fbpx
Wikipedia

Logrolling

Logrolling is the trading of favors, or quid pro quo, such as vote trading by legislative members to obtain passage of actions of interest to each legislative member.[1] In organizational analysis, it refers to a practice in which different organizations promote each other's agendas, each in the expectation that the other will reciprocate. In an academic context, the Nuttall Encyclopedia describes logrolling as "mutual praise by authors of each other's work". Where intricate tactics or strategy are involved, the process may be called horse trading.

Concept and origin edit

There are three types of logrolling:

  • Logrolling in direct democracies: a few individuals vote openly, and votes are easy to trade, rearrange, and observe. Direct democracy is pervasive in representative assemblies and small-government units
  • Implicit logrolling: large bodies of voters decide complex issues and trade votes without a formal vote trade (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2])
  • Distributive logrolling: enables policymakers to achieve their public goals. These policymakers logroll to ensure that their district policies and pork barrel packages are put into practice regardless of whether their policies are actually efficient (Evans 1994[3] and Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]).

Distributive logrolling is the most prevalent kind of logrolling found in a democratic system of governance.[4]

Quid pro quo sums up the concept of logrolling in the United States' political process today. Logrolling is the process by which politicians trade support for one issue or piece of legislation in exchange for another politician's support, especially by means of legislative votes (Holcombe 2006[5]). If a legislator logrolls, he initiates the trade of votes for one particular act or bill in order to secure votes on behalf of another act or bill. Logrolling means that two parties will pledge their mutual support, so both bills can attain a simple majority. For example, a vote on behalf of a tariff may be traded by a congressman for a vote from another congressman on behalf of an agricultural subsidy to ensure that both acts will gain a majority and pass through the legislature (Shughart 2008[6]). Logrolling cannot occur during presidential elections, where a vast voting population necessitates that individual votes have little political power, or during secret-ballot votes (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]). Because logrolling is pervasive in the political process, it is important to understand which external situations determine when, why, and how logrolling will occur, and whether it is beneficial, efficient, or neither.

Origins edit

 
Davy Crockett by William Henry Huddle, 1889.

The widest accepted origin is the old custom of neighbors assisting each other with the moving of logs. If two neighbors had cut a lot of timber that needed to be moved, it made more sense for them to work together to roll the logs.[7][8] In this way, it is similar to a barn-raising where a neighbor comes and helps a family build their barn, and, in turn, that family goes and returns the favor, helping him build his. Here is an example of the term's original use:

"A family comes to sit in the forest," wrote an observer in 1835; "Their neighbors lay down their employments, shoulder their axes, and come in to the log-rolling. They spend the day in hard labor, and then retire, leaving the newcomers their good wishes, and a habitation."[9]

American frontiersman Davy Crockett was one of the first to apply the term to legislation:

The first known use of the term was by Congressman Davy Crockett, who said on the floor (of the U.S. House of Representatives) in 1835, "my people don't like me to log-roll in their business, and vote away pre-emption rights to fellows in other states that never kindle a fire on their own land."[10]

Choice to logroll edit

Human beings, whether ignorant or informed, rational or irrational, logical or illogical, determine individual and group action through choices. Economics studies these choices, including the choice to logroll, and their particular influence within the market sector (Schwartz 1977[11]). In America, political and economic decisions are usually made by politicians elected to legislative assemblies, and not directly by the citizenry (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]). Although legislative votes are recorded and are available to the American public, legislators can exchange their votes on issues they do not care much about for votes on other issues that are more important to their personal agendas (Holcombe 2006[5]). In The Calculus of Consent, James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock explore the relationship between individual choice in the voting process and in the marketplace, specifically within logrolling. Logrolling vote trades, like any activity within the marketplace, must be mutually beneficial (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]).

A vote trade is like a legislative IOU. When a legislator needs a few more votes to acquire a simple majority, he will seek support through a vote exchange. He will promise a fellow legislator an IOU vote for another piece of legislation in return for a vote on his own act or bill. Legislators who logroll within a small body, for example, the U.S. House or Senate, have incentive to honor their IOU votes because they cannot have their reputations tainted if they wish to be effective politicians (Holcombe 2006[5]).

Logrolling and the role of preference edit

People have varying preferences, and make decisions at the margin to maximize their utility and improve their welfare. The same is true for legislators, who all enter office with different agendas, passions, and goals. Ideological diversity plays a significant role in the result of a vote and carries with it a significant cost. In addition, legislators will favor interests that offer them the most support. Legislative votes are determined by the intensity of personal preference, desires of constituents, and, ultimately, what will lead to the particular legislator's greatest utility. When people have ideologies at opposite ends of the political spectrum, it's difficult to ensure a simple majority, so buying a supermajority vote through logrolling may be the most cost effective (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]).

In the General Possibility Theorem, Kenneth Arrow argues that if a legislative consensus can be reached through a simple majority, then minimum conditions must be satisfied, and these conditions must provide a superior ranking to any subset of alternative votes (Arrow 1963[12]). A bill must be attractive to a legislator, or else he will not cast his vote for it. A vote, by the pure nature of the voting process, demonstrates explicit interest in whatever is voted upon. In logrolling, a superior ranking means that the marginal benefit of the vote is greater than any alternatives, so exchanging votes is worthwhile. The General Possibility Theorem necessitates that allocating one vote for another must constitute true utility and a sincere vote. Arrow's theory may place more restrictions and limitations on an individual voter's preferences than Buchanan and Tullock's; regardless, individuals will always choose the option they value most.

Logrolling to reach the optimal decision edit

Decisions reach an optimum only when they are unanimous, when votes are not coerced and everyone has veto power (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]). Unanimous votes, however, are not required for the American voting process. This is why some logrolling advocates argue that logrolling must be allowed within a democracy—sometimes there may not be a "best" or "most efficient" option on a vote.

Logrolling creates a market within which votes are exchanged as a sort of currency, and thus, facilitates the political process that produces the highest valued outcomes (Holcombe 2006[5]). If individual participants recognize the value of their own vote, they are motivated to trade. When methods of trade do not conflict with given standards or ethical procedures, individuals naturally seek mutually advantageous vote trades. An individual may effectually, but imperfectly, "sell" his vote on a particular issue to, in return, secure votes from other individuals on behalf of legislation he prefers (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]).

Logrolling has one necessary condition: benefits from the public activity must be significantly more concentrated or localized than the costs. In economics, decisions are made at the margin. Logrolling depends on the reality that the marginal benefit (or utility) of at least some elected officials, or the citizenry, will increase when the legislation is passed (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]). Any economist will consider the immediate opportunity cost of the logrolling procedure within the legislative body, as well as the external cost of the vote (the cost to enact and see the bill through to fruition).

When transaction costs are low and parties involved are perfectly informed, a mutually beneficial agreement will occur: whoever values the property the highest will end up with it. This is what Ronald H. Coase proposed in his Theory of Property Rights in 1960. This theory holds true within the world of economics. In the American system of government, legislators have the incentive to logroll because transaction costs are low. When transaction costs are low, the Coase theorem says that the political marketplace (the decisions of the legislatures) will allocate resources to the highest valued point (Coase 1960[13]).

Typically, logrolling is a mechanism used to gain support for special interest and minority groups. However, because of the ideological mix that already exists within the legislature itself, minority views are often represented, even if only marginally. With low transaction costs, the Coase theorem will come into play. The highest valued outcome is chosen by the legislature, regardless the member's ideological stance or political affiliation (Holcombe 2006[5]).

The problem of cyclical majorities may arise with the absence of logrolling. The cyclical majority problem occurs when voters are faced with multiple voting options but cannot choose the option they most prefer, since it is not available. Voters must consider whether the alternative option is closer to their original preference (Bara and Weale 2006[14]). However, when logrolling is allowed, the highest valued outcome is secure without the threat of a cyclical majority. For example, suppose a country road in West Virginia is in disrepair. The local congressman proposes a bill to have the main road in his community resurfaced and paved. The road leads to a town of merely 600 residents. Thus, the other legislators will vote against the measure because the funding is not worthwhile to their constituents. In a logrolling system, the local legislator can use his vote to bargain with his fellow legislators. He will exchange his vote for his fellow legislators' bills to promote, for instance, the construction of new hospitals and the increase of veteran's benefits, in return for their votes to repair the road (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]).

Logrolling: An example edit

Table 1-1
Agriculture Tax Vote School Tax Vote Fire Tax Vote
Tanya $300 $200 Y $150 $200 N $100 $200 N
Alvin $150 $200 N $350 $200 Y $150 $200 N
Rebecca $100 $200 N $50 $200 N $225 $200 Y
Total $550 $600 Inefficient $550 $600 Inefficient $475 $600 Inefficient

Table 1-1 explains another example of logrolling. In the example, we have three individuals: Tanya, Alvin, and Rebecca. Tanya favors subsidies for agriculture, Alvin favors school construction, and Rebecca favors the recruitment of more firefighters. It seems as if the proposals are doomed to fail because each is opposed by a majority of voters. Even so, this may not be the outcome. Tanya may visit Rebecca and tell her that she will vote for Rebecca's bill to recruit more firefighters so long as Rebecca votes for her policy, subsidies for agriculture, in return. Now both proposals will win because they have gained a simple majority (Table 1-2), even though in reality the subsidy is opposed by two of the three voters. It's easy to see the Coase theorem at work in examples like this. Here, transaction costs are low, so mutually beneficial agreements are found, and the person who values the service the most will hold it (Browning and Browning 1979[15]). Still, outcomes may be inefficient.

Efficient logrolling edit

Table 1-2
Agriculture Tax Vote School Tax Vote Fire Tax Vote
Tanya $350 $200 Y $150 $200 N $100 $200 Y
Alvin $150 $200 N $350 $200 Y $200 $200 N
Rebecca $125 $200 Y $50 $200 N $300 $200 Y
Example $625 $600 Efficient $550 $600 Inefficient $600 $600 Efficient

If the sum of the total benefit of the legislation for all the voters is less than the cost of the legislation itself, the legislation is inefficient. Despite its inefficiency, however, it still may pass if logrolling is permitted. If Tanya trades her vote to recruit more firemen to Rebecca in exchange for Rebecca's vote in favor of agriculture subsidies, a mutually beneficial agreement will be reached, even though the outcome is inefficient. On the other hand, if the sum of the total benefit of the legislation for all voters is greater than the cost of the legislation itself, the legislation is efficient. If Tanya trades her vote once again for Rebecca's vote, both parties will reach a mutually beneficial agreement and an efficient outcome.

Minimum winning coalitions and logrolling edit

A minimum winning coalition is the smallest number of votes required to win the passage of a piece of legislation. Minimum winning coalitions demonstrate the importance of logrolling within a democracy, because the minimal winning coalition may be overthrown with the sway of a single vote. As previously mentioned, coalitions will buy a supermajority of votes if the support for the proposed legislation sways. If a legislator logrolls a few votes beyond the minimal winning coalition to his side, he will ensure that the final vote will be in favor of his legislation. In a way, vote trading does combine positions on distinct issues to form single legislative votes and packages (Stratmann 1992[16]). Logrolled votes transcend affiliations and party lines and become feasible outcomes preferred by a majority or winning coalition (Schwartz 1977[11]).

Logrolling in real politics edit

A problem in research is that it is impossible to identify vote trading directly within the House of Representatives or the Senate because roll call votes on specific goods are not observed (Irwin and Kroszner 1996[17]). However, examples of refurbished bills can shed some light on the working-out of logrolling within the legislature. For example, in 1930, the Smoot-Hawley tariff, the second-highest tariff in U.S. history, passed the House and Senate. Congress voted to increase tariffs exponentially, which worked to push the United States from a stagnant recession into a plummeting depression (Irwin and Kroszner 1996[17]). Strict party line votes suggest that partisan polarization in 1929 prevented the Smoot-Hawley bill from passing through Congress. The bill, however, was revamped, and legislators used logrolling to pass it through both chambers in 1930.

Omnibus bills can be an alternative market to logrolling. Various clauses are added to a bill to satisfy all involved parties sufficiently. However, large bills, like the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, require an in depth knowledge of 1,000 plus pages. Many sections of these types of bills are initially opposed but are later supported because of special benefit clauses (Evans 1994[3]).

Because logrolling allows special-interest groups a voice in the political process, programs that benefit a minority group can get the approval of a majority. However, this may not be in the best interest of the majority. Special-interest groups typically do not represent the typical voter, but rather, small branches of minority ideologies (Holcombe 2006[5]). Voting results with or without logrolling will differ only if the minority is more interested in an issue than the majority, enough to separate the marginal voters from the majority. Studies show that lobbying and political pressure exerted by special-interest groups are not atypical behavior in a modern democracy (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]). Conditions imposed upon the social choice of the legislature imply a more severe restriction on the individual voter's preferences than the theory of logrolling presented by Buchanan and Tullock and presumed by Arrow's General Possibility Theory (Wilson 1969[18]).

Critics reproach members of Congress for protecting their own electoral interests at the expense of the general welfare. Congressmen tend to distribute specialized benefits at a great cost and ignore the particular costs the legislation bears upon the taxpayers (Evans 1994[3]). Legislators, who seek their personal benefit via logrolling even though it may not benefit those who must pay for the measure, are known as maximizers. Maximizers only take into account their personal cost and electability, instead of the effects of their actions on other parties involved. In short, other taxpayers will pay for the policy even if it does not affect them (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]). Initially, maximizers will encourage other legislators to have the same selfish behavior because significant gains can be accrued in the short run. Buchanan and Tullock state that within a system of maximizers, all individuals are worse off than if they had all adopted Kantian norms of behavior.

Legislative bodies can expect higher government spending and taxation when logrolling is allowed to flourish. Logrolling does not imply excessive spending; members can trade tax reductions just as easily as they can trade pork barrel policies. The problem is that benefits of a vote only reach a particular portion of the population, while the tax costs that pay for the vote are spread throughout the entire populace, especially when the act depends on revenue from sales or income taxes. Benefits are concentrated in localities, and the costs are dispersed throughout the nation. Committee members can thus exploit pork barrel projects for electoral purposes. The citizenry is seen as a "common pool," used to finance projects through taxes. Somehow the citizens end up paying higher taxes than those who are not in a logroll system (Dalenberg and Duffy-Deno 1991[19] and Gilligan and Matsusaka 1995[20]). In a system where logrolling is permitted, a third party may bear the cost of the project, rather than those who receive the full benefit of the legislation. This is always inefficient.

The logic of collective action shows that votes for bills are motivated by politicians and are determined by a simple majority (Olson 1971[21]). Politicians are in the game to win it. Collective effort explains why farms acquire government subsidies at the expense of millions of consumers and why those in the textile industry benefit at the expense of clothing buyers (Shughart 2008[6]). Congressional committees ensure that each committee leader will create legislative coalitions to push his policies to fruition. Thus, ceteris paribus, members who receive such projects, are likely to vote in support of their leader's wishes (Evans 1994[3]).

Policymakers and congressmen have goals of power, and making their own mark in public policy, not pure aims of reelection (Dodd 1977[22]). Reelection does play a great part in the legislative process as a condition to achieving any other political goal. Thus, logrolling can be a powerful tool for committee chairs, who control the voting agendas (Evans 1994[3]). While committee leaders create the supermajority, they try to achieve their personal goals and help a bare majority of members achieve theirs. A skilled policy-oriented committee leader often seeks to exploit the goals of other members in order to construct legislation he or she will prefer (Arnold 1979[23] and Strahan 1989[24]).

Wafelijzerpolitiek edit

Wafelijzerpolitiek (lit. waffle iron politics) is a form of logrolling used in Belgium. Until the split of the unitary Belgium in several parts, the unitary government decided on the funds given to big projects. As there were usually two opposing groups of about equal size in Belgium, this norm resulted in the approval of two equally sized projects in the two parts of the country, with the funds given to the two projects being equal. As a result, one project was always overfunded. Many see wafelijzerpolitiek as the source of Belgium's high debt.

After the first state reformation in 1988, many big projects were decided regionally, so the number of wafelijzer projects went down. There are still some things that fall under the supervision of the federal government, where wafelijzerpolitiek still happens. One example is the Belgian railway network.

Another result of the wafelijzerpolitiek is the big useless works. As Flanders is a part of Belgium with many ports (e.g., big ports in Antwerp and Zeebrugge), for every investment in Flemish waterways there had to be an investment in Walloon waterways. Some results are the Ronquières inclined plane and the Strépy-Thieu boat lift.

Simple referendums edit

In a referendum on a simple issue, the voter cannot easily trade his own vote for a vote on a reciprocal favor. This is because first, he is unsure as to when and how the other issues will be voted upon, and second, he and his immediate neighbors represent a fraction of the total electorate. Thus, trading may not be worthwhile (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]).

Vote trading under a democratic, majority-rule institution is sometimes considered morally reprehensible behavior. However, the only perfect solution to rid the political system of distributive logrolling would be to develop a specific formula to weigh the costs and benefits of legislation perfectly and only allow efficient programs to be enacted (This is inconceivable. Therefore, logrolling must occur, but only by observing the constitutional rules that have been laid down as safeguards of democracy (Buchanan and Tullock 1962[2]).

Summary edit

The reality is that transaction costs are high, and most voters, who are ignorant of political issues and the political process, see little incentive to attempt to influence their local legislator's political decisions (Holcombe 2006[5]). It is also difficult for voters to be informed of their legislator's voting habits. Because of this, distributive logrolling will occur in democratic systems. Furthermore, it is the responsibility of the legislator to measure the costs and benefits of legislation and determine what is most efficient for his constituents. Logrolling will occur only if members of the legislature fail to gather enough votes for the passage of specific legislation. In essence, logrolling is a legal way to manipulate voter preference toward either an efficient or an inefficient outcome that would not otherwise be enacted (Browning 1979[15]).

Legality edit

Logrolling is illegal in numerous jurisdictions, and in some instances is a crime.[25] Sophisticated computational techniques have been developed for the detection and prosecution of this crime.[26]

Other usages edit

Spy Magazine ran a feature entitled "Logrolling in Our Time" that cited suspicious or humorous examples of mutually admiring book jacket blurbs by pairs of authors. Private Eye magazine regularly draws attention to alleged logrolling by authors in "books of the year" features published by British newspapers and magazines.[27][full citation needed]

Log rolling or a hodgepodge legislation in the Philippines also refers to any legislation that have several subjects on unrelated matters combined together. It is expressed in Article 6 Section 26.1 of the 1987 Philippine Constitution as a guarantee to prevent surprise or fraud from the legislature.[28]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ [1] – Education 2020, government course; definition of logrolling: "An agreement by two or more lawmakers to support each other's bills."
  2. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon (1962). The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Press.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  3. ^ a b c d e Evans, Diana (1994). "Policy and Pork: The Use of Pork Barrel Projects to Build Policy Coalitions in the House of Representatives". American Journal of Political Science. 4. 38 (4): 894–917. doi:10.2307/2111726. JSTOR 2111726.
  4. ^ "Logrolling: A Glossary of Political Economy Terms - Dr. Paul M. Johnson".
  5. ^ a b c d e f g Holcombe, Randall (2006). Public Sector Economics: The Role of Government in the American Economy. New Jersey: Prentice Hall. pp. 179–181.
  6. ^ a b Shughart II, William. "Public Choice". The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Library of Economics and Liberty. Retrieved April 17, 2020.
  7. ^ Online Etymology Dictionary
  8. ^ . Archived from the original on June 26, 2008. Retrieved June 9, 2008.
  9. ^ Barnhart, David K.; Metcalf, Allan A. (1999). America in So Many Words: Words That Have Shaped America. Houghton Mifflin Harcourt. p. 95. ISBN 0-618-00270-7.
  10. ^ Crockett, Davy (1835). An account of Col. Crockett's tour to the North and down East: in the year of Our Lord one thousand eight hundred and thirty-four. His object being to examine the grand manufacturing establishments of the country; and also to find out the condition of its literature and its morals, the extent of its commerce, and the practical operation of "The Experiment"... E. L. Carey and A. Hart.
  11. ^ a b Schwartz, Thomas (1977). "Collection of Issues and Vote Trading". The American Political Science Review. 71 (3): 999–1010. doi:10.2307/1960103. JSTOR 1960103. S2CID 154434919.
  12. ^ Arrow, Kenneth (1963). Social Choice and Individual Values, 2nd Ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
  13. ^ Coase, Ronald H. (1960). "The Problem of Social Cost" (PDF). The Journal of Law and Economics. 3: 1–44. doi:10.1086/466560. S2CID 222331226.
  14. ^ Bara, Judith, and Weale, Albert (2006). Democratic Politics and Party Competition: Essays in Honor of Ian Budge. New York: Routledge.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  15. ^ a b Browning, Edgar K. and Browning, Jacquelene M. (1979). Public Finance and the Price System, Voting and Resource Allocation. New York: Macmillan.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  16. ^ Stratmann, Thomas (1992). "The Effects of Logrolling on Congressional Voting". The American Economic Review. 82 (5): 1162–1176.
  17. ^ a b Irwin, Douglass; Randall Kroszner (1996). "Log-Rolling and Economic Interests in the Passage of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff" (PDF). Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. 45. 45: 173–200. doi:10.1016/S0167-2231(96)00023-1. S2CID 154857884.
  18. ^ Wilson, Robert (1969). "An Axiomatic Model of Logrolling". The American Economic Review. 3. 59: 331–341.
  19. ^ Dalenberg, Douglas R; Kevin Duffy-Demo (1991). "At Large Vs. Ward Elections: Implications for Public Infrastructure". Public Choice. 70 (3): 335–342. doi:10.1007/BF00156239. S2CID 154544695.
  20. ^ Gilligan, Thomas; John Matsusaka (1995). "Deviations from Constituent Interests". Economic Inquiry. 33 (3): 383–401. doi:10.1111/j.1465-7295.1995.tb01870.x.
  21. ^ Olson, Mancur Jr. (1971). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. New York: Schocken Books.
  22. ^ Dodd, Lawrence (1977). "Congress and the Quest for Power". Congress Reconsidered.
  23. ^ Arnold, Douglas R. (1979). Congress and the Bureaucracy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. ISBN 9780300023459.
  24. ^ Strahan, Randall (1989). "Member's Goals and Coalition-Building Strategies in the U.S. House: The Case of Tax Reforms". Journal of Politics. 51 (2): 373–384. doi:10.2307/2131347. JSTOR 2131347. S2CID 154543023.
  25. ^ "Penal Code §86 — Vote Trading: Of Crimes Against the Legislative Power". State of California. Legislature. 2014. Every Member of either house of the Legislature, or any member of the legislative body of a city, county, city and county, school district, or other special district, who asks, receives, or agrees to receive, [...] or gives, or offers or promises to give, any official vote in consideration that another Member of the Legislature, or another member of the legislative body of a city, county, city and county, school district, or other special district shall give this vote either upon the same or another question, is punishable by imprisonment
  26. ^ Guerrero, Omar; Matter, Ulrich (2017). "Uncovering Vote Trading Through Networks and Computation". Saïd Business School WP. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3047871. S2CID 54950702. SSRN 3047871.
  27. ^ Private Eye, 21 December 2007.
  28. ^ "G.R. No. L-44257".

External links edit

  •   The dictionary definition of logrolling at Wiktionary

logrolling, other, uses, disambiguation, trading, favors, quid, such, vote, trading, legislative, members, obtain, passage, actions, interest, each, legislative, member, organizational, analysis, refers, practice, which, different, organizations, promote, each. For other uses see Logrolling disambiguation Logrolling is the trading of favors or quid pro quo such as vote trading by legislative members to obtain passage of actions of interest to each legislative member 1 In organizational analysis it refers to a practice in which different organizations promote each other s agendas each in the expectation that the other will reciprocate In an academic context the Nuttall Encyclopedia describes logrolling as mutual praise by authors of each other s work Where intricate tactics or strategy are involved the process may be called horse trading Contents 1 Concept and origin 1 1 Origins 1 2 Choice to logroll 1 3 Logrolling and the role of preference 1 4 Logrolling to reach the optimal decision 1 5 Logrolling An example 1 6 Efficient logrolling 1 7 Minimum winning coalitions and logrolling 1 8 Logrolling in real politics 1 8 1 Wafelijzerpolitiek 1 9 Simple referendums 1 10 Summary 2 Legality 3 Other usages 4 See also 5 References 6 External linksConcept and origin editThere are three types of logrolling Logrolling in direct democracies a few individuals vote openly and votes are easy to trade rearrange and observe Direct democracy is pervasive in representative assemblies and small government units Implicit logrolling large bodies of voters decide complex issues and trade votes without a formal vote trade Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Distributive logrolling enables policymakers to achieve their public goals These policymakers logroll to ensure that their district policies and pork barrel packages are put into practice regardless of whether their policies are actually efficient Evans 1994 3 and Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Distributive logrolling is the most prevalent kind of logrolling found in a democratic system of governance 4 Quid pro quo sums up the concept of logrolling in the United States political process today Logrolling is the process by which politicians trade support for one issue or piece of legislation in exchange for another politician s support especially by means of legislative votes Holcombe 2006 5 If a legislator logrolls he initiates the trade of votes for one particular act or bill in order to secure votes on behalf of another act or bill Logrolling means that two parties will pledge their mutual support so both bills can attain a simple majority For example a vote on behalf of a tariff may be traded by a congressman for a vote from another congressman on behalf of an agricultural subsidy to ensure that both acts will gain a majority and pass through the legislature Shughart 2008 6 Logrolling cannot occur during presidential elections where a vast voting population necessitates that individual votes have little political power or during secret ballot votes Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Because logrolling is pervasive in the political process it is important to understand which external situations determine when why and how logrolling will occur and whether it is beneficial efficient or neither Origins edit nbsp Davy Crockett by William Henry Huddle 1889 The widest accepted origin is the old custom of neighbors assisting each other with the moving of logs If two neighbors had cut a lot of timber that needed to be moved it made more sense for them to work together to roll the logs 7 8 In this way it is similar to a barn raising where a neighbor comes and helps a family build their barn and in turn that family goes and returns the favor helping him build his Here is an example of the term s original use A family comes to sit in the forest wrote an observer in 1835 Their neighbors lay down their employments shoulder their axes and come in to the log rolling They spend the day in hard labor and then retire leaving the newcomers their good wishes and a habitation 9 American frontiersman Davy Crockett was one of the first to apply the term to legislation The first known use of the term was by Congressman Davy Crockett who said on the floor of the U S House of Representatives in 1835 my people don t like me to log roll in their business and vote away pre emption rights to fellows in other states that never kindle a fire on their own land 10 Choice to logroll edit Human beings whether ignorant or informed rational or irrational logical or illogical determine individual and group action through choices Economics studies these choices including the choice to logroll and their particular influence within the market sector Schwartz 1977 11 In America political and economic decisions are usually made by politicians elected to legislative assemblies and not directly by the citizenry Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Although legislative votes are recorded and are available to the American public legislators can exchange their votes on issues they do not care much about for votes on other issues that are more important to their personal agendas Holcombe 2006 5 In The Calculus of Consent James M Buchanan and Gordon Tullock explore the relationship between individual choice in the voting process and in the marketplace specifically within logrolling Logrolling vote trades like any activity within the marketplace must be mutually beneficial Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 A vote trade is like a legislative IOU When a legislator needs a few more votes to acquire a simple majority he will seek support through a vote exchange He will promise a fellow legislator an IOU vote for another piece of legislation in return for a vote on his own act or bill Legislators who logroll within a small body for example the U S House or Senate have incentive to honor their IOU votes because they cannot have their reputations tainted if they wish to be effective politicians Holcombe 2006 5 Logrolling and the role of preference edit People have varying preferences and make decisions at the margin to maximize their utility and improve their welfare The same is true for legislators who all enter office with different agendas passions and goals Ideological diversity plays a significant role in the result of a vote and carries with it a significant cost In addition legislators will favor interests that offer them the most support Legislative votes are determined by the intensity of personal preference desires of constituents and ultimately what will lead to the particular legislator s greatest utility When people have ideologies at opposite ends of the political spectrum it s difficult to ensure a simple majority so buying a supermajority vote through logrolling may be the most cost effective Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 In the General Possibility Theorem Kenneth Arrow argues that if a legislative consensus can be reached through a simple majority then minimum conditions must be satisfied and these conditions must provide a superior ranking to any subset of alternative votes Arrow 1963 12 A bill must be attractive to a legislator or else he will not cast his vote for it A vote by the pure nature of the voting process demonstrates explicit interest in whatever is voted upon In logrolling a superior ranking means that the marginal benefit of the vote is greater than any alternatives so exchanging votes is worthwhile The General Possibility Theorem necessitates that allocating one vote for another must constitute true utility and a sincere vote Arrow s theory may place more restrictions and limitations on an individual voter s preferences than Buchanan and Tullock s regardless individuals will always choose the option they value most Logrolling to reach the optimal decision edit Decisions reach an optimum only when they are unanimous when votes are not coerced and everyone has veto power Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Unanimous votes however are not required for the American voting process This is why some logrolling advocates argue that logrolling must be allowed within a democracy sometimes there may not be a best or most efficient option on a vote Logrolling creates a market within which votes are exchanged as a sort of currency and thus facilitates the political process that produces the highest valued outcomes Holcombe 2006 5 If individual participants recognize the value of their own vote they are motivated to trade When methods of trade do not conflict with given standards or ethical procedures individuals naturally seek mutually advantageous vote trades An individual may effectually but imperfectly sell his vote on a particular issue to in return secure votes from other individuals on behalf of legislation he prefers Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Logrolling has one necessary condition benefits from the public activity must be significantly more concentrated or localized than the costs In economics decisions are made at the margin Logrolling depends on the reality that the marginal benefit or utility of at least some elected officials or the citizenry will increase when the legislation is passed Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Any economist will consider the immediate opportunity cost of the logrolling procedure within the legislative body as well as the external cost of the vote the cost to enact and see the bill through to fruition When transaction costs are low and parties involved are perfectly informed a mutually beneficial agreement will occur whoever values the property the highest will end up with it This is what Ronald H Coase proposed in his Theory of Property Rights in 1960 This theory holds true within the world of economics In the American system of government legislators have the incentive to logroll because transaction costs are low When transaction costs are low the Coase theorem says that the political marketplace the decisions of the legislatures will allocate resources to the highest valued point Coase 1960 13 Typically logrolling is a mechanism used to gain support for special interest and minority groups However because of the ideological mix that already exists within the legislature itself minority views are often represented even if only marginally With low transaction costs the Coase theorem will come into play The highest valued outcome is chosen by the legislature regardless the member s ideological stance or political affiliation Holcombe 2006 5 The problem of cyclical majorities may arise with the absence of logrolling The cyclical majority problem occurs when voters are faced with multiple voting options but cannot choose the option they most prefer since it is not available Voters must consider whether the alternative option is closer to their original preference Bara and Weale 2006 14 However when logrolling is allowed the highest valued outcome is secure without the threat of a cyclical majority For example suppose a country road in West Virginia is in disrepair The local congressman proposes a bill to have the main road in his community resurfaced and paved The road leads to a town of merely 600 residents Thus the other legislators will vote against the measure because the funding is not worthwhile to their constituents In a logrolling system the local legislator can use his vote to bargain with his fellow legislators He will exchange his vote for his fellow legislators bills to promote for instance the construction of new hospitals and the increase of veteran s benefits in return for their votes to repair the road Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Logrolling An example edit Table 1 1 Agriculture Tax Vote School Tax Vote Fire Tax VoteTanya 300 200 Y 150 200 N 100 200 NAlvin 150 200 N 350 200 Y 150 200 NRebecca 100 200 N 50 200 N 225 200 YTotal 550 600 Inefficient 550 600 Inefficient 475 600 InefficientTable 1 1 explains another example of logrolling In the example we have three individuals Tanya Alvin and Rebecca Tanya favors subsidies for agriculture Alvin favors school construction and Rebecca favors the recruitment of more firefighters It seems as if the proposals are doomed to fail because each is opposed by a majority of voters Even so this may not be the outcome Tanya may visit Rebecca and tell her that she will vote for Rebecca s bill to recruit more firefighters so long as Rebecca votes for her policy subsidies for agriculture in return Now both proposals will win because they have gained a simple majority Table 1 2 even though in reality the subsidy is opposed by two of the three voters It s easy to see the Coase theorem at work in examples like this Here transaction costs are low so mutually beneficial agreements are found and the person who values the service the most will hold it Browning and Browning 1979 15 Still outcomes may be inefficient Efficient logrolling edit Table 1 2 Agriculture Tax Vote School Tax Vote Fire Tax VoteTanya 350 200 Y 150 200 N 100 200 YAlvin 150 200 N 350 200 Y 200 200 NRebecca 125 200 Y 50 200 N 300 200 YExample 625 600 Efficient 550 600 Inefficient 600 600 EfficientIf the sum of the total benefit of the legislation for all the voters is less than the cost of the legislation itself the legislation is inefficient Despite its inefficiency however it still may pass if logrolling is permitted If Tanya trades her vote to recruit more firemen to Rebecca in exchange for Rebecca s vote in favor of agriculture subsidies a mutually beneficial agreement will be reached even though the outcome is inefficient On the other hand if the sum of the total benefit of the legislation for all voters is greater than the cost of the legislation itself the legislation is efficient If Tanya trades her vote once again for Rebecca s vote both parties will reach a mutually beneficial agreement and an efficient outcome Minimum winning coalitions and logrolling edit A minimum winning coalition is the smallest number of votes required to win the passage of a piece of legislation Minimum winning coalitions demonstrate the importance of logrolling within a democracy because the minimal winning coalition may be overthrown with the sway of a single vote As previously mentioned coalitions will buy a supermajority of votes if the support for the proposed legislation sways If a legislator logrolls a few votes beyond the minimal winning coalition to his side he will ensure that the final vote will be in favor of his legislation In a way vote trading does combine positions on distinct issues to form single legislative votes and packages Stratmann 1992 16 Logrolled votes transcend affiliations and party lines and become feasible outcomes preferred by a majority or winning coalition Schwartz 1977 11 Logrolling in real politics edit A problem in research is that it is impossible to identify vote trading directly within the House of Representatives or the Senate because roll call votes on specific goods are not observed Irwin and Kroszner 1996 17 However examples of refurbished bills can shed some light on the working out of logrolling within the legislature For example in 1930 the Smoot Hawley tariff the second highest tariff in U S history passed the House and Senate Congress voted to increase tariffs exponentially which worked to push the United States from a stagnant recession into a plummeting depression Irwin and Kroszner 1996 17 Strict party line votes suggest that partisan polarization in 1929 prevented the Smoot Hawley bill from passing through Congress The bill however was revamped and legislators used logrolling to pass it through both chambers in 1930 Omnibus bills can be an alternative market to logrolling Various clauses are added to a bill to satisfy all involved parties sufficiently However large bills like the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act require an in depth knowledge of 1 000 plus pages Many sections of these types of bills are initially opposed but are later supported because of special benefit clauses Evans 1994 3 Because logrolling allows special interest groups a voice in the political process programs that benefit a minority group can get the approval of a majority However this may not be in the best interest of the majority Special interest groups typically do not represent the typical voter but rather small branches of minority ideologies Holcombe 2006 5 Voting results with or without logrolling will differ only if the minority is more interested in an issue than the majority enough to separate the marginal voters from the majority Studies show that lobbying and political pressure exerted by special interest groups are not atypical behavior in a modern democracy Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Conditions imposed upon the social choice of the legislature imply a more severe restriction on the individual voter s preferences than the theory of logrolling presented by Buchanan and Tullock and presumed by Arrow s General Possibility Theory Wilson 1969 18 Critics reproach members of Congress for protecting their own electoral interests at the expense of the general welfare Congressmen tend to distribute specialized benefits at a great cost and ignore the particular costs the legislation bears upon the taxpayers Evans 1994 3 Legislators who seek their personal benefit via logrolling even though it may not benefit those who must pay for the measure are known as maximizers Maximizers only take into account their personal cost and electability instead of the effects of their actions on other parties involved In short other taxpayers will pay for the policy even if it does not affect them Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Initially maximizers will encourage other legislators to have the same selfish behavior because significant gains can be accrued in the short run Buchanan and Tullock state that within a system of maximizers all individuals are worse off than if they had all adopted Kantian norms of behavior Legislative bodies can expect higher government spending and taxation when logrolling is allowed to flourish Logrolling does not imply excessive spending members can trade tax reductions just as easily as they can trade pork barrel policies The problem is that benefits of a vote only reach a particular portion of the population while the tax costs that pay for the vote are spread throughout the entire populace especially when the act depends on revenue from sales or income taxes Benefits are concentrated in localities and the costs are dispersed throughout the nation Committee members can thus exploit pork barrel projects for electoral purposes The citizenry is seen as a common pool used to finance projects through taxes Somehow the citizens end up paying higher taxes than those who are not in a logroll system Dalenberg and Duffy Deno 1991 19 and Gilligan and Matsusaka 1995 20 In a system where logrolling is permitted a third party may bear the cost of the project rather than those who receive the full benefit of the legislation This is always inefficient The logic of collective action shows that votes for bills are motivated by politicians and are determined by a simple majority Olson 1971 21 Politicians are in the game to win it Collective effort explains why farms acquire government subsidies at the expense of millions of consumers and why those in the textile industry benefit at the expense of clothing buyers Shughart 2008 6 Congressional committees ensure that each committee leader will create legislative coalitions to push his policies to fruition Thus ceteris paribus members who receive such projects are likely to vote in support of their leader s wishes Evans 1994 3 Policymakers and congressmen have goals of power and making their own mark in public policy not pure aims of reelection Dodd 1977 22 Reelection does play a great part in the legislative process as a condition to achieving any other political goal Thus logrolling can be a powerful tool for committee chairs who control the voting agendas Evans 1994 3 While committee leaders create the supermajority they try to achieve their personal goals and help a bare majority of members achieve theirs A skilled policy oriented committee leader often seeks to exploit the goals of other members in order to construct legislation he or she will prefer Arnold 1979 23 and Strahan 1989 24 Wafelijzerpolitiek edit Main article Waffle iron politics Wafelijzerpolitiek lit waffle iron politics is a form of logrolling used in Belgium Until the split of the unitary Belgium in several parts the unitary government decided on the funds given to big projects As there were usually two opposing groups of about equal size in Belgium this norm resulted in the approval of two equally sized projects in the two parts of the country with the funds given to the two projects being equal As a result one project was always overfunded Many see wafelijzerpolitiek as the source of Belgium s high debt After the first state reformation in 1988 many big projects were decided regionally so the number of wafelijzer projects went down There are still some things that fall under the supervision of the federal government where wafelijzerpolitiek still happens One example is the Belgian railway network Another result of the wafelijzerpolitiek is the big useless works As Flanders is a part of Belgium with many ports e g big ports in Antwerp and Zeebrugge for every investment in Flemish waterways there had to be an investment in Walloon waterways Some results are the Ronquieres inclined plane and the Strepy Thieu boat lift Simple referendums edit In a referendum on a simple issue the voter cannot easily trade his own vote for a vote on a reciprocal favor This is because first he is unsure as to when and how the other issues will be voted upon and second he and his immediate neighbors represent a fraction of the total electorate Thus trading may not be worthwhile Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Vote trading under a democratic majority rule institution is sometimes considered morally reprehensible behavior However the only perfect solution to rid the political system of distributive logrolling would be to develop a specific formula to weigh the costs and benefits of legislation perfectly and only allow efficient programs to be enacted This is inconceivable Therefore logrolling must occur but only by observing the constitutional rules that have been laid down as safeguards of democracy Buchanan and Tullock 1962 2 Summary edit The reality is that transaction costs are high and most voters who are ignorant of political issues and the political process see little incentive to attempt to influence their local legislator s political decisions Holcombe 2006 5 It is also difficult for voters to be informed of their legislator s voting habits Because of this distributive logrolling will occur in democratic systems Furthermore it is the responsibility of the legislator to measure the costs and benefits of legislation and determine what is most efficient for his constituents Logrolling will occur only if members of the legislature fail to gather enough votes for the passage of specific legislation In essence logrolling is a legal way to manipulate voter preference toward either an efficient or an inefficient outcome that would not otherwise be enacted Browning 1979 15 Legality editLogrolling is illegal in numerous jurisdictions and in some instances is a crime 25 Sophisticated computational techniques have been developed for the detection and prosecution of this crime 26 Other usages editSpy Magazine ran a feature entitled Logrolling in Our Time that cited suspicious or humorous examples of mutually admiring book jacket blurbs by pairs of authors Private Eye magazine regularly draws attention to alleged logrolling by authors in books of the year features published by British newspapers and magazines 27 full citation needed Log rolling or a hodgepodge legislation in the Philippines also refers to any legislation that have several subjects on unrelated matters combined together It is expressed in Article 6 Section 26 1 of the 1987 Philippine Constitution as a guarantee to prevent surprise or fraud from the legislature 28 See also editBarn raising Bee gathering Blog roll Political corruption which can overlap in instances where logrolling is corrupted by personal gain Pay to play Vote tradingReferences edit 1 Education 2020 government course definition of logrolling An agreement by two or more lawmakers to support each other s bills a b c d e f g h i j k l m n Buchanan James M and Tullock Gordon 1962 The Calculus of Consent Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy Ann Arbor Michigan University of Michigan Press a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link a b c d e Evans Diana 1994 Policy and Pork The Use of Pork Barrel Projects to Build Policy Coalitions in the House of Representatives American Journal of Political Science 4 38 4 894 917 doi 10 2307 2111726 JSTOR 2111726 Logrolling A Glossary of Political Economy Terms Dr Paul M Johnson a b c d e f g Holcombe Randall 2006 Public Sector Economics The Role of Government in the American Economy New Jersey Prentice Hall pp 179 181 a b Shughart II William Public Choice The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics Library of Economics and Liberty Retrieved April 17 2020 Online Etymology Dictionary logrolling The American Heritage Dictionary of the English Language 4th Edition 2000 Archived from the original on June 26 2008 Retrieved June 9 2008 Barnhart David K Metcalf Allan A 1999 America in So Many Words Words That Have Shaped America Houghton Mifflin Harcourt p 95 ISBN 0 618 00270 7 Crockett Davy 1835 An account of Col Crockett s tour to the North and down East in the year of Our Lord one thousand eight hundred and thirty four His object being to examine the grand manufacturing establishments of the country and also to find out the condition of its literature and its morals the extent of its commerce and the practical operation of The Experiment E L Carey and A Hart a b Schwartz Thomas 1977 Collection of Issues and Vote Trading The American Political Science Review 71 3 999 1010 doi 10 2307 1960103 JSTOR 1960103 S2CID 154434919 Arrow Kenneth 1963 Social Choice and Individual Values 2nd Ed New York John Wiley amp Sons Coase Ronald H 1960 The Problem of Social Cost PDF The Journal of Law and Economics 3 1 44 doi 10 1086 466560 S2CID 222331226 Bara Judith and Weale Albert 2006 Democratic Politics and Party Competition Essays in Honor of Ian Budge New York Routledge a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link a b Browning Edgar K and Browning Jacquelene M 1979 Public Finance and the Price System Voting and Resource Allocation New York Macmillan a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Stratmann Thomas 1992 The Effects of Logrolling on Congressional Voting The American Economic Review 82 5 1162 1176 a b Irwin Douglass Randall Kroszner 1996 Log Rolling and Economic Interests in the Passage of the Smoot Hawley Tariff PDF Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 45 45 173 200 doi 10 1016 S0167 2231 96 00023 1 S2CID 154857884 Wilson Robert 1969 An Axiomatic Model of Logrolling The American Economic Review 3 59 331 341 Dalenberg Douglas R Kevin Duffy Demo 1991 At Large Vs Ward Elections Implications for Public Infrastructure Public Choice 70 3 335 342 doi 10 1007 BF00156239 S2CID 154544695 Gilligan Thomas John Matsusaka 1995 Deviations from Constituent Interests Economic Inquiry 33 3 383 401 doi 10 1111 j 1465 7295 1995 tb01870 x Olson Mancur Jr 1971 The Logic of Collective Action Public Goods and the Theory of Groups New York Schocken Books Dodd Lawrence 1977 Congress and the Quest for Power Congress Reconsidered Arnold Douglas R 1979 Congress and the Bureaucracy New Haven CT Yale University Press ISBN 9780300023459 Strahan Randall 1989 Member s Goals and Coalition Building Strategies in the U S House The Case of Tax Reforms Journal of Politics 51 2 373 384 doi 10 2307 2131347 JSTOR 2131347 S2CID 154543023 Penal Code 86 Vote Trading Of Crimes Against the Legislative Power State of California Legislature 2014 Every Member of either house of the Legislature or any member of the legislative body of a city county city and county school district or other special district who asks receives or agrees to receive or gives or offers or promises to give any official vote in consideration that another Member of the Legislature or another member of the legislative body of a city county city and county school district or other special district shall give this vote either upon the same or another question is punishable by imprisonment Guerrero Omar Matter Ulrich 2017 Uncovering Vote Trading Through Networks and Computation Said Business School WP doi 10 2139 ssrn 3047871 S2CID 54950702 SSRN 3047871 Private Eye 21 December 2007 G R No L 44257 External links edit nbsp The dictionary definition of logrolling at Wiktionary Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Logrolling amp oldid 1176394458, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.