sophie; Cislaghi, Beniamino (2020). "Mapping the Social-Norms Literature: An Overview of Reviews". Perspectives on Psychological Science. 15 (1): 62–80. doi:10.1177/1745691619866455. ISSN 1745-6916. PMC 6970459. PMID 31697614.
  10. ^ a b Gibbs, Jack P. (1965). "Norms: The Problem of Definition and Classification". American Journal of Sociology. 70 (5): 586–594. doi:10.1086/223933. ISSN 0002-9602. JSTOR 2774978. PMID 14269217. S2CID 27377450.
  11. ^ Katzenstein, Peter (1996). The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics. Columbia University Press. p. 54. ISBN 978-0-231-10469-2.
  12. ^ a b c d e f Sandholtz, Wayne (2017). "International Norm Change". Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics. doi:10.1093/acrefore/9780190228637.013.588. ISBN 9780190228637.
  13. ^ a b c Hecher, Michael; Opp, Karl-Dieter (2001). Social Norms. Russell Sage Foundation. pp. xi. ISBN 978-0-87154-354-7. JSTOR 10.7758/9781610442800.
  14. ^ a b c d e f g h Horne, Christine; Mollborn, Stefanie (2020). "Norms: An Integrated Framework". Annual Review of Sociology. 46 (1): 467–487. doi:10.1146/annurev-soc-121919-054658. ISSN 0360-0572. S2CID 225435025.
  15. ^ Young, H. Peyton (2016), "Social Norms", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 1–7, doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_2338-1, ISBN 978-1-349-95121-5, S2CID 13026974, retrieved 2021-05-22
  16. ^ Knight, Jack (1992). Institutions and social conflict. Cambridge University Press. pp. 1–2. ISBN 978-0-511-52817-0. OCLC 1127523562.
  17. ^ Streeck, Wolfgang; Thelen, Kathleen Ann (2005). Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies. Oxford University Press. p. 14. ISBN 978-0-19-928046-9.
  18. ^ Horne, Christine; Johnson, Monica Kirkpatrick (2021). "Testing an Integrated Theory: Distancing Norms in the Early Months of Covid-19". Sociological Perspectives. 64 (5): 970–987. doi:10.1177/07311214211005493. ISSN 0731-1214.
  19. ^ Sugden, Robert (1989). "Spontaneous Order". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 3 (4): 85–97. doi:10.1257/jep.3.4.85. ISSN 0895-3309.
  20. ^ a b c d e f g h Hackman, J.R. (1992). "Group influences on individuals in organizations". In M.D. Dunnette & L.M. Hough (Eds.), Handbook of industrial and organizational psychology (Vol. 3). Palo Alto: Consulting Psychologists Press, 234-245.
  21. ^ Chong, D. (2000) Rational lives: norms and values in politics and society
  22. ^ Gerber, L. & Macionis, J. (2011) Sociology, 7th Canadian ed., p. 65
  23. ^ Sunstein, Cass R. (1996). "Social Norms and Social Roles". Columbia Law Review. 96 (4): 903–968. doi:10.2307/1123430. ISSN 0010-1958. JSTOR 1123430. S2CID 153823271.
  24. ^ Keck, Margaret E.; Sikkink, Kathryn (1998). Activists beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International Politics. Cornell University Press. ISBN 978-0-8014-3444-0. JSTOR 10.7591/j.ctt5hh13f.
  25. ^ Kendall, D. (2011) Sociology in our times
  26. ^ Sandholtz, Wayne (2008-03-01). "Dynamics of International Norm Change: Rules against Wartime Plunder". European Journal of International Relations. 14 (1): 101–131. doi:10.1177/1354066107087766. ISSN 1354-0661. S2CID 143721778.
  27. ^ Wiener, Antje (2008). The Invisible Constitution of Politics: Contested Norms and International Encounters. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-89596-5.
  28. ^ Krook, Mona Lena; True, Jacqui (2012-03-01). "Rethinking the life cycles of international norms: The United Nations and the global promotion of gender equality". European Journal of International Relations. 18 (1): 103–127. doi:10.1177/1354066110380963. ISSN 1354-0661. S2CID 145545535.
  29. ^ Sandholtz, Wayne (2009). International Norms and Cycles of Change. Oxford University Press. pp. 16–18. ISBN 978-0-19-985537-7.
  30. ^ Bicchieri, Cristina; Dimant, Eugen; Gächter, Simon; Nosenzo, Daniele (2022). "Social proximity and the erosion of norm compliance". Games and Economic Behavior. 132: 59–72. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2021.11.012. ISSN 0899-8256.
  31. ^ a b Feldman, D.C. (1984). "The development and enforcement of group norms". Academy of Management Review. 9 (1): 47–55. doi:10.2307/258231. JSTOR 258231.
  32. ^ a b c Bettenhausen, K.; Murnighan, J.K. (1985). "The emergence of norms in competitive decision-making groups". Administrative Science Quarterly. 30 (3): 350–372. doi:10.2307/2392667. JSTOR 2392667. S2CID 52525302.
  33. ^ Appelbaum, R. P., Carr, D., Duneir, M., & Giddens, A. (2009). "Conformity, Deviance, and Crime." Introduction to Sociology, New York, NY: W. W. Norton & Company, Inc., p. 173.
  34. ^ Molinari, Christina (2015). "Clifford Shaw and Henry McKay". In Dobbert, Duane L.; Mackey, Thomas X. (eds.). Deviance: Theories on Behaviors That Defy Social Norms: Theories on Behaviors That Defy Social Norms. ABC-CLIO. pp. 108–118. ISBN 978-1-4408-3324-3.
  35. ^ Drobak, John N. "1. The Role of Social Variables." Norms and the Law. Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 2006. N. pag. Print.
  36. ^ a b c Hollander, E.P. (1958). "Conformity, status, and idiosyncrasy credit". Psychological Review. 65 (2): 117–127. doi:10.1037/h0042501. PMID 13542706.
  37. ^ Greenspan, Patricia S. "Chapter 4: Moral Residues." Practical Guilt: Moral Dilemmas, Emotions, and Social Norms. N.p.: Oxford UP, 1995. N. pag. Print.
  38. ^ Greenspan, Patricia S. "Chapter 6: Basing Ethics on Emotion." Practical Guilt: Moral Dilemmas, Emotions, and Social Norms
  39. ^ Huang, Peter H.; Wu, Ho-Mou (October 1994). "More Order Without More Law: A Theory of Social Norms and Organizational Cultures". The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. 10 (2): 390–406. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.jleo.a036856. SSRN 5412.
  40. ^ Aarts, H.; Dijksterhuis, A. (2003). (PDF). Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 84 (1): 18–28. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.84.1.18. PMID 12518968. S2CID 18213113. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2020-07-09.
  41. ^ Collins, S. E.; Carey, K. B.; Sliwinski, M. J. (2002). "Mailed personalized normative feedback as a brief intervention for at-risk college drinkers". Journal of Studies on Alcohol. 63 (5): 559–567. doi:10.15288/jsa.2002.63.559. PMID 12380852.
  42. ^ Gerber, A. S.; Rogers, T. (2009). "Descriptive social norms and motivation to vote: everybody's voting and so should you". The Journal of Politics. 71 (1): 178–191. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.691.37. doi:10.1017/s0022381608090117. S2CID 10783035.
  43. ^ Brandon, Alec; List, John A.; Metcalfe, Robert D.; Price, Michael K.; Rundhammer, Florian (19 March 2019). "Testing for crowd out in social nudges: Evidence from a natural field experiment in the market for electricity". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 116 (12): 5293–5298. Bibcode:2019PNAS..116.5293B. doi:10.1073/pnas.1802874115. PMC 6431171. PMID 30104369.
  44. ^ a b c d e f Jackson, J. (1965). "Structural characteristics of norms". In I.D. Steiner & M. Fishbein (Eds.), Current studies in social psychology (pp. 301-309).
  45. ^ Druzin, Bryan (2016). "Using Social Norms as a Substitute for Law". Albany Law Review. 78: 68.
