fbpx
Wikipedia

New classical macroeconomics

New classical macroeconomics, sometimes simply called new classical economics, is a school of thought in macroeconomics that builds its analysis entirely on a neoclassical framework. Specifically, it emphasizes the importance of rigorous foundations based on microeconomics, especially rational expectations.

New classical macroeconomics strives to provide neoclassical microeconomic foundations for macroeconomic analysis. This is in contrast with its rival new Keynesian school that uses microfoundations, such as price stickiness and imperfect competition, to generate macroeconomic models similar to earlier, Keynesian ones.[1]

History edit

Classical economics is the term used for the first modern school of economics. The publication of Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations in 1776 is considered to be the birth of the school. Perhaps the central idea behind it is on the ability of the market to be self-correcting as well as being the most superior institution in allocating resources. The central assumption implied is that all individuals maximize their utility.

The so-called marginal revolution that occurred in Europe in the late 19th century, led by Carl Menger, William Stanley Jevons, and Léon Walras, gave rise to what is known as neoclassical economics. This neoclassical formulation had also been formalized by Alfred Marshall. However, it was the general equilibrium of Walras that helped solidify the research in economic science as a mathematical and deductive enterprise, the essence of which is still neoclassical and makes up what is currently found in mainstream economics textbooks to this day.

The neoclassical school dominated the field up until the Great Depression of the 1930s. Then, however, with the publication of The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money by John Maynard Keynes in 1936,[2] certain neoclassical assumptions were rejected. Keynes proposed an aggregated framework to explain macroeconomic behavior, leading thus to the current distinction between micro- and macroeconomics. Of particular importance in Keynes' theories was his explanation of economic behavior as also being led by "animal spirits". In this sense, it limited the role for the so-called rational (maximizing) agent.

The Post-World War II period saw the widespread implementation of Keynesian economic policy in the United States and Western European countries. Its dominance in the field by the 1970s was best reflected by the controversial statement attributed to US President Richard Nixon and economist Milton Friedman: "We are all Keynesians now".

Problems arose during the 1973–75 recession which was largely triggered by the 1973 oil crisis. The nascent classical economists ignored the broader global economic conditions of the time in favor of targeting Keynesian policy responses for continued unemployment, high inflation and stagnant economic growth—stagflation. Conversely, the emerging global markets left traditional Keynesian schools struggling to reconcile the Phillips curve with the current economic conditions, which ruled out concurrent high inflation and high unemployment.

Emergence in response to stagflation edit

The New Classical school emerged in the 1970s as a response to what were perceived as failures of Keynesian economics to explain stagflation. New Classical and monetarist criticisms led by Robert Lucas, Jr. and Milton Friedman respectively forced a labored rethinking of Keynesian economics. In particular, Lucas designed the Lucas critique primarily as a means to cast doubt on the Keynesian model. This strengthened the case for macro models to be based on microeconomics.

After the 1970s, the New Classical school for a while became the dominant school in Macroeconomics.

New neoclassical synthesis edit

Prior to the late 1990s, macroeconomics was split between new Keynesian work on market imperfections demonstrated with small models and new classical work on real business cycle theory that used fully specified general equilibrium models and used changes in technology to explain fluctuations in economic output.[3] The new neoclassical synthesis developed as a consensus on the best way to explain short-run fluctuations in the economy.[4][5]

The new synthesis took elements from both schools. New classical economics contributed the methodology behind real business cycle theory[6] and new Keynesian economics contributed nominal rigidities (slow moving and periodic, rather than continuous, price changes also called sticky prices).[7] The new synthesis provides the theoretical foundation for much of contemporary mainstream economics.[8][7][5]

Analytic method edit

The new classical perspective takes root in three diagnostic sources of fluctuations in growth: the productivity wedge, the capital wedge, and the labor wedge. Through the neoclassical perspective and business cycle accounting one can look at the diagnostics and find the main ‘culprits’ for fluctuations in the real economy.

  • A productivity/efficiency wedge is a simple measure of aggregate production efficiency. In relation to the Great Depression, a productivity wedge means the economy is less productive given the capital and labor resources available in the economy.
  • A capital wedge is a gap between the intertemporal marginal rate of substitution in consumption and the marginal product of capital. In this wedge, there's a “deadweight” loss that affects capital accumulation and savings decisions acting as a distortionary capital (savings) tax.
  • A labor wedge is the ratio between the marginal rate of substitution of consumption for leisure and the marginal product of labor and acts as a distortionary labor tax, making hiring workers less profitable (i.e. labor market frictions).

Foundation, axioms and assumptions edit

New classical economics is based on Walrasian assumptions. All agents are assumed to maximize utility on the basis of rational expectations. At any one time, the economy is assumed to have a unique equilibrium at full employment or potential output achieved through price and wage adjustment. In other words, the market clears at all times.

New classical economics has also pioneered the use of representative agent models. Such models have received severe neoclassical criticism, pointing to the disjuncture between microeconomic behavior and macroeconomic results, as indicated by Alan Kirman.[9]

The concept of rational expectations was originally used by John Muth,[10] and was popularized by Lucas.[11] One of the most famous new classical models is the real business cycle model, developed by Edward C. Prescott and Finn E. Kydland.

Legacy edit

It turned out that pure new classical models had low explanatory and predictive power. The models could not simultaneously explain both the duration and magnitude of actual cycles. Additionally, the model's key result that only unexpected changes in money can affect the business cycle and unemployment did not stand empirical tests.[12][13][14][15][16]

The mainstream turned to the new neoclassical synthesis.[8][17][5] Most economists, even most new classical economists, accepted the new Keynesian notion that for several reasons wages and prices do not move quickly and smoothly to the values needed for long-run equilibrium between quantities supplied and demanded. Therefore, they also accept the monetarist and new Keynesian view that monetary policy can have a considerable effect in the short run.[18] The new classical macroeconomics contributed the rational expectations hypothesis and the idea of intertemporal optimisation to new Keynesian economics and the new neoclassical synthesis.[12]

Peter Galbács thinks that critics have a superficial and incomplete understanding of the new classical macroeconomics. He argues that one should not forget the conditional character of the new classical doctrines. If prices are completely flexible and if public expectations are completely rational and if real economic shocks are white noises, monetary policy cannot affect unemployment or production and any intention to control the real economy ends up only in a change in the rate of inflation. However, and this is the point, if any of these conditions does not hold, monetary policy can be effective again. So, if any of the conditions necessary for the equivalence does not hold, countercyclical fiscal policy can be effective. Controlling the real economy is possible perhaps in a Keynesian style if government regains its potential to exert this control. Therefore, actually, new classical macroeconomics highlights the conditions under which economic policy can be effective and not the predestined inefficiency of economic policy. Countercyclical aspirations need not to be abandoned, only the playing-field of economic policy got narrowed by new classicals. While Keynes urged active countercyclical efforts of fiscal policy, these efforts are not predestined to fail not even in the new classical theory, only the conditions necessary for the efficiency of countercyclical efforts were specified by new classicals.[19]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Chapter 1. Snowdon, Brian and Vane, Howard R., (2005). Modern Macroeconomics: Its Origin, Development and Current State. Edward Elgar Publishing, ISBN 1-84542-208-2
  2. ^ Skidelsky, Robert (1996). "The Influence of the Great Depression on Keynes's General Theory" (PDF). History of Economics Review. 25 (1): 78–87. doi:10.1080/10370196.1996.11733219.
  3. ^ Blanchard 2000, p. 1404.
  4. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory (May 2006). "The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer" (PDF). pp. 14–15.
  5. ^ a b c Goodfriend, Marvin and King, Robert G. The New Neoclassical Synthesis and The Role of Monetary Policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Working papers. June 1997. No. 98–5. http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/working_papers/1998/pdf/wp98-5.pdf.
  6. ^ Kocherlakota 2010, p. 12.
  7. ^ a b Mankiw, N. Gregory (May 2006). "The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer" (PDF).
  8. ^ a b Woodford, Michael. Convergence in Macroeconomics: Elements of the New Synthesis. January 2008. http://www.columbia.edu/~mw2230/Convergence_AEJ.pdf.
  9. ^ Kirkman, Alan P. (1992). "Whom or What does the Representative Individual Represent?". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 6 (2): 117–136. doi:10.1257/jep.6.2.117. JSTOR 2138411.
  10. ^ Muth, John F. (1961). "Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements". Econometrica. 29 (3): 315–335. doi:10.2307/1909635. JSTOR 1909635.
  11. ^ Lucas, Robert E. (1972). "Expectations and the Neutrality of Money". Journal of Economic Theory. 4 (2): 103–124. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.592.6178. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(72)90142-1.
  12. ^ a b Snowdon, Brian (Fall 2007). "The New Classical Counter-Revolution: False Path or Illuminating Complement?" (PDF). Eastern Economic Journal. 33 (4): 541–562. doi:10.1057/eej.2007.40. JSTOR 20642377. S2CID 154761891.
  13. ^ Gilbert, Evan; Michie, Jonathan (1997). "New Classical Macroeconomic Theory and Fiscal Rules: Some Methodological Problems". Contributions to Political Economy. 16 (1): 1–21. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.cpe.a014051.
  14. ^ Greenwald, Bruce C.; Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1987). "Keynesian, New Keynesian, and New Classical Economics". Oxford Economic Papers. 39 (1): 119–133. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.692.8775. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a041773.
  15. ^ Mark Thoma, New Classical, New Keynesian, and Real Business Cycle Models, Economist's View
  16. ^ Seidman, Laurence (Fall 2007). "Reply to: "The New Classical Counter-Revolution: False Path or Illuminating Complement?"" (PDF). Eastern Economic Journal. 33 (4): 563–565. doi:10.1057/eej.2007.41. JSTOR 20642378. S2CID 153260374.
  17. ^ Mankiw, N. Greg. The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer. May 2006. p. 14–15. http://scholar.harvard.edu/files/mankiw/files/macroeconomist_as_scientist.pdf?m=1360042085.
  18. ^ Kevin Hoover (2008). "New Classical Macroeconomics", econlib.org
  19. ^ Galbács, Peter (2015). The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics. A Positive Critique. Contributions to Economics. Heidelberg/New York/Dordrecht/London: Springer. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-17578-2. ISBN 978-3-319-17578-2.

Further reading edit

  • Artis, Michael (1992). "Macroecononomic Theory". In Maloney, John (ed.). What's New in Economics?. New York: Manchester University Press. pp. 135–167. ISBN 978-0-7190-3280-6.
  • Barro, Robert J. (1989). "New Classicals and Keynesians, or the Good Guys and the Bad Guys" (PDF). Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics. 125 (3): 263–273. doi:10.3386/w2982.
  • Hoover, Kevin D. (1988). The New Classical Macroeconomics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. ISBN 978-0-631-14605-6.

External links edit

classical, macroeconomics, confused, with, neoclassical, economics, sometimes, simply, called, classical, economics, school, thought, macroeconomics, that, builds, analysis, entirely, neoclassical, framework, specifically, emphasizes, importance, rigorous, fou. Not to be confused with Neoclassical economics New classical macroeconomics sometimes simply called new classical economics is a school of thought in macroeconomics that builds its analysis entirely on a neoclassical framework Specifically it emphasizes the importance of rigorous foundations based on microeconomics especially rational expectations New classical macroeconomics strives to provide neoclassical microeconomic foundations for macroeconomic analysis This is in contrast with its rival new Keynesian school that uses microfoundations such as price stickiness and imperfect competition to generate macroeconomic models similar to earlier Keynesian ones 1 Contents 1 History 1 1 Emergence in response to stagflation 1 2 New neoclassical synthesis 2 Analytic method 3 Foundation axioms and assumptions 4 Legacy 5 See also 6 References 7 Further reading 8 External linksHistory editClassical economics is the term used for the first modern school of economics The publication of Adam Smith s The Wealth of Nations in 1776 is considered to be the birth of the school Perhaps the central idea behind it is on the ability of the market to be self correcting as well as being the most superior institution in allocating resources The central assumption implied is that all individuals maximize their utility The so called marginal revolution that occurred in Europe in the late 19th century led by Carl Menger William Stanley Jevons and Leon Walras gave rise to what is known as neoclassical economics This neoclassical formulation had also been formalized by Alfred Marshall However it was the general equilibrium of Walras that helped solidify the research in economic science as a mathematical and deductive enterprise the essence of which is still neoclassical and makes up what is currently found in mainstream economics textbooks to this day The neoclassical school dominated the field up until the Great Depression of the 1930s Then however with the publication of The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money by John Maynard Keynes in 1936 2 certain neoclassical assumptions were rejected Keynes proposed an aggregated framework to explain macroeconomic behavior leading thus to the current distinction between micro and macroeconomics Of particular importance in Keynes theories was his explanation of economic behavior as also being led by animal spirits In this sense it limited the role for the so called rational maximizing agent The Post World War II period saw the widespread implementation of Keynesian economic policy in the United States and Western European countries Its dominance in the field by the 1970s was best reflected by the controversial statement attributed to US President Richard Nixon and economist Milton Friedman We are all Keynesians now Problems arose during the 1973 75 recession which was largely triggered by the 1973 oil crisis The nascent classical economists ignored the broader global economic conditions of the time in favor of targeting Keynesian policy responses for continued unemployment high inflation and stagnant economic growth stagflation Conversely the emerging global markets left traditional Keynesian schools struggling to reconcile the Phillips curve with the current economic conditions which ruled out concurrent high inflation and high unemployment Emergence in response to stagflation edit The New Classical school emerged in the 1970s as a response to what were perceived as failures of Keynesian economics to explain stagflation New Classical and monetarist criticisms led by Robert Lucas Jr and Milton Friedman respectively forced a labored rethinking of Keynesian economics In particular Lucas designed the Lucas critique primarily as a means to cast doubt on the Keynesian model This strengthened the case for macro models to be based on microeconomics After the 1970s the New Classical school for a while became the dominant school in Macroeconomics New neoclassical synthesis edit Prior to the late 1990s macroeconomics was split between new Keynesian work on market imperfections demonstrated with small models and new classical work on real business cycle theory that used fully specified general equilibrium models and used changes in technology to explain fluctuations in economic output 3 The new neoclassical synthesis developed as a consensus on the best way to explain short run fluctuations in the economy 4 5 The new synthesis took elements from both schools New classical economics contributed the methodology behind real business cycle theory 6 and new Keynesian economics contributed nominal rigidities slow moving and periodic rather than continuous price changes also called sticky prices 7 The new synthesis provides the theoretical foundation for much of contemporary mainstream economics 8 7 5 Analytic method editThe new classical perspective takes root in three diagnostic sources of fluctuations in growth the productivity wedge the capital wedge and the labor wedge Through the neoclassical perspective and business cycle accounting one can look at the diagnostics and find the main culprits for fluctuations in the real economy A productivity efficiency wedge is a simple measure of aggregate production efficiency In relation to the Great Depression a productivity wedge means the economy is less productive given the capital and labor resources available in the economy A capital wedge is a gap between the intertemporal marginal rate of substitution in consumption and the marginal product of capital In this wedge there s a deadweight loss that affects capital accumulation and savings decisions acting as a distortionary capital savings tax A labor wedge is the ratio between the marginal rate of substitution of consumption for leisure and the marginal product of labor and acts as a distortionary labor tax making hiring workers less profitable i e labor market frictions Foundation axioms and assumptions editNew classical economics is based on Walrasian assumptions All agents are assumed to maximize utility on the basis of rational expectations At any one time the economy is assumed to have a unique equilibrium at full employment or potential output achieved through price and wage adjustment In other words the market clears at all times New classical economics has also pioneered the use of representative agent models Such models have received severe neoclassical criticism pointing to the disjuncture between microeconomic behavior and macroeconomic results as indicated by Alan Kirman 9 The concept of rational expectations was originally used by John Muth 10 and was popularized by Lucas 11 One of the most famous new classical models is the real business cycle model developed by Edward C Prescott and Finn E Kydland Legacy editIt turned out that pure new classical models had low explanatory and predictive power The models could not simultaneously explain both the duration and magnitude of actual cycles Additionally the model s key result that only unexpected changes in money can affect the business cycle and unemployment did not stand empirical tests 12 13 14 15 16 The mainstream turned to the new neoclassical synthesis 8 17 5 Most economists even most new classical economists accepted the new Keynesian notion that for several reasons wages and prices do not move quickly and smoothly to the values needed for long run equilibrium between quantities supplied and demanded Therefore they also accept the monetarist and new Keynesian view that monetary policy can have a considerable effect in the short run 18 The new classical macroeconomics contributed the rational expectations hypothesis and the idea of intertemporal optimisation to new Keynesian economics and the new neoclassical synthesis 12 Peter Galbacs thinks that critics have a superficial and incomplete understanding of the new classical macroeconomics He argues that one should not forget the conditional character of the new classical doctrines If prices are completely flexible and if public expectations are completely rational and if real economic shocks are white noises monetary policy cannot affect unemployment or production and any intention to control the real economy ends up only in a change in the rate of inflation However and this is the point if any of these conditions does not hold monetary policy can be effective again So if any of the conditions necessary for the equivalence does not hold countercyclical fiscal policy can be effective Controlling the real economy is possible perhaps in a Keynesian style if government regains its potential to exert this control Therefore actually new classical macroeconomics highlights the conditions under which economic policy can be effective and not the predestined inefficiency of economic policy Countercyclical aspirations need not to be abandoned only the playing field of economic policy got narrowed by new classicals While Keynes urged active countercyclical efforts of fiscal policy these efforts are not predestined to fail not even in the new classical theory only the conditions necessary for the efficiency of countercyclical efforts were specified by new classicals 19 See also editNeoclassical synthesisReferences edit Chapter 1 Snowdon Brian and Vane Howard R 2005 Modern Macroeconomics Its Origin Development and Current State Edward Elgar Publishing ISBN 1 84542 208 2 Skidelsky Robert 1996 The Influence of the Great Depression on Keynes s General Theory PDF History of Economics Review 25 1 78 87 doi 10 1080 10370196 1996 11733219 Blanchard 2000 p 1404 sfn error no target CITEREFBlanchard2000 help Mankiw N Gregory May 2006 The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer PDF pp 14 15 a b c Goodfriend Marvin and King Robert G The New Neoclassical Synthesis and The Role of Monetary Policy Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working papers June 1997 No 98 5 http www richmondfed org publications research working papers 1998 pdf wp98 5 pdf Kocherlakota 2010 p 12 sfn error no target CITEREFKocherlakota2010 help a b Mankiw N Gregory May 2006 The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer PDF a b Woodford Michael Convergence in Macroeconomics Elements of the New Synthesis January 2008 http www columbia edu mw2230 Convergence AEJ pdf Kirkman Alan P 1992 Whom or What does the Representative Individual Represent Journal of Economic Perspectives 6 2 117 136 doi 10 1257 jep 6 2 117 JSTOR 2138411 Muth John F 1961 Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements Econometrica 29 3 315 335 doi 10 2307 1909635 JSTOR 1909635 Lucas Robert E 1972 Expectations and the Neutrality of Money Journal of Economic Theory 4 2 103 124 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 592 6178 doi 10 1016 0022 0531 72 90142 1 a b Snowdon Brian Fall 2007 The New Classical Counter Revolution False Path or Illuminating Complement PDF Eastern Economic Journal 33 4 541 562 doi 10 1057 eej 2007 40 JSTOR 20642377 S2CID 154761891 Gilbert Evan Michie Jonathan 1997 New Classical Macroeconomic Theory and Fiscal Rules Some Methodological Problems Contributions to Political Economy 16 1 1 21 doi 10 1093 oxfordjournals cpe a014051 Greenwald Bruce C Stiglitz Joseph E 1987 Keynesian New Keynesian and New Classical Economics Oxford Economic Papers 39 1 119 133 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 692 8775 doi 10 1093 oxfordjournals oep a041773 Mark Thoma New Classical New Keynesian and Real Business Cycle Models Economist s View Seidman Laurence Fall 2007 Reply to The New Classical Counter Revolution False Path or Illuminating Complement PDF Eastern Economic Journal 33 4 563 565 doi 10 1057 eej 2007 41 JSTOR 20642378 S2CID 153260374 Mankiw N Greg The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer May 2006 p 14 15 http scholar harvard edu files mankiw files macroeconomist as scientist pdf m 1360042085 Kevin Hoover 2008 New Classical Macroeconomics econlib org Galbacs Peter 2015 The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics A Positive Critique Contributions to Economics Heidelberg New York Dordrecht London Springer doi 10 1007 978 3 319 17578 2 ISBN 978 3 319 17578 2 Further reading editArtis Michael 1992 Macroecononomic Theory In Maloney John ed What s New in Economics New York Manchester University Press pp 135 167 ISBN 978 0 7190 3280 6 Barro Robert J 1989 New Classicals and Keynesians or the Good Guys and the Bad Guys PDF Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics 125 3 263 273 doi 10 3386 w2982 Hoover Kevin D 1988 The New Classical Macroeconomics Oxford Basil Blackwell ISBN 978 0 631 14605 6 External links editHoover Kevin D 2008 New Classical Macroeconomics In David R Henderson ed Concise Encyclopedia of Economics 2nd ed Indianapolis Library of Economics and Liberty ISBN 978 0865976658 OCLC 237794267 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title New classical macroeconomics amp oldid 1209263242, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.