fbpx
Wikipedia

Accountability

Accountability, in terms of ethics and governance, is equated with answerability, culpability, liability, and the expectation of account-giving.[1]

As in an aspect of governance, it has been central to discussions related to problems in the public sector, nonprofit, private (corporate), and individual contexts. In leadership roles,[2] accountability is the acknowledgment of and assumption of responsibility for actions, products, decisions, and policies such as administration, governance, and implementation, including the obligation to report, justify, and be answerable for resulting consequences.

In governance, accountability has expanded beyond the basic definition of "being called to account for one's actions".[3] It is frequently described as an account-giving relationship between individuals, e.g. "A is accountable to B when A is obliged to inform B about A's (past or future) actions and decisions, to justify them, and to suffer punishment in the case of eventual misconduct."[4]

Accountability cannot exist without proper accounting practices; in other words, an absence of accounting means an absence of accountability.[citation needed] Another key area that contributes to accountability is good records management.[5]

History and etymology edit

"Accountability" derives from the late Latin accomptare (to account), a prefixed form of computare (to calculate), which in turn is derived from putare (to reckon).[6] While the word itself does not appear in English until its use in 13th century Norman England,[7] the concept of account-giving has ancient roots in record-keeping activities related to governance and money-lending systems that first developed in Ancient Egypt,[8] Israel,[9] Babylon,[10] Greece,[11] and later Rome.[12]

Political edit

Political accountability is when a politician makes choices on behalf of the people, and the people have the ability to reward or sanction the politician.[13] In representative democracies, citizens delegate power to elected officials through periodic elections, and such officials are empowered to represent or act in the citizens' interest.[13] A challenge is how to see to it that those with such power, who presumably have divergent interests from the citizens, nonetheless act in their best interests.[14] Citizens can rely on rewards or sanctions to reward or threaten politicians who might otherwise act in a manner that is antithetical to the people's interest.[14] Accountability occurs when citizens only vote to re-elect representatives who act in their interests, and if representatives then select policies that will help them be re-elected.[14] "Governments are 'accountable' if voters can discern whether governments are acting in their interest and sanction them appropriately, so that those incumbents who act in the best interest of the citizens win reelection and those who do not lose them."[14]

Representatives can be held accountable through two mechanisms: electoral replacement and rational anticipation.[15] In electoral replacement, citizens vote to replace representatives who are out of step with their interests. Rational anticipation requires that representatives anticipate the consequences of being out of step with their constituency and then govern in accordance with citizens' wishes to avoid negative consequences.[15] Accountability can still be achieved even if citizens are not perfectly knowledgeable about their representatives' actions; as long as representatives believe that they will be held accountable by citizens, they will still be motivated to act in accordance with the citizens' interests.[16]

Electoral edit

Electoral accountability refers to citizens using their vote to sanction or reward politicians.[14]

Some researchers have considered accountability using formal theory, which makes assumptions about the state of the world to draw larger conclusions. Voters can hold representatives accountable through the process of sanctioning—voting the incumbent out of office in response to poor performance.[14] While politicians face a decrease in vote share as a result of poor performance, they are less likely to see an increase in vote share for good performance.[17] Selection—voters choosing candidates based on who will best represent their interests—is another method by which voters hold their representatives accountable.[14] These methods of accountability can occur simultaneously, with voters holding representatives accountable using both sanctioning and selection.[14] These conclusions rely on the assumption that voters do not observe the policy implemented by the incumbent, but do know their own welfare.[clarification needed][14]

Some factors make it harder for voters to sanction incumbents. When politicians do not have control over outcomes, it becomes harder[how?] to hold them accountable.[17] Additionally, when organizations are unable to monitor elections and provide information to voters, then voters struggle to sanction the incumbent.[18] When voters are better informed about the incumbent's performance, the incumbent is more vulnerable to voter sanctioning.[18] Furthermore, when incumbents face sanctioning, challengers are more likely to enter the race.[18]