  46. ^ Hechter, Michael et al., eds.. "Introduction". Social Norms. Ed. Michael Hechter et al.. Russell Sage Foundation, 2001. xi–xx.
  47. ^ Roffee, James A (2013). "The Synthetic Necessary Truth Behind New Labour's Criminalisation of Incest". Social & Legal Studies. 23: 113–130. doi:10.1177/0964663913502068. S2CID 145292798.
  48. ^ Doering, Laura; Ody-Brasier, Amandine (2021). "Time and Punishment: How Individuals Respond to Being Sanctioned in Voluntary Associations". American Journal of Sociology. 127 (2): 441–491. doi:10.1086/717102. ISSN 0002-9602. S2CID 246017181.
  49. ^ a b Marshall, G. Oxford Dictionary of Sociology
  50. ^ a b Kamau, C. (2009) Strategizing impression management in corporations: cultural knowledge as capital. In D. Harorimana (Ed) Cultural implications of knowledge sharing, management and transfer: identifying competitive advantage. Chapter 4. Information Science Reference. ISBN 978-1-60566-790-4
  51. ^ Ellickson, Robert (1994). Order without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes.
  52. ^ a b c HYDEN, HAKAN (2022). SOCIOLOGY OF LAW AS THE SCIENCE OF NORMS. [S.l.]: ROUTLEDGE. ISBN 978-1-003-24192-8. OCLC 1274199773.
  53. ^ HYDEN, HAKAN (2022). SOCIOLOGY OF LAW AS THE SCIENCE OF NORMS. [S.l.]: ROUTLEDGE. ISBN 978-1-003-24192-8. OCLC 1274199773.
  54. ^ HYDEN, HAKAN (2022). SOCIOLOGY OF LAW AS THE SCIENCE OF NORMS. [S.l.]: ROUTLEDGE. ISBN 978-1-003-24192-8. OCLC 1274199773.
  55. ^ HYDEN, HAKAN (2022). SOCIOLOGY OF LAW AS THE SCIENCE OF NORMS. [S.l.]: ROUTLEDGE. ISBN 978-1-003-24192-8. OCLC 1274199773.
  56. ^ HYDEN, HAKAN (2022). SOCIOLOGY OF LAW AS THE SCIENCE OF NORMS. [S.l.]: ROUTLEDGE. ISBN 978-1-003-24192-8. OCLC 1274199773.
  57. ^ See The International Handbook of Sociology, ed. by Stella R. Quah and Arnaud Sales, Sage 2000, p. 62.
  58. ^ Dobbert, Duane L., and Thomas X. Mackey. "Chapter 9: B.F. Skinner." Deviance: Theories on Behaviors That Defy Social Norms. N.p.: n.p., n.d. N. pag. Print.
  59. ^ a b c Cialdini, R.B.; Reno, R.R.; Kallgren, C.A. (1990). "A focus theory of normative conduct: Recycling the concept of norms to reduce littering in public places". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 58 (6): 1015–1026. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.58.6.1015. S2CID 7867498.
  60. ^ Hechter, Michael; Opp, Karl-Dieter (2001). Social Norms. Russell Sage Foundation. ISBN 978-1-61044-280-0.[page needed]
  61. ^ Horne, Christine (2009). "A Social Norms Approach to Legitimacy". American Behavioral Scientist. 53 (3): 400–415. doi:10.1177/0002764209338799. ISSN 0002-7642. S2CID 144726807.
  62. ^ a b Simmons, Beth A; Jo, Hyeran (2019). "Measuring Norms and Normative Contestation: The Case of International Criminal Law". Journal of Global Security Studies. 4 (1): 18–36. doi:10.1093/jogss/ogy043. ISSN 2057-3170.
  63. ^ Lantis, Jeffrey S.; Wunderlich, Carmen (2018). "Resiliency dynamics of norm clusters: Norm contestation and international cooperation". Review of International Studies. 44 (3): 570–593. doi:10.1017/S0260210517000626. ISSN 0260-2105. S2CID 148853481.
  64. ^ Checkel, Jeffrey T. (2001). "Why Comply? Social Learning and European Identity Change". International Organization. 55 (3): 553–588. doi:10.1162/00208180152507551. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 3078657. S2CID 143511229.
  65. ^ a b Cialdini, R (2007). "Descriptive social norms as underappreciated sources of social control". Psychometrika. 72 (2): 263–268. doi:10.1007/s11336-006-1560-6. S2CID 121708702.
  66. ^ Schultz, Nolan; Cialdini, Goldstein; Griskevicius (2007). "The constructive, destructive, and reconstructive power of social norms" (PDF). Psychological Science. 18 (5): 429–434. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9280.2007.01917.x. hdl:10211.3/199684. PMID 17576283. S2CID 19200458.
  67. ^ a b Rivis, Amanda, Sheeran, Paschal. "Descriptive Norms as an Additional Predictor in the Theory of Planned Behaviour: A Meta-Analysis". 2003
  68. ^ a b Wilson, K.L.; Lizzio, A.J.; Zauner, S.; Gallois, C. (2001). "Social rules for managing attempted interpersonal domination in the workplace: Influence of status and gender". Sex Roles. 44 (3/4): 129–154. doi:10.1023/a:1010998802612. S2CID 142800037.
  69. ^ Attitudes, behavior, and social context : the role of norms and group membership. Deborah J. Terry, Michael A. Hogg. Mahwah, N.J.: L. Erlbaum Associates. 2000. ISBN 0-585-17974-3. OCLC 44961884.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  70. ^ "Author index for volume 50". Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. 50 (2): 411. 1991. doi:10.1016/0749-5978(91)90029-s. ISSN 0749-5978.
  71. ^ Voss, Thomas. Game-Theoretical Perspectives on the Emergence of Social Norms. Social Norms, 2001, p.105.
  72. ^ Bicchieri, Cristina. 2006. The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms, New York: Cambridge University Press, Ch. 1
  73. ^ a b Voss 2001, p. 105

Further reading

  • Axelrod, Robert (1984). The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books. ISBN 9780465021222.
  • Appelbaum, R. P., Carr, D., Duneir, M., Giddens, A. (2009). Conformity, Deviance, and Crime. Introduction to Sociology, New York, NY: W. W. Norton & Company, Inc., p. 173.
  • Becker, H. S. (1982). "Culture: A Sociological View". Yale Review. 71 (4): 513–527.
  • Bicchieri, C. (2006). The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms, New York: Cambridge University Press.
  • Blumer, H (1956). "Sociological Analysis and the 'Variable". American Sociological Review. 21 (6): 683–690. doi:10.2307/2088418. JSTOR 2088418. S2CID 146998430.
  • Boyd, R. & Richerson, P.J. (1985). Culture and the Evolutionary Process, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  • Burt, R.S. (1987). "Social Contagion and Innovation: Cohesive Versus Structural Equivalence". American Journal of Sociology. 92 (6): 1287–1335. doi:10.1086/228667. S2CID 22380365.
  • Rimal, Rajiv N. (2016). "Social Norms: A Review". Review of Communication Research. 4 (1): 1–28. doi:10.12840/issn.2255-4165.2016.04.01.008.
  • Cialdini, R (2007). "Descriptive Social Norms as Underappreciated Sources of Social Control". Psychometrika. 72 (2): 263–268. doi:10.1007/s11336-006-1560-6. S2CID 121708702.
  • Druzin, Bryan H. (24 June 2012). "Eating Peas with One's Fingers: A Semiotic Approach to Law and Social Norms". International Journal for the Semiotics of Law - Revue internationale de Sémiotique juridique. 26 (2): 257–274. doi:10.1007/s11196-012-9271-z. S2CID 85439929.
  • Durkheim, E. (1915). The Elementary Forms of the Religious Life, New York: Free Press.
  • Elster, Jon (1 November 1989). "Social Norms and Economic Theory". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 3 (4): 99–117. doi:10.1257/jep.3.4.99. hdl:10535/3264. S2CID 154638062.
  • Fehr, Ernst; Fischbacher, Urs; Gächter, Simon (March 2002). "Strong reciprocity, human cooperation, and the enforcement of social norms" (PDF). Human Nature. 13 (1): 1–25. doi:10.1007/s12110-002-1012-7. PMID 26192593. S2CID 2901235. (PDF) from the original on 2019-03-26.
  • Fine, G.A. (2001). Social Norms, ed. by Michael Hechter and Karl-Dieter Opp, New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation.
  • Greif, A (1994). "Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies". Journal of Political Economy. 102 (5): 912–950. doi:10.1086/261959. S2CID 153431326.
  • Hechter, M. & Karl-Dieter Opp, eds. (2001). Social Norms, New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
  • Heiss, J. (1981). "Social Roles," In Social Psychology: Sociological Perspectives, Rosenburg, M. & Turner, R.H. (eds.), New York: Basic Books.
  • Hochschild, A. (1989). "The Economy of Gratitude," In D.D. Franks & E.D. McCarthy (Eds.), The Sociology of Emotions: Original Essays and Research Papers, Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
  • Horne, C. (2001). "Social Norms". In M. Hechter & K. Opp (Eds.), New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation.
  • Kahneman, D.; Miller, D.T. (1986). (PDF). Psychological Review. 80 (2): 136–153. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.93.2.136. S2CID 7706059. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2020-07-11.
  • Kollock, P (1994). "The emergence of exchange structures: An experimental study of uncertainty, commitment, and trust". American Journal of Sociology. 100 (2): 313–45. doi:10.1086/230539. S2CID 144646491.
  • Kohn, M.L. (1977). Class and Conformity: A Study in Values, 2nd ed., Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
  • Macy, M.W.; Skvoretz, J. (1998). "The evolution of trust and cooperation between strangers: A computational model". American Sociological Review. 63 (5): 638–660. doi:10.2307/2657332. JSTOR 2657332.
  • Mark, N (1998). "Birds of a feather sing together". Social Forces. 77 (2): 453–485. doi:10.1093/sf/77.2.453. S2CID 143739215.
  • McElreath, Richard; Boyd, Robert; Richerson, Peter J. (February 2003). (PDF). Current Anthropology. 44 (1): 122–130. doi:10.1086/345689. S2CID 8796947. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2019-03-07.
  • Opp, K (1982). "The evolutionary emergence of norms". British Journal of Social Psychology. 21 (2): 139–149. doi:10.1111/j.2044-8309.1982.tb00522.x.
  • Posner, Eric A. (1996). "The Regulation of Groups: The Influence of Legal and Nonlegal Sanctions on Collective Action". The University of Chicago Law Review. 63 (1): 133–197. doi:10.2307/1600068. JSTOR 1600068.
  • Posner, E. (2000). Law and Social Norms. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press
  • Prentice, D. A.; Miller, D. T. (1993). "Pluralistic ignorance and alcohol use on campus: Some consequences of misperceiving the social norm". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 64 (2): 243–256. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.470.522. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.64.2.243. PMID 8433272.
  • Schultz, P. Wesley; Nolan, Jessica M.; Cialdini, Robert B.; Goldstein, Noah J.; Griskevicius, Vladas (25 November 2016). "The Constructive, Destructive, and Reconstructive Power of Social Norms". Psychological Science. 18 (5): 429–434. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9280.2007.01917.x. hdl:10211.3/199684. PMID 17576283. S2CID 19200458.
  • Scott, J.F. (1971). Internalization of Norms: A Sociological Theory of Moral Commitment, Englewoods Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice–Hall.
  • Ullmann-Margalit, E. (1977). The Emergence of Norms. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Yamagishi, T.; Cook, K.S.; Watabe, M. (1998). "Uncertainty, trust, and commitment formation in the United States and Japan". American Journal of Sociology. 104 (1): 165–194. doi:10.1086/210005. S2CID 144931651.
  • Young, H.P. (2008). "Social norms". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition.

External links

social, norm, shared, standards, acceptable, behavior, groups, both, informal, understandings, that, govern, behavior, members, society, well, codified, into, rules, laws, ative, influences, social, norms, deemed, powerful, drivers, human, behavioural, changes. Social norms are shared standards of acceptable behavior by groups 1 2 Social norms can both be informal understandings that govern the behavior of members of a society as well as be codified into rules and laws 3 Social normative influences or social norms are deemed to be powerful drivers of human behavioural changes and well organized and incorporated by major theories which explain human behaviour 4 Institutions are composed of multiple norms 5 Norms are shared social beliefs about behavior thus they are distinct from ideas attitudes and values which can be held privately and which do not necessarily concern behavior 2 Norms are contingent on context social group and historical circumstances 6 Scholars distinguish between regulative norms which constrain behavior constitutive norms which shape interests and prescriptive norms which prescribe what actors ought to do 7 5 4 The effects of norms can be determined by a logic of appropriateness and logic of consequences the former entails that actors follow norms because it is socially appropriate and the latter entails that actors follow norms because of cost benefit calculations 8 Three stages have been identified in the life cycle of a norm 1 Norm emergence norm entrepreneurs seek to persuade others of the desirability and appropriateness of certain behaviors 2 Norm cascade when a norm obtains broad acceptance and 3 Norm internalization when a norm acquires a taken for granted quality 5 Norms are robust to various degrees some norms are often violated whereas other norms are so deeply internalized that norm violations are infrequent 2 4 Evidence for the existence of norms can be detected in the patterns of behavior within groups as well as the articulation of norms in group discourse 2 Contents 1 Definition 2 Emergence and transmission 2 1 Transfer of norms between groups 3 Deviance from social norms 4 Behavior 5 Social control 6 Sociology 6 1 Operant conditioning 7 Focus theory of normative conduct 8 Types 8 1 Descriptive versus injunctive 8 2 Prescriptive and proscriptive norms 8 3 Subjective norms 9 Mathematical representations 9 1 Return potential model 9 2 Game theory 10 See also 11 References 12 Further reading 13 External linksDefinition Edit Shaking hands after a sports match is an example of a social norm There are varied definitions of social norms but there is agreement among scholars that norms are 9 social and shared among members of a group related to behaviors and shape decision making proscriptive or prescriptive socially acceptable way of living by a group of people in a society In 1965 Jack P Gibbs identified three basic normative dimensions that all concepts of norms could be subsumed under a collective evaluation of behavior in terms of what it ought to be a collective expectation as to what behavior will be particular reactions to behavior including attempts sanction or induce certain conduct 10 According to Ronald Jepperson Peter Katzenstein and Alexander Wendt norms are collective expectations about proper behavior for a given identity 11 Wayne Sandholtz argues against this definition as he writes that shared expectations are an effect of norms not an intrinsic quality of norms 12 Sandholtz Martha Finnemore and Kathryn Sikkink define norms instead as standards of appropriate behavior for actors with a given identity 12 5 In this definition norms have an oughtness quality to them 12 5 Michael Hechter and Karl Dieter Opp define norms as cultural phenomena that prescribe and proscribe behavior in specific circumstances 13 Sociologists Christine Horne and Stefanie Mollborn define norms as group level evaluations of behavior 14 This entails that norms are widespread expectations of social approval or disapproval of behavior 14 Scholars debate whether social norms are individual constructs or collective constructs 9 Economist and game theorist Peyton Young defines norms as patterns of behavior that are self enforcing within a group 6 He emphasizes that norms are driven by shared expectations Everyone conforms everyone is expected to conform and everyone wants to conform when they expect everyone else to conform 6 He characterizes norms as devices that coordinate people s expectations in interactions that possess multiple equilibria 15 Concepts such as conventions customs morals mores rules and laws have been characterized as equivalent to norms 10 Institutions can be considered collections or clusters of multiple norms 5 Rules and norms are not necessarily distinct phenomena both are standards of conduct that can have varying levels of specificity and formality 12 14 Laws are a highly formal version of norms 16 12 17 Laws rules and norms may be contradictory for example a law may prohibit something but norms still allow it 14 Norms are not the equivalent of an aggregation of individual attitudes 18 Ideas attitudes and values are not necessarily norms as these concepts do not necessarily concern behavior and may be held privately 2 14 Prevalent behaviors and behavioral regularities are not necessarily norms 14 9 Instinctual or biological reactions personal tastes and personal habits are not necessarily norms 9 Emergence and transmission EditGroups may adopt norms in a variety of ways Some stable and self reinforcing norms may emerge spontaneously without conscious human design 19 13 Peyton Young goes as far as to say that norms typically evolve without top down direction through interactions of individuals rather than by design 6 Norms may develop informally emerging gradually as a result of repeated use of discretionary stimuli to control behavior 20 21 Not necessarily laws set in writing informal norms represent generally accepted and widely sanctioned routines that people follow in everyday life 22 These informal norms if broken may not invite formal legal punishments or sanctions but instead encourage reprimands warnings or othering incest for example is generally thought of as wrong in society but many jurisdictions do not legally prohibit it Norms may also be created and advanced through conscious human design by norm entrepreneurs 23 24 Norms can arise formally where groups explicitly outline and implement behavioral expectations Legal norms typically arise from design 13 25 A large number of these norms we follow naturally such as driving on the right side of the road in the US and on the left side in the UK or not speeding in order to avoid a ticket Martha Finnemore and Kathryn Sikkink identify three stages in the life cycle of a norm 5 Norm emergence Norm entrepreneurs seek to persuade others to adopt their ideas about what is desirable and appropriate Norm cascade When a norm has broad acceptance and reaches a tipping point with norm leaders pressuring others to adopt and adhere to the norm Norm internalization When the norm has acquired a taken for granted quality where compliance with the norm is nearly automaticThey argue that several factors may raise the influence of certain norms 5 Legitimation Actors that feel insecure about their status and reputation may be more likely to embrace norms Prominence Norms that are held by actors seen as desirable and successful are more likely to diffuse to others Intrinsic qualities of the norm Norms that are specific long lasting and universal are more likely to become prominent Path dependency Norms that are related to preexisting norms are more likely to be widely accepted World time context Systemic shocks such as wars revolutions and economic crises may motivate a search for new normsChristina Horne and Stefanie Mollborn have identified two broad categories of arguments for the emergence of norms 14 Consequentialism norms are created when an individual s behavior has consequences and externalities for other members of the group Relationalism norms are created because people want to attract positive social reactions In other words norms do not necessarily contribute to the collective good Per consequentialism norms contribute to the collective good However per relationalism norms do not necessarily contribute to the collective good norms may even be harmful to the collective 14 Some scholars have characterized norms as inherently unstable thus creating possibilities for norm change 12 26 27 28 According to Wayne Sandholtz actors are more likely to persuade others to modify existing norms if they possess power can reference existing foundational meta norms and can reference precedents 29 Social proximity between actors has been characterized as a key component in sustaining social norms 30 Transfer of norms between groups Edit Individuals may also import norms from a previous organization to their new group which can get adopted over time 31 32 Without a clear indication of how to act people typically rely on their history to determine the best course forward what was successful before may serve them well again In a group individuals may all import different histories or scripts about appropriate behaviors common experience over time will lead the group to define as a whole its take on the right action usually with the integration of several members schemas 32 Under the importation paradigm norm formation occurs subtly and swiftly 32 whereas with formal or informal development of norms may take longer Groups internalize norms by accepting them as reasonable and proper standards for behavior within the group Once firmly established a norm becomes a part of the group s operational structure and hence more difficult to change While possible for newcomers to a group to change its norms it is much more likely that the new individual will adopt the group s norms values and perspectives rather than the other way around 20 Deviance from social norms Edit Normal bad word a graffiti in Ljubljana Slovenia Deviance is defined as nonconformity to a set of norms that are accepted by a significant number of people in a community or society 33 More simply put if group members do not follow a norm they become labeled as a deviant In the sociological literature this can often lead to them being considered outcasts of society Yet deviant behavior amongst children is somewhat expected Except the idea of this deviance manifesting as a criminal action the social tolerance given in the example of the child is quickly withdrawn against the criminal Crime is considered one of the most extreme forms of deviancy according to scholar Clifford R Shaw 34 What is considered normal is relative to the location of the culture in which the social interaction is taking place In psychology an individual who routinely disobeys group norms runs the risk of turning into the institutionalized deviant Similar to the sociological definition institutionalized deviants may be judged by other group members for their failure to adhere to norms At first group members may increase pressure on a non conformist attempting to engage the individual in conversation or explicate why he or she should follow their behavioral expectations The role in which one decides on whether or not to behave is largely determined on how their actions will affect others 35 Especially with new members who perhaps do not know any better groups may use discretionary stimuli to bring an individual s behavior back into line Over time however if members continue to disobey the group will give up on them as a lost cause while the group may not necessarily revoke their membership they may give them only superficial consideration 20 If a worker is late to a meeting for example violating the office norm of punctuality a boss or other co worker may wait for the individual to arrive and pull him aside later to ask what happened If the behavior continues eventually the group may begin meetings without him since the individual is always late The group generalizes the individual s disobedience and promptly dismisses it thereby reducing the member s influence and footing in future group disagreements Group tolerance for deviation varies across membership not all group members receive the same treatment for norm violations Individuals may build up a reserve of good behavior through conformity which they can borrow against later These idiosyncrasy credits provide a theoretical currency for understanding variations in group behavioral expectations 36 A teacher for example may more easily forgive a straight A student for misbehaving who has past good credit saved up than a repeatedly disruptive student While past performance can help build idiosyncrasy credits some group members have a higher balance to start with 36 Individuals can import idiosyncrasy credits from another group childhood movie stars for example who enroll in college may experience more leeway in adopting school norms than other incoming freshmen Finally leaders or individuals in other high status positions may begin with more credits and appear to be above the rules at times 20 36 Even their idiosyncrasy credits are not bottomless however while held to a more lenient standard than the average member leaders may still face group rejection if their disobedience becomes too extreme Deviance also causes multiple emotions one experiences when going against a norm One of those emotions widely attributed to deviance is guilt Guilt is connected to the ethics of duty which in turn becomes a primary object of moral obligation Guilt is followed by an action that is questioned after its doing 37 It can be described as something negative to the self as well as a negative state of feeling Used in both instances it is both an unpleasant feeling as well as a form of self punishment Using the metaphor of dirty hands 38 it is the staining or tainting of oneself and therefore having to self cleanse away the filth It is a form of reparation that confronts oneself as well as submitting to the possibility of anger and punishment from others Guilt is a point in both action and feeling that acts as a stimulus for further honorable actions Behavior EditWhereas ideas in general do not necessarily have behavioral implications Martha Finnemore notes that norms by definition concern behavior One could say that they are collectively held ideas about behavior 2 Norms running counter to the behaviors of the overarching society or culture may be transmitted and maintained within small subgroups of society For example Crandall 1988 noted that certain groups e g cheerleading squads dance troupes sports teams sororities have a rate of bulimia a publicly recognized life threatening disease that is much higher than society as a whole Social norms have a way of maintaining order and organizing groups 39 In the field of social psychology the roles of norms are emphasized which can guide behavior in a certain situation or environment as mental representations of appropriate behavior 40 It has been shown that normative messages can promote pro social behavior including decreasing alcohol use 41 increasing voter turnout 42 and reducing energy use 43 According to the psychological definition of social norms behavioral component norms have two dimensions how much a behavior is exhibited and how much the group approves of that behavior 44 Social control EditAlthough not considered to be formal laws within society norms still work to promote a great deal of social control 45 They are statements that regulate conduct The cultural phenomenon that is the norm is the prescriber of acceptable behavior in specific instances Ranging in variations depending on culture race religion and geographical location it is the foundation of the terms some know as acceptable as not to injure others the golden rule and to keep promises that have been pledged 46 Without them there would be a world without consensus common ground or restrictions Even though the law and a state s legislation is not intended to control social norms society and the law are inherently linked and one dictates the other This is why it has been said that the language used in some legislation is controlling and dictating for what should or should not be accepted For example the criminalization of familial sexual relations is said to protect those that are vulnerable however even consenting adults cannot have sexual relationships with their relatives The language surrounding these laws conveys the message that such acts are supposedly immoral and should be condemned even though there is no actual victim in these consenting relationships 47 Social norms can be enforced formally e g through sanctions or informally e g through body language and non verbal communication cues 48 Because individuals often derive physical or psychological resources from group membership groups are said to control discretionary stimuli groups can withhold or give out more resources in response to members adherence to group norms effectively controlling member behavior through rewards and operant conditioning 20 Social psychology research has found the more an individual values group controlled resources or the more an individual sees group membership as central to his definition of self the more likely he is to conform 20 Social norms also allow an individual to assess what behaviors the group deems important to its existence or survival since they represent a codification of belief groups generally do not punish members or create norms over actions which they care little about 20 31 Norms in every culture create conformity that allows for people to become socialized to the culture in which they live 49 As social beings individuals learn when and where it is appropriate to say certain things to use certain words to discuss certain topics or wear certain clothes and when it is not Thus knowledge about cultural norms is important for impressions 50 which is an individual s regulation of their nonverbal behavior One also comes to know through experience what types of people he she can and cannot discuss certain topics with or wear certain types of dress around Typically this knowledge is derived through experience i e social norms are learned through social interaction 50 Wearing a suit to a job interview in order to give a great first impression represents a common example of a social norm in the white collar work force In his work Order without Law How Neighbors Settle Disputes Robert Ellickson studies various interactions between members of neighbourhoods and communities to show how societal norms create order within a small group of people He argues that in a small community or neighborhood many rules and disputes can be settled without a central governing body simply by the interactions within these communities 51 Sociology EditIn sociology norms are seen as rules that bind an individual s actions to a specific sanction in one of two forms a punishment or a reward 52 Through regulation of behavior social norms create unique patterns that allow for distinguishing characteristics to be made between social systems 52 This creates a boundary that allows for a differentiation between those that belong in a specific social setting and those that do not 52 For Talcott Parsons of the functionalist school norms dictate the interactions of people in all social encounters On the other hand Karl Marx believed that norms are used to promote the creation of roles in society which allows for people of different levels of social class structure to be able to function properly 49 Marx claims that this power dynamic creates social order James Coleman sociologist used both micro and macro conditions for his theory 53 For Coleman norms start out as goal oriented actions by actors on the micro level 54 If the benefits do not outweigh the costs of the action for the actors then a social norm would emerge 55 The norm s effectiveness is then determined by its ability to enforce its sanctions against those who would not contribute to the optimal social order 56 Heinrich Popitz is convinced that the establishment of social norms that make the future actions of alter foreseeable for ego solves the problem of contingency Niklas Luhmann In this way ego can count on those actions as if they would already have been performed and does not have to wait for their actual execution social interaction is thus accelerated Important factors in the standardization of behavior are sanctions 57 and social roles Operant conditioning Edit The probability of these behaviours occurring again is discussed in the theories of B F Skinner who states that operant conditioning plays a role in the process of social norm development Operant conditioning is the process by which behaviours are changed as a function of their consequences The probability that a behaviour will occur can be increased or decreased depending on the consequences of said behaviour In the case of social deviance an individual who has gone against a norm will contact the negative contingencies associated with deviance this may take the form of formal or informal rebuke social isolation or censure or more concrete punishments such as fines or imprisonment If one reduces the deviant behavior after receiving a negative consequence then they have learned via punishment If they have engaged in a behavior consistent with a social norm after having an aversive stimulus reduced then they have learned via negative reinforcement Reinforcement increases behavior while punishment decreases behavior As an example of this consider a child who has painted on the walls of her house if she has never done this before she may immediately seek a reaction from her mother or father The form of reaction taken by the mother or father will affect whether the behaviour is likely to occur again in the future If her parent is positive and approving of the behaviour it will likely reoccur reinforcement however if the parent offers an aversive consequence physical punishment time out anger etc then the child is less likely to repeat the behaviour in future punishment Skinner also states that humans are conditioned from a very young age on how to behave and how to act with those around us considering the outside influences of the society and location one is in 58 Built to blend into the ambiance and attitude around us deviance is a frowned upon action Focus theory of normative conduct EditCialdini Reno and Kallgren developed the focus theory of normative conduct to describe how individuals implicitly juggle multiple behavioral expectations at once Expanding on conflicting prior beliefs about whether cultural situational or personal norms motivate action the researchers suggested the focus of an individual s attention will dictate what behavioral expectation they follow 59 Types EditThere is no clear consensus on how the term norm should be used 60 Martha Finnemore and Kathryn Sikkink distinguish between three types of norms 5 Regulative norms they order and constrain behavior Constitutive norms they create new actors interests or categories of action Evaluative and prescriptive norms they have an oughtness quality to themFinnemore Sikkink Jeffrey W Legro and others have argued that the robustness or effectiveness of norms can be measured by factors such as The specificity of the norm norms that are clear and specific are more likely to be effective 5 4 The longevity of the norm norms with a history are more likely to be effective 5 The universality of the norm norms that make general claims rather than localized and particularistic claims are more likely to be effective 5 The prominence of the norm norms that are widely accepted among powerful actors are more likely to be effective 4 Christina Horne argues that the robustness of a norm is shaped by the degree of support for the actors who sanction deviant behaviors she refers to norms regulating how to enforce norms as metanorms 61 According to Beth G Simmons and Hyeran Jo diversity of support for a norm can be a strong indicator of robustness 62 They add that institutionalization of a norm raises its robustness 62 It has also been posited that norms that exist within broader clusters of distinct but mutually reinforcing norms may be more robust 63 Jeffrey Checkel argues that there are two common types of explanations for the efficacy of norms 64 Rationalism actors comply with norms due to coercion cost benefit calculations and material incentives Constructivism actors comply with norms due to social learning and socializationAccording to Peyton Young mechanisms that support normative behavior include 6 Coordination Social pressure Signaling Focal pointsDescriptive versus injunctive Edit Descriptive norms depict what happens while injunctive norms describe what should happen Cialdini Reno and Kallgren 1990 define a descriptive norm as people s perceptions of what is commonly done in specific situations it signifies what most people do without assigning judgment The absence of trash on the ground in a parking lot for example transmits the descriptive norm that most people there do not litter 59 65 An Injunctive norm on the other hand transmits group approval about a particular behavior it dictates how an individual should behave 59 65 66 67 Watching another person pick up trash off the ground and throw it out a group member may pick up on the injunctive norm that he ought to not litter Prescriptive and proscriptive norms Edit Prescriptive norms are unwritten rules that are understood and followed by society and indicate what we should do 68 Expressing gratitude or writing a Thank You card when someone gives you a gift represents a prescriptive norm in American culture Proscriptive norms in contrast comprise the other end of the same spectrum they are similarly society s unwritten rules about what one should not do 68 These norms can vary between cultures while kissing someone you just met on the cheek is an acceptable greeting in some European countries this is not acceptable and thus represents a proscriptive norm in the United States Subjective norms Edit Subjective norms are determined by beliefs about the extent to which important others want a person to perform a behavior When combined with attitude toward behavior subjective norms shape an individuals intentions 69 Social influences are conceptualized in terms of the pressure that people perceive from important others to perform or not to perform a behavior 67 Social Psychologist Icek Azjen theorized that subjective norms are determined by the strength of a given normative belief and further weighted by the significance of a social referent as represented in the following equation SN Snimi where n is a normative belief and m is the motivation to comply with said belief 70 Mathematical representations EditOver the last few decades several theorists have attempted to explain social norms from a more theoretical point of view By quantifying behavioral expectations graphically or attempting to plot the logic behind adherence theorists hoped to be able to predict whether or not individuals would conform The return potential model and game theory provide a slightly more economic conceptualization of norms suggesting individuals can calculate the cost or benefit behind possible behavioral outcomes Under these theoretical frameworks choosing to obey or violate norms becomes a more deliberate quantifiable decision Return potential model Edit Figure 1 The return potential model reproduced from Jackson 1965 Developed in the 1960s the return potential model provides a method for plotting and visualizing group norms In the regular coordinate plane the amount of behavior exhibited is plotted on the X axis label a in Figure 1 while the amount of group acceptance or approval gets plotted on the Y axis b in Figure 1 44 The graph represents the potential return or positive outcome to an individual for a given behavioral norm Theoretically one could plot a point for each increment of behavior how much the group likes or dislikes that action For example it may be the case that among first year graduate students strong social norms exist around how many daily cups of coffee a student drinks If the return curve in Figure 1 correctly displays the example social norm we can see that if someone drinks 0 cups of coffee a day the group strongly disapproves The group disapproves of the behavior of any member who drinks fewer than four cups of coffee a day the group disapproves of drinking more than seven cups shown by the approval curve dipping back below zero As seen in this example the return potential model displays how much group approval one can expect for each increment of behavior Point of maximum return The point with the greatest y coordinate is called the point of maximum return as it represents the amount of behavior the group likes the best 44 While c in Figure 1 is labeling the return curve in general the highlighted point just above it at X 6 represents the point of maximum return Extending our above example the point of maximum return for first year graduate students would be 6 cups of coffee they receive the most social approval for drinking exactly that many cups Any more or any fewer cups would decrease the approval Range of tolerable behavior Label d represents the range of tolerable behavior or the amount of action the group finds acceptable 44 It encompasses all the positive area under the curve In Figure 1 the range of tolerable behavior extends is 3 as the group approves of all behavior from 4 to 7 and 7 4 3 Carrying over our coffee example again we can see that first years only approve of having a limited number of cups of coffee between 4 and 7 more than 7 cups or fewer than 4 would fall outside the range of tolerable behavior Norms can have a narrower or wider range of tolerable behavior Typically a narrower range of behavior indicates a behavior with greater consequences to the group 20 Intensity The intensity of the norm tells how much the group cares about the norm or how much group affect is at stake to be won or lost It is represented in the return potential model by the total amount of area subsumed by the curve regardless of whether the area is positive or negative 44 A norm with low intensity would not vary far from the x axis the amount of approval or disapproval for given behaviors would be closer to zero A high intensity norm however would have more extreme approval ratings In Figure 1 the intensity of the norm appears high as few behaviors invoke a rating of indifference Crystallization Finally norm crystallization refers to how much variance exists within the curve translated from the theoretical back to the actual norm it shows how much agreement exists between group members about the approval for a given amount of behavior 44 It may be that some members believe the norm more central to group functioning than others A group norm like how many cups of coffee first years should drink would probably have low crystallization since a lot of individuals have varying beliefs about the appropriate amount of caffeine to imbibe in contrast the norm of not plagiarizing another student s work would likely have high crystallization as people uniformly agree on the behavior s unacceptability Showing the overall group norm the return potential model in Figure 1 does not indicate the crystallization However a return potential model that plotted individual data points alongside the cumulative norm could demonstrate the variance and allow us to deduce crystallization Game theory Edit Main article Game theory Another general formal framework that can be used to represent the essential elements of the social situation surrounding a norm is the repeated game of game theory Rational choice a branch of game theory deals with the relations and actions socially committed among rational agents 71 A norm gives a person a rule of thumb for how they should behave However a rational person acts according to the rule only if it is beneficial for them The situation can be described as follows A norm gives an expectation of how other people act in a given situation macro A person acts optimally given the expectation micro For a norm to be stable people s actions must reconstitute the expectation without change micro macro feedback loop A set of such correct stable expectations is known as a Nash equilibrium Thus a stable norm must constitute a Nash equilibrium 72 In the Nash equilibrium no one actor has any positive incentive in individually deviating from a certain action 73 Social norms will be implemented if the actions of that specific norm come into agreement by the support of the Nash equilibrium in the majority of the game theoretical approaches 73 From a game theoretical point of view there are two explanations for the vast variety of norms that exist throughout the world One is the difference in games Different parts of the world may give different environmental contexts and different people may have different values which may result in a difference in games The other is equilibrium selection not explicable by the game itself Equilibrium selection is closely related to coordination For a simple example driving is common throughout the world but in some countries people drive on the right and in other countries people drive on the left see coordination game A framework called comparative institutional analysis is proposed to deal with the game theoretical structural understanding of the variety of social norms See also EditAnomie Breaching experiment Convention norm Enculturation Etiquette Heteronormativity Ideal ethics Ideology Morality Mores Norm philosophy Norm of reciprocity Normality behavior Normalization sociology Other philosophy Philosophical value Peer pressure Rule complex Social norms marketing Social structure Taboo Portals Biography Clothing Society Philosophy Politics PsychologyReferences Edit Lapinski M K Rimal R N 2005 An explication of social norms Communication Theory 15 2 127 147 doi 10 1093 ct 15 2 127 a b c d e f Finnemore Martha 1996 National Interests in International Society Cornell University Press pp 22 24 26 27 JSTOR 10 7591 j ctt1rv61rh Pristl A C Kilian S Mann A 2020 When does a social norm catch the worm Disentangling socialnormative influences on sustainable consumption behaviour Consumer Behav 20 3 635 654 doi 10 1002 cb 1890 S2CID 228807152 a b c d e Legro Jeffrey W 1997 Which Norms Matter Revisiting the Failure of Internationalism International Organization 51 1 31 63 doi 10 1162 002081897550294 ISSN 0020 8183 JSTOR 2703951 S2CID 154368865 a b c d e f g h i j k l Finnemore Martha Sikkink Kathryn 1998 International Norm Dynamics and Political Change International Organization 52 4 887 917 doi 10 1162 002081898550789 ISSN 0020 8183 JSTOR 2601361 S2CID 10950888 a b c d e Young H Peyton 2015 The Evolution of Social Norms Annual Review of Economics 7 1 359 387 doi 10 1146 annurev economics 080614 115322 ISSN 1941 1383 Tannenwald Nina 1999 The Nuclear Taboo The United States and the Normative Basis of Nuclear Non Use International Organization 53 3 433 468 doi 10 1162 002081899550959 ISSN 0020 8183 JSTOR 2601286 Herrmann Richard K Shannon Vaughn P 2001 Defending International Norms The Role of Obligation Material Interest and Perception in Decision Making International Organization 55 3 621 654 doi 10 1162 00208180152507579 ISSN 0020 8183 JSTOR 3078659 S2CID 145661726 a b c d Legros Sophie Cislaghi Beniamino 2020 Mapping the Social Norms Literature An Overview of Reviews Perspectives on Psychological Science 15 1 62 80 doi 10 1177 1745691619866455 ISSN 1745 6916 PMC 6970459 PMID 31697614 a b Gibbs Jack P 1965 Norms The Problem of Definition and Classification American Journal of Sociology 70 5 586 594 doi 10 1086 223933 ISSN 0002 9602 JSTOR 2774978 PMID 14269217 S2CID 27377450 Katzenstein Peter 1996 The Culture of National Security Norms and Identity in World Politics Columbia University Press p 54 ISBN 978 0 231 10469 2 a b c d e f Sandholtz Wayne 2017 International Norm Change Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics doi 10 1093 acrefore 9780190228637 013 588 ISBN 9780190228637 a b c Hecher Michael Opp Karl Dieter 2001 Social Norms Russell Sage Foundation pp xi ISBN 978 0 87154 354 7 JSTOR 10 7758 9781610442800 a b c d e f g h Horne Christine Mollborn Stefanie 2020 Norms An Integrated Framework Annual Review of Sociology 46 1 467 487 doi 10 1146 annurev soc 121919 054658 ISSN 0360 0572 S2CID 225435025 Young H Peyton 2016 Social Norms The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics London Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 1 7 doi 10 1057 978 1 349 95121 5 2338 1 ISBN 978 1 349 95121 5 S2CID 13026974 retrieved 2021 05 22 Knight Jack 1992 Institutions and social conflict Cambridge University Press pp 1 2 ISBN 978 0 511 52817 0 OCLC 1127523562 Streeck Wolfgang Thelen Kathleen Ann 2005 Beyond Continuity Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies Oxford University Press p 14 ISBN 978 0 19 928046 9 Horne Christine Johnson Monica Kirkpatrick 2021 Testing an Integrated Theory Distancing Norms in the Early Months of Covid 19 Sociological Perspectives 64 5 970 987 doi 10 1177 07311214211005493 ISSN 0731 1214 Sugden Robert 1989 Spontaneous Order Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 4 85 97 doi 10 1257 jep 3 4 85 ISSN 0895 3309 a b c d e f g h Hackman J R 1992 Group influences on individuals in organizations In M D Dunnette amp L M Hough Eds Handbook of industrial and organizational psychology Vol 3 Palo Alto Consulting Psychologists Press 234 245 Chong D 2000 Rational lives norms and values in politics and society Gerber L amp Macionis J 2011 Sociology 7th Canadian ed p 65 Sunstein Cass R 1996 Social Norms and Social Roles Columbia Law Review 96 4 903 968 doi 10 2307 1123430 ISSN 0010 1958 JSTOR 1123430 S2CID 153823271 Keck Margaret E Sikkink Kathryn 1998 Activists beyond Borders Advocacy Networks in International Politics Cornell University Press ISBN 978 0 8014 3444 0 JSTOR 10 7591 j ctt5hh13f Kendall D 2011 Sociology in our times Sandholtz Wayne 2008 03 01 Dynamics of International Norm Change Rules against Wartime Plunder European Journal of International Relations 14 1 101 131 doi 10 1177 1354066107087766 ISSN 1354 0661 S2CID 143721778 Wiener Antje 2008 The Invisible Constitution of Politics Contested Norms and International Encounters Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 89596 5 Krook Mona Lena True Jacqui 2012 03 01 Rethinking the life cycles of international norms The United Nations and the global promotion of gender equality European Journal of International Relations 18 1 103 127 doi 10 1177 1354066110380963 ISSN 1354 0661 S2CID 145545535 Sandholtz Wayne 2009 International Norms and Cycles of Change Oxford University Press pp 16 18 ISBN 978 0 19 985537 7 Bicchieri Cristina Dimant Eugen Gachter Simon Nosenzo Daniele 2022 Social proximity and the erosion of norm compliance Games and Economic Behavior 132 59 72 doi 10 1016 j geb 2021 11 012 ISSN 0899 8256 a b Feldman D C 1984 The development and enforcement of group norms Academy of Management Review 9 1 47 55 doi 10 2307 258231 JSTOR 258231 a b c Bettenhausen K Murnighan J K 1985 The emergence of norms in competitive decision making groups Administrative Science Quarterly 30 3 350 372 doi 10 2307 2392667 JSTOR 2392667 S2CID 52525302 Appelbaum R P Carr D Duneir M amp Giddens A 2009 Conformity Deviance and Crime Introduction to Sociology New York NY W W Norton amp Company Inc p 173 Molinari Christina 2015 Clifford Shaw and Henry McKay In Dobbert Duane L Mackey Thomas X eds Deviance Theories on Behaviors That Defy Social Norms Theories on Behaviors That Defy Social Norms ABC CLIO pp 108 118 ISBN 978 1 4408 3324 3 Drobak John N 1 The Role of Social Variables Norms and the Law Cambridge Cambridge UP 2006 N pag Print a b c Hollander E P 1958 Conformity status and idiosyncrasy credit Psychological Review 65 2 117 127 doi 10 1037 h0042501 PMID 13542706 Greenspan Patricia S Chapter 4 Moral Residues Practical Guilt Moral Dilemmas Emotions and Social Norms N p Oxford UP 1995 N pag Print Greenspan Patricia S Chapter 6 Basing Ethics on Emotion Practical Guilt Moral Dilemmas Emotions and Social Norms Huang Peter H Wu Ho Mou October 1994 More Order Without More Law A Theory of Social Norms and Organizational Cultures The Journal of Law Economics and Organization 10 2 390 406 doi 10 1093 oxfordjournals jleo a036856 SSRN 5412 Aarts H Dijksterhuis A 2003 The silence of the library Environment situational norm and social behavior PDF Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 84 1 18 28 doi 10 1037 0022 3514 84 1 18 PMID 12518968 S2CID 18213113 Archived from the original PDF on 2020 07 09 Collins S E Carey K B Sliwinski M J 2002 Mailed personalized normative feedback as a brief intervention for at risk college drinkers Journal of Studies on Alcohol 63 5 559 567 doi 10 15288 jsa 2002 63 559 PMID 12380852 Gerber A S Rogers T 2009 Descriptive social norms and motivation to vote everybody s voting and so should you The Journal of Politics 71 1 178 191 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 691 37 doi 10 1017 s0022381608090117 S2CID 10783035 Brandon Alec List John A Metcalfe Robert D Price Michael K Rundhammer Florian 19 March 2019 Testing for crowd out in social nudges Evidence from a natural field experiment in the market for electricity Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 116 12 5293 5298 Bibcode 2019PNAS 116 5293B doi 10 1073 pnas 1802874115 PMC 6431171 PMID 30104369 a b c d e f Jackson J 1965 Structural characteristics of norms In I D Steiner amp M Fishbein Eds Current studies in social psychology pp 301 309 Druzin Bryan 2016 Using Social Norms as a Substitute for Law Albany Law Review 78 68 Hechter Michael et al eds Introduction Social Norms Ed Michael Hechter et al Russell Sage Foundation 2001 xi xx Roffee James A 2013 The Synthetic Necessary Truth Behind New Labour s Criminalisation of Incest Social amp Legal Studies 23 113 130 doi 10 1177 0964663913502068 S2CID 145292798 Doering Laura Ody Brasier Amandine 2021 Time and Punishment How Individuals Respond to Being Sanctioned in Voluntary Associations American Journal of Sociology 127 2 441 491 doi 10 1086 717102 ISSN 0002 9602 S2CID 246017181 a b Marshall G Oxford Dictionary of Sociology a b Kamau C 2009 Strategizing impression management in corporations cultural knowledge as capital In D Harorimana Ed Cultural implications of knowledge sharing management and transfer identifying competitive advantage Chapter 4 Information Science Reference ISBN 978 1 60566 790 4 Ellickson Robert 1994 Order without Law How Neighbors Settle Disputes a b c HYDEN HAKAN 2022 SOCIOLOGY OF LAW AS THE SCIENCE OF NORMS S l ROUTLEDGE ISBN 978 1 003 24192 8 OCLC 1274199773 HYDEN HAKAN 2022 SOCIOLOGY OF LAW AS THE SCIENCE OF NORMS S l ROUTLEDGE ISBN 978 1 003 24192 8 OCLC 1274199773 HYDEN HAKAN 2022 SOCIOLOGY OF LAW AS THE SCIENCE OF NORMS S l ROUTLEDGE ISBN 978 1 003 24192 8 OCLC 1274199773 HYDEN HAKAN 2022 SOCIOLOGY OF LAW AS THE SCIENCE OF NORMS S l ROUTLEDGE ISBN 978 1 003 24192 8 OCLC 1274199773 HYDEN HAKAN 2022 SOCIOLOGY OF LAW AS THE SCIENCE OF NORMS S l ROUTLEDGE ISBN 978 1 003 24192 8 OCLC 1274199773 See The International Handbook of Sociology ed by Stella R Quah and Arnaud Sales Sage 2000 p 62 Dobbert Duane L and Thomas X Mackey Chapter 9 B F Skinner Deviance Theories on Behaviors That Defy Social Norms N p n p n d N pag Print a b c Cialdini R B Reno R R Kallgren C A 1990 A focus theory of normative conduct Recycling the concept of norms to reduce littering in public places Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 58 6 1015 1026 doi 10 1037 0022 3514 58 6 1015 S2CID 7867498 Hechter Michael Opp Karl Dieter 2001 Social Norms Russell Sage Foundation ISBN 978 1 61044 280 0 page needed Horne Christine 2009 A Social Norms Approach to Legitimacy American Behavioral Scientist 53 3 400 415 doi 10 1177 0002764209338799 ISSN 0002 7642 S2CID 144726807 a b Simmons Beth A Jo Hyeran 2019 Measuring Norms and Normative Contestation The Case of International Criminal Law Journal of Global Security Studies 4 1 18 36 doi 10 1093 jogss ogy043 ISSN 2057 3170 Lantis Jeffrey S Wunderlich Carmen 2018 Resiliency dynamics of norm clusters Norm contestation and international cooperation Review of International Studies 44 3 570 593 doi 10 1017 S0260210517000626 ISSN 0260 2105 S2CID 148853481 Checkel Jeffrey T 2001 Why Comply Social Learning and European Identity Change International Organization 55 3 553 588 doi 10 1162 00208180152507551 ISSN 0020 8183 JSTOR 3078657 S2CID 143511229 a b Cialdini R 2007 Descriptive social norms as underappreciated sources of social control Psychometrika 72 2 263 268 doi 10 1007 s11336 006 1560 6 S2CID 121708702 Schultz Nolan Cialdini Goldstein Griskevicius 2007 The constructive destructive and reconstructive power of social norms PDF Psychological Science 18 5 429 434 doi 10 1111 j 1467 9280 2007 01917 x hdl 10211 3 199684 PMID 17576283 S2CID 19200458 a b Rivis Amanda Sheeran Paschal Descriptive Norms as an Additional Predictor in the Theory of Planned Behaviour A Meta Analysis 2003 a b Wilson K L Lizzio A J Zauner S Gallois C 2001 Social rules for managing attempted interpersonal domination in the workplace Influence of status and gender Sex Roles 44 3 4 129 154 doi 10 1023 a 1010998802612 S2CID 142800037 Attitudes behavior and social context the role of norms and group membership Deborah J Terry Michael A Hogg Mahwah N J L Erlbaum Associates 2000 ISBN 0 585 17974 3 OCLC 44961884 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint others link Author index for volume 50 Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 50 2 411 1991 doi 10 1016 0749 5978 91 90029 s ISSN 0749 5978 Voss Thomas Game Theoretical Perspectives on the Emergence of Social Norms Social Norms 2001 p 105 Bicchieri Cristina 2006 The Grammar of Society The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms New York Cambridge University Press Ch 1 a b Voss 2001 p 105Further reading Edit Scholia has a topic profile for Social norm Axelrod Robert 1984 The Evolution of Cooperation New York Basic Books ISBN 9780465021222 Appelbaum R P Carr D Duneir M Giddens A 2009 Conformity Deviance and Crime Introduction to Sociology New York NY W W Norton amp Company Inc p 173 Becker H S 1982 Culture A Sociological View Yale Review 71 4 513 527 Bicchieri C 2006 The Grammar of Society The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms New York Cambridge University Press Blumer H 1956 Sociological Analysis and the Variable American Sociological Review 21 6 683 690 doi 10 2307 2088418 JSTOR 2088418 S2CID 146998430 Boyd R amp Richerson P J 1985 Culture and the Evolutionary Process Chicago University of Chicago Press Burt R S 1987 Social Contagion and Innovation Cohesive Versus Structural Equivalence American Journal of Sociology 92 6 1287 1335 doi 10 1086 228667 S2CID 22380365 Rimal Rajiv N 2016 Social Norms A Review Review of Communication Research 4 1 1 28 doi 10 12840 issn 2255 4165 2016 04 01 008 Cialdini R 2007 Descriptive Social Norms as Underappreciated Sources of Social Control Psychometrika 72 2 263 268 doi 10 1007 s11336 006 1560 6 S2CID 121708702 Druzin Bryan H 24 June 2012 Eating Peas with One s Fingers A Semiotic Approach to Law and Social Norms International Journal for the Semiotics of Law Revue internationale de Semiotique juridique 26 2 257 274 doi 10 1007 s11196 012 9271 z S2CID 85439929 Durkheim E 1915 The Elementary Forms of the Religious Life New York Free Press Elster Jon 1 November 1989 Social Norms and Economic Theory Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 4 99 117 doi 10 1257 jep 3 4 99 hdl 10535 3264 S2CID 154638062 Fehr Ernst Fischbacher Urs Gachter Simon March 2002 Strong reciprocity human cooperation and the enforcement of social norms PDF Human Nature 13 1 1 25 doi 10 1007 s12110 002 1012 7 PMID 26192593 S2CID 2901235 Archived PDF from the original on 2019 03 26 Fine G A 2001 Social Norms ed by Michael Hechter and Karl Dieter Opp New York NY Russell Sage Foundation Greif A 1994 Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies Journal of Political Economy 102 5 912 950 doi 10 1086 261959 S2CID 153431326 Hechter M amp Karl Dieter Opp eds 2001 Social Norms New York Russell Sage Foundation Heiss J 1981 Social Roles In Social Psychology Sociological Perspectives Rosenburg M amp Turner R H eds New York Basic Books Hochschild A 1989 The Economy of Gratitude In D D Franks amp E D McCarthy Eds The Sociology of Emotions Original Essays and Research Papers Greenwich CT JAI Press Horne C 2001 Social Norms In M Hechter amp K Opp Eds New York NY Russell Sage Foundation Kahneman D Miller D T 1986 Norm Theory Comparing reality to its alternatives PDF Psychological Review 80 2 136 153 doi 10 1037 0033 295x 93 2 136 S2CID 7706059 Archived from the original PDF on 2020 07 11 Kollock P 1994 The emergence of exchange structures An experimental study of uncertainty commitment and trust American Journal of Sociology 100 2 313 45 doi 10 1086 230539 S2CID 144646491 Kohn M L 1977 Class and Conformity A Study in Values 2nd ed Chicago IL University of Chicago Press Macy M W Skvoretz J 1998 The evolution of trust and cooperation between strangers A computational model American Sociological Review 63 5 638 660 doi 10 2307 2657332 JSTOR 2657332 Mark N 1998 Birds of a feather sing together Social Forces 77 2 453 485 doi 10 1093 sf 77 2 453 S2CID 143739215 McElreath Richard Boyd Robert Richerson Peter J February 2003 Shared Norms and the Evolution of Ethnic Markers PDF Current Anthropology 44 1 122 130 doi 10 1086 345689 S2CID 8796947 Archived from the original PDF on 2019 03 07 Opp K 1982 The evolutionary emergence of norms British Journal of Social Psychology 21 2 139 149 doi 10 1111 j 2044 8309 1982 tb00522 x Posner Eric A 1996 The Regulation of Groups The Influence of Legal and Nonlegal Sanctions on Collective Action The University of Chicago Law Review 63 1 133 197 doi 10 2307 1600068 JSTOR 1600068 Posner E 2000 Law and Social Norms Cambridge MA Harvard University Press Prentice D A Miller D T 1993 Pluralistic ignorance and alcohol use on campus Some consequences of misperceiving the social norm Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 64 2 243 256 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 470 522 doi 10 1037 0022 3514 64 2 243 PMID 8433272 Schultz P Wesley Nolan Jessica M Cialdini Robert B Goldstein Noah J Griskevicius Vladas 25 November 2016 The Constructive Destructive and Reconstructive Power of Social Norms Psychological Science 18 5 429 434 doi 10 1111 j 1467 9280 2007 01917 x hdl 10211 3 199684 PMID 17576283 S2CID 19200458 Scott J F 1971 Internalization of Norms A Sociological Theory of Moral Commitment Englewoods Cliffs N J Prentice Hall Ullmann Margalit E 1977 The Emergence of Norms Oxford Oxford University Press Yamagishi T Cook K S Watabe M 1998 Uncertainty trust and commitment formation in the United States and Japan American Journal of Sociology 104 1 165 194 doi 10 1086 210005 S2CID 144931651 Young H P 2008 Social norms The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition External links EditBicchieri Cristina Muldoon Ryan Social Norms In Zalta Edward N ed Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Social norm amp oldid 1132454548, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.