While elections provide a mechanism which can theoretically increase government accountability to citizens, they may instead lead to less egalitarian policy outcomes, because those who hold the government accountable tend to be from wealthier segments of society.[19] For example, a study of elected versus appointed property assessors in the state of New York shows that the election of property assessors leads to policies that severely undertax wealthier homes relative to poorer homes.[19]

Electoral manipulation and accountability edit

Studies on political accountability have emphasized the key role of elections in promoting accountability in democratic settings. It is through elections that citizens hold governments accountable for past performance.[14][20] However, the role of elections in fostering accountability is often undermined by electoral manipulation and fraud.[21] By preventing citizens from removing leaders through elections based on their performance in office, electoral manipulation breaks down accountability and may undercut the consolidation of democratic institutions.[22]

Electoral manipulation is not rare; some estimates are that in the 1990s and 2000s, up to one fourth of elections suffered some form of substantial manipulation.[21] This includes a large array of pre-election and election-day tactics, such as outlawing rival parties and candidates, employing violence and intimidation, and manipulating voter registration and vote count.[23] Some efforts to improve accountability by preventing electoral manipulation and fraud have obtained a certain measure of success, such as using cell phone applications for monitoring and disseminating polling station results[24] and employing domestic or international election observers.[25][26] However, governments may simply alter the type of manipulation or where it occurs in order to deceive observers and monitoring agencies.[25][26]

Governments, politicians, and political parties are more likely to resort to electoral manipulation and fraud when they believe they might be removed from office and when they face few institutional constraints to their power.[27] Low political competition has also been linked to some forms of manipulation, such as abolishing presidential term limits.[28] Well-connected[how?] candidates are more likely to resort to vote count fraud.[24] Governments may engage in electoral manipulation not only to obtain victory at a given election or to remain in office longer, but also for post-election reasons, such as reducing the strength of the opposition or increasing their own bargaining power in the subsequent period.[21]

Administrative edit

Public goods edit

Politicians may be incentivized to provide public goods as a means of accountability.[clarification needed][29] The ability of voters to attribute the credit and blame of outcomes also determines the extent of public goods provision.[29][30] Research suggests that public goods provision is conditional on[vague] being able to attribute outcomes to politicians as opposed to civil servants.[30] This attribution can be enhanced by more short-run and visible inputs and outcomes such as famine relief or access to drinking water, whereas lower-visibility issues such as sanitation and education may be more difficult to attribute credit for and thus less likely to provide for.[29]

Another condition determining how voters use the provision of public goods to hold leaders accountable is whether the prioritization of public goods is determined either directly via vote or delegated to a governing body.[31][32] An experiment in New Mexico regarding proposed spending during the state's 2008 special summer legislative session provides evidence that legislators update their positions when learning about voters' policy preferences, indicating that a representative democracy can increase accountability when politicians learn about voters' preferences.[31] A 2016 experiment in Afghanistan regarding rural development projects, however, finds that when voters directly prioritize their preferences at the ballot box, they perceive the quality of local government to be higher than when a governing committee prioritizes development projects.[32] These contrasting outcomes highlight a debate between trustees and delegates, though the lack of objective superior outcomes in projects decided by vote as opposed to committee in the Afghanistan experiment indicate neither is superior to the other in determining which public goods should be given priority.[33]

Other research indicates that voters use elections to hold politicians accountable for the provision of public goods.[34][35] In India, rural areas are charged a flat rate for electricity, but in the province of Uttar Pradesh, line loss—electricity that is consumed but not billed—is significantly higher in election years than non-election years, and increases in line loss reliably predict electoral gains.[34] Voters rewarded incumbent politicians with a 12% increase in party seats in response to a 10% increase of unbilled electricity, in 2007 elections.[34] In Ghana, the improvement of road conditions is linked to an increasing vote share for incumbent parties.[35] Both of these research outcomes hinge on voters being able to attribute the service of public goods to politicians.[34][35][30]

Politicians may also have incentives to respond to pressure for public goods provision in electoral autocracies.[36][37] There is evidence that as autocratic governments lose seats in their party's legislatures, they respond by increasing spending on public goods such as education, healthcare, and pensions.[36] There is further evidence suggesting higher quality of life, civil liberties, and human development in electoral autocracies, lending credence to the theory that autocratic rulers use elections as a bellwether against popular discontent and citizen opposition, and in turn increase public goods provision to dampen the grievances of disgruntled citizens, even in non-democracies.[37]

While the introduction of elections is generally thought to improve public goods provision, in some cases, researchers have shown that it may reduce its quality.[38] For example, the introduction of direct elections for local district office in Indonesia resulted in political interference in the hiring process for bureaucrats in the public education sector, reducing the quality of education provision; politicians were incentivized to dole out patronage positions in the education sector, especially in election years, and where such positions were added, student test scores were lower.[38]

Non-electoral edit

Governments are held accountable if citizens can punish or reward the government to influence it to pursue their best interests.[14] While scholars who study democratic theory emphasize the role of elections in ensuring accountability,[39] another strand of scholars investigates non-electoral forms of accountability in democracies and non-democracies[40][41][42][43] and the conditions that make unelected leaders represent the interests of the general public.[44][45][46]

Political protests edit

Political changes after protests can be the result of the protests per se, or symptoms of shifts in political preferences underneath the observable phenomena of the protests. One study of the Tea Party movement in the United States has shown that protests per se have an impact on political change.[40]

Other scholars studied the effect of protests on political changes in developing countries. Mass protests instigated by economic hardship and political repression occurred in 16 sub-Saharan African countries, and 21 governments in the region implemented significant political reforms, such as the adoption of multi-party elections.[41] Authoritarian regimes in Africa distorted the market and reduced the cost of farm produce in favor of urban workers at the cost of rural farmers in the 1980s to prevent urban unrest, which is more visible and easier to mobilize than rural protests.[47]

Selectorates edit

Belsky et al. point out that whereas, under more democratic governance, accountability is built into the institution of the state by a habit of regular elections, accountability in autocratic regimes[48] relies on a selectorate—a group that legitimizes or delegitimizes the autocrat's powers according to selectorate theory. Selectorates are those on whom a leader depends in order to hold onto power, and those who have the ability to depose a leader.[49] When a selectorate's hold on power is not overly dependent on the leader in office, selectorates can remove poorly performing leaders, and this accountability by selectorates renders it possible for autocracies to perform better for the benefit of all.[48] Beyond that, institutions[specify] can act as credible restraints on autocracy as well.[how?]

Civil societies edit

In democracies, voluntary associations, interest groups, and associational activity can improve the performance of the government.[50] One study showed that civil society organizations such as NGOs can increase the performance of local government according to the central government's standards by monitoring and disclosing information about local government performance in authoritarian regimes like China.[42] Solidarity groups in rural China, in which members share moral obligations and interests, can hold local officials accountable as well[44] when (i) the solidarity group encompasses everyone under the local government's jurisdiction, and (ii) local officials are embedded in the group as members. The social standing and recognition of these groups encourages local officials to perform well, as they value high moral standing in the group.[44]

At the local level, various accountability measures exist that impact the job performance of elected officials.[51][52][53] In Uganda, civil society organizations (CSOs) that divulge to the public how well an incumbent is performing their job duties, in a district with an upcoming competitive election, increase the performance of the politician for the rest of their term.[54] In contrast to these works, a meta-analysis released in 2019 uncovers no effects from CSO voter information campaigns on political accountability after examining the results from seven trials across six countries.[55] In Ghana, election-day monitoring of polling centers for district-level positions, as well as an increase in the awareness of monitoring in an upcoming election, increases job performance among incumbents, who spend more of their annual Constituency Development Fund allocations from the central government on public goods for the electorate.[51] In locales with weaker institutions, when citizens elect leaders with higher levels of competency, these officials have a greater ability to overcome the barriers of bad informal institutions, and deliver more goods and long-term investment projects for the constituency without needing to raise taxes.[52] Additionally, many local elections are for positions that involve performing jobs with a single function, such as a school board member or a sheriff. These elected officials are held accountable to their positions mainly through information provided to the public through the media.[53] When the media focuses attention on data trends associated with these positions, constituents are then able to use this information to retrospectively vote for or against an incumbent based on their performance in office.[53]

Public opinion polls edit

Approval ratings generated through public opinion polling create a measure of job performance during an incumbent's term that has implications for whether the official will retain their seat, or if reelection will even be sought.[56][57] These approval ratings predict election outcomes when combined with other factors included in Bayesian Model Averaging forecasts.[58] In the United States, senator job approval ratings affect whether a senator will retire, the quality of candidates that seek to challenge them, the amount of money the senator can raise to seek reelection if they decide to run, and the outcome of the election itself.[56] Strategic incumbent senators will seek reelection less when their approval ratings are low during their time in office.[56][57]

Shared interests edit

Traditional leaders in Zambia provide local public goods despite the fact that they lack an electoral incentive to do so.[45] Many customary chiefs never leave the communities they lead and depend on local sources for a significant portion of their income; thus, traditional leaders may facilitate bringing in local public goods and benefit from the community's development over time just like stationary bandits[definition needed] in Olson's argument.[definition needed][43][45]

Accountability and corruption edit

Political corruption refers to "the misuse or the abuse of public office for private gains". Corrupt practices include fraud, appropriation of public funds, and accepting bribes.[59][60] Corruption can cause people to negatively evaluate politicians, since citizens may perceive corruption as a signal of poor performance, motivating them to sanction an incumbent.[61] As the model of retrospective voting suggests that voters incentivize good politicians' behavior by rewarding good performance and punishing bad performance, citizens are expected to sanction corrupt politicians.[59] However, studies suggest that though voters have a distaste for corruption, they often fail to punish corrupt incumbents; some of them receive benefits from their representatives' corrupt practices, and prefer to retain this type of politician.[62][59] In high-corruption contexts, voters may become more tolerant of or even prefer corrupt politicians because others are also perceived as corrupt, leading to a corrupt equilibrium "where voters are generally willing to retain corrupt politicians", referred to as a "political corruption trap".[62] This high corruption equilibrium is difficult to break due to interaction between corrupt politicians, voters who tolerate and retain corrupt politicians, and potential entrants or challengers who also engage in corrupt practices, leading to the maintenance of corruption.[62]

Democracy does not seem to reduce corruption.[63] Economic development is associated with a decrease in corruption.[63] Freedom of the press contributes to the reduction of corruption by exposing corrupt actions.[63] Documentation on how a corrupt government (e.g. Alberto Fujimori's government from 1998 to 2000 in Peru) can strategically undermine checks-and-balances institutions, suggests that the news media—i.e. newspapers and mainly television—is crucial to the dissemination of information to the public.[64] There is also evidence about the importance of local media, such as local radio stations, in holding corrupt incumbents accountable and in promoting non-corrupt politicians.[citation needed] Information about corruption may not only lead to vote losses for the incumbent parties, but also for challenging parties, as well the erosion of partisan attachments, which implies that information about corruption also provokes citizens' disengagement from the political process.[61]

Scholarly literature about corruption finds mixed results about the role of political institutions on the level of a country's corruption.[63] For example, some scholarly research suggests that more horizontal accountability, or oversight across branches of government, would generally decrease corruption.[65] However, other research shows that increased oversight could increase corruption when actors in one branch can pressure actors in another to collude; in Ghana, bureaucrats are more likely to engage in corruption on behalf of politicians when politicians have higher levels of discretion to oversee the bureaucracy (e.g., by threatening to transfer noncompliant bureaucrats).[66]

Low accountability for corruption is difficult to combat, and some anti-corruption activities may also lead to perverse consequences.[67] For example, in places where private sector work pays better than public sector work (e.g., China), highly qualified individuals engaging in public sector work may only find such work attractive because it allows for further compensation through corrupt activities. Government anti-corruption activities can therefore decrease the quality and overall representativeness of the bureaucracy as a result.[68] On the other hand, there is evidence that, despite strategic evasion and unintentional consequences, anti-corruption initiatives are beneficial, as they lower malfeasance and increase social welfare, even where strategic evasion is relatively large.[69]

Police accountability edit

Police accountability involves holding both individual police officers, as well as law enforcement agencies responsible for effectively delivering basic services of crime control and maintaining order, while treating individuals fairly and within the bounds of law. Police are expected to uphold laws, regarding due process, search and seizure, arrests, discrimination, as well as other laws relating to equal employment, sexual harassment, etc. Holding police accountable is important for maintaining the public's "faith in the system".[70]: 42  Research has shown that the public prefers independent review of complaints against law enforcement, rather than relying on police departments to conduct internal investigations. There is a suggestion that such oversight would improve the public's view on the way in which police officers are held accountable.[71]

Organizational edit

Ethical edit

Within an organization, the principles and practices of ethical accountability aim to improve both the internal standard of individual and group conduct as well as external factors, such as sustainable economic and ecologic strategies. Also, ethical accountability plays an important role in academic fields, such as laboratory experiments and field research. Debates around the practice of ethical accountability on the part of researchers in the social field[vague] – whether professional or others – were explored by Norma R.A. Romm in her work on Accountability in Social Research,[72] and elsewhere.[73] Researcher accountability implies that researchers are cognizant of, and take some responsibility for, the potential impact of their ways of doing research – and of writing it up – on the social fields of which the research is part. Accountability is linked to considering carefully, and being open to challenge in relation to, one's choices concerning how research agendas are framed and the styles in which research results are written.

Security edit

The traceability of actions performed on a system to a specific system entity (user, process, device) also affects accountability. For example, the use of unique user identification and authentication supports accountability, and the use of shared user IDs and passwords degrades accountability.

Individuals within organizations edit

Because many individuals in large organizations contribute in many ways to decisions and policies, it is difficult even in principle to identify who should be accountable for the results. This is what is known, following Dennis F. Thompson, as "the problem of many hands".[74] It creates a dilemma for accountability. If individuals are held accountable or responsible, individuals who could not have prevented the results are either unfairly punished, or they "take responsibility" in a symbolic ritual without suffering any consequences. If only organizations are held accountable, then all individuals in the organization are equally blameworthy or all are excused.

Various solutions have been proposed. One is to broaden the criteria for individual responsibility so that individuals are held accountable for not anticipating failures in the organization. Another solution, recently proposed by Thompson, is to hold individuals accountable for the design of the organization, both retrospectively and prospectively.[75]

Accountability is an element of a responsibility assignment matrix which indicates who is ultimately answerable for the correct and thorough completion of a deliverable or task, as well as the delegation of the work to those responsible.

Public/private overlap edit

With the increase in public service provided by private entities, especially in Britain and the United States, some have called for increased political accountability mechanisms for otherwise non-political entities. Legal scholar Anne Davies, for instance, argues that the line between public institutions and private entities like corporations is becoming blurred in certain areas of public service in the United Kingdom, and that this can compromise political accountability in those areas. She and others argue that some administrative law reform is necessary to address this accountability gap.[citation needed]

With respect to the public/private overlap in the United States, public concern over the contracting of government services (including military) and the resulting accountability gap was highlighted following the Nisour Square massacre perpetrated by the Blackwater security firm in Iraq.[76]

In education edit

As defined by National Council on Measurement in Education (NCME), accountability is "[a] program, often legislated, that attributes the responsibility for student learning to teachers, school administrators, and/or students. Test results typically are used to judge accountability, and often consequences are imposed for shortcomings."[77]

Student accountability is traditionally based on school and classroom rules, combined with sanctions for infringement.

In contrast, some educational establishments such as Sudbury schools believe that students are personally responsible for their acts, and that traditional schools do not permit students to choose their course of action fully; they do not permit students to embark on the course, once chosen; and they do not permit students to suffer the consequences of the course, once taken. Freedom of choice, freedom of action, freedom to bear the results of action are considered the three great freedoms that constitute personal responsibility. Sudbury schools claim that "'Ethics' is a course taught by life experience". They adduce that the essential ingredient for acquiring values—and for moral action—is personal responsibility, that schools will become involved in the teaching of morals when they become communities of people who fully respect each other's right to make choices, and that the only way the schools can become meaningful purveyors of ethical values is if they provide students and adults with real-life experiences that are bearers of moral import. Students are given complete responsibility for their own education and the school is run by a direct democracy in which students and staff are equals.[78]

Media and accountability edit

Econometric research has found that countries with greater press freedom tend to have less corruption.[79] Greater political accountability and lower corruption were more likely where newspaper consumption was higher, according to data from roughly 100 countries and from different states in the US.[80] Congressmen[where?] who receive less press coverage are less likely to produce a positive impact for their constituencies, are less likely to stand witness before[clarification needed] congressional hearings, and federal spending for their district is lower.[81] One explanation for the positive impact of media on accountability stems from Besley and Burgess' work.[82] They argue that media resolves the information asymmetries between citizens and government and provides a way of overcoming obstacles preventing political action.[82] When elected officials and the public gain information, the public is better equipped to hold politicians accountable and politicians are more responsive.[83][81] Ferraz & Finan demonstrate this in the Brazilian context. In their work, they find releasing audit reports prior to elections creates a more informed electorate which holds incumbent officials accountable.[84]

While evidence supports the positive impact of press freedom on political accountability, other work highlights the significance of factors such as media concentration and ownership as government tools for influencing or controlling news content.[85] Non-democratic regimes use media for a variety of purposes such as – (i) to enhance regime resilience, (ii) censor, or (iii) strategically distract the public.[86] Control of the media may also be especially beneficial to incumbents in new or developing democracies, who consider media control a spoil of office.[87]

An analysis of the evolution of mass media in the U.S. and Europe since World War II noted mixed results from the growth of the Internet: "The digital revolution has been good for freedom of expression [and] information [but] has had mixed effects on freedom of the press": It has disrupted traditional sources of funding, and new forms of Internet journalism have replaced only a tiny fraction of what's been lost.[88] Various systems have been proposed for increasing the funds available for investigative journalism that allow individual citizens to direct small amounts of government funds to news outlets or investigative journalism projects of their choice.

Standards edit

Accountability standards have been established that organizations can voluntarily commit to. Standards apply in particular to the non-profit world and to Corporate Social Responsibility initiatives. Accountability standards include the:

INGO Accountability Charter
signed by a large number of NGOs to "demonstrate their commitment to accountability and transparency"[89]
AccountAbility's AA1000 series
"principles-based standards to help organisations become more accountable, responsible and sustainable. They address issues affecting governance, business models and organizational strategy, as well as providing operational guidance on sustainability assurance and stakeholder engagement"[90]
Humanitarian Accountability Partnership 2010 standards
for humanitarian organizations to help them "design, implement, assess, improve and recognize accountable programmes"[91]

In addition, some non-profit organizations set up their own commitments to accountability:

Accountability, Learning and Planning System (ALPS) by ActionAid
a framework that sets out key accountability requirements, guidelines, and processes[92]

See also edit

Footnotes edit

  1. ^ Dykstra, Clarence A. (February 1938). "The Quest for Responsibility". American Political Science Review. 33 (1): 1–25. doi:10.2307/1949761. JSTOR 1949761. S2CID 143587418.
  2. ^ Williams, Reyes (2006). Leadership accountability in a globalizing world. London: Palgraave Macmillan.
  3. ^
    • Mulgan, Richard (2000). "'Accountability': An Ever-Expanding Concept?". Public Administration. 78 (3): 555–573. doi:10.1111/1467-9299.00218.
    • Sinclair, Amanda (1995). "The Chameleon of Accountability: Forms and Discourses". Accounting, Organizations and Society. 20 (2/3): 219–237. doi:10.1016/0361-3682(93)E0003-Y.
  4. ^ Schedler, Andreas (1999). "Conceptualizing Accountability". In Andreas Schedler; Larry Diamond; Marc F. Plattner (eds.). The Self-Restraining State: Power and Accountability in New Democracies. London: Lynne Rienner Publishers. pp. 13–28. ISBN 978-1-55587-773-6.
  5. ^ David, Rodreck (2017). "Contribution of records management to audit opinions and accountability in government". South Africa Journal of Information Management. 19 (1). AOSIS. doi:10.4102/sajim.v19i1.771. ISSN 1560-683X. S2CID 168907338.
  6. ^ Oxford English Dictionary (2nd ed.).[page needed]
  7. ^
    • Dubnick, Melvin (1998). "Clarifying Accountability: An Ethical Theory Framework". In Charles Sampford; Noel Preston; C. A. Bois (eds.). Public Sector Ethics: Finding And Implementing Values. Leichhardt, NSW, Australia: The Federation Press/Routledge. pp. 68–81.
    • Seidman, Gary I (Winter 2005). "The Origins of Accountability: Everything I Know About the Sovereign's Immunity, I Learned from King Henry III". St. Louis University Law Journal. 49 (2): 393–480.
  8. ^ Ezzamel, Mahmoud (December 1997). "Accounting, Control and Accountability: Preliminary Evidence from Ancient Egypt". Critical Perspectives on Accounting. 8 (6): 563–601. doi:10.1006/cpac.1997.0123.
  9. ^ Walzer, Michael (1994). "The Legal Codes of Ancient Israel". In Ian Shapiro (ed.). the Rule of Law. NY: New York University Press. pp. 101–119.
  10. ^ Urch, Edwin J. (July 1929). "The Law Code of Hammurabi". American Bar Association Journal. 15 (7): 437–441.
  11. ^ Roberts, Jennifer T. (1982). Accountability in Athenian Government. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press. ISBN 9780299086800.
  12. ^ Plescia, Joseph (January 2001). "Judicial Accountability and Immunity in Roman Law". American Journal of Legal History. 45 (1): 51–70. doi:10.2307/3185349. JSTOR 3185349.
  13. ^ a b Fearon, James (1999). Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
  14. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k Przeworski, Adam; Stokes, Susan Carol; Manin, Bernard (2003). Democracy, accountability, and representation. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521641531. OCLC 58400209.
  15. ^ a b Stimson, James A.; MacKuen, Michael B.; Erikson, Robert S. "Dynamic Representation". American Political Science Review. 98 (3): 543–565.
  16. ^ Arnold, R. Douglas (1990). The logic of congressional action. Yale University Press. ISBN 0300056591. OCLC 472546186.
  17. ^ a b Martin, Lucy; Raffler, Pia (4 August 2019). "Fault Lines: The Effects of Bureaucratic Power on Electoral Accountability" (PDF). American Journal of Political Science. (PDF) from the original on 6 December 2019. Retrieved 6 December 2019.
  18. ^ a b c Grossman, Guy; Michelitch, Kristin Grace; Prato, Carlo (2 March 2022), The Effect of Sustained Transparency on Electoral Accountability, Center for Open Science, doi:10.31219/osf.io/qwcek
  19. ^ a b Sances, Michael W. (January 2016). "The Distributional Impact of Greater Responsiveness: Evidence from New York Towns". The Journal of Politics. 78 (1): 105–119. doi:10.1086/683026. ISSN 0022-3816. S2CID 155437616.
  20. ^ Besley, Timothy J.; Kudamatsu, Masayuki (1 May 2007). "Making Autocracy Work". SSRN 1127017.
  21. ^ a b c Simpser, Alberto (2013). Why governments and parties manipulate elections: theory, practice, and implications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-1-107-30688-2. OCLC 826857655.
  22. ^ Long, James Dunway (2014). Voting, Fraud, and Violence: Political Accountability in African Elections (Thesis). University of California San Diego.
  23. ^ Schedler, Andreas (2002). "The Menu of Manipulation". Journal of Democracy. 13 (2): 36–50. doi:10.1353/jod.2002.0031. ISSN 1086-3214. S2CID 154830665.
  24. ^ a b Callen, Michael; Long, James D. (2015). "Institutional Corruption and Election Fraud: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Afghanistan" (PDF). American Economic Review. 105 (1): 354–381. doi:10.1257/aer.20120427. ISSN 0002-8282. S2CID 7016902.
  25. ^ a b Ichino, Nahomi; Schündeln, Matthias (2012). "Deterring or Displacing Electoral Irregularities? Spillover Effects of Observers in a Randomized Field Experiment in Ghana". The Journal of Politics. 74 (1): 292–307. doi:10.1017/S0022381611001368. ISSN 0022-3816. S2CID 10426326.
  26. ^ a b Beaulieu, Emily; Hyde, Susan D. (2009). "In the Shadow of Democracy Promotion: Strategic Manipulation, International Observers, and Election Boycotts". Comparative Political Studies. 42 (3): 392–415. doi:10.1177/0010414008325571. ISSN 0010-4140. S2CID 155078768.
  27. ^ Hafner-Burton, Emilie Marie; Hyde, Susan D.; Jablonski, Ryan S. (6 September 2012). "When Do Governments Resort to Election Violence?". British Journal of Political Science. Rochester, N.Y. SSRN 1667063.
  28. ^ McKie, Kristin (2019). "Presidential Term Limit Contravention: Abolish, Extend, Fail, or Respect?". Comparative Political Studies. 52 (10): 1500–1534. doi:10.1177/0010414019830737. ISSN 0010-4140. S2CID 159155380.
  29. ^ a b c Batley, Richard; Mcloughlin, Claire (October 2015). "The Politics of Public Services: A Service Characteristics Approach". World Development. 74: 275–285. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.05.018.
  30. ^ a b c Martin, Lucy; Raffler, Pia J. (7 June 2020). "Fault Lines: The Effects of Bureaucratic Power on Electoral Accountability". American Journal of Political Science. 65 (1). Wiley: 210–224. doi:10.1111/ajps.12530. ISSN 0092-5853. S2CID 209526364.
  31. ^ a b Butler, Daniel M. (22 August 2011). "Can Learning Constituency Opinion Affect How Legislators Vote? Results from a Field Experiment". Quarterly Journal of Political Science. 6 (1): 55–83. doi:10.1561/100.00011019. S2CID 155004601.
  32. ^ a b Beath, Andrew; Christia, Fotini; Enikolopov, Ruben (2017). "Direct democracy and resource allocation: Experimental evidence from Afghanistan" (PDF). Journal of Development Economics. 124. Elsevier BV: 199–213. doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2016.10.001. hdl:1721.1/127650. ISSN 0304-3878.
  33. ^
    • Rehfeld, Andrew (May 2009). "Representation Rethought: On Trustees, Delegates, and Gyroscopes in the Study of Political Representation and Democracy". American Political Science Review. 103 (2): 214–230. doi:10.1017/S0003055409090261. ISSN 0003-0554. S2CID 53957756.
    • Fox, Justin; Shotts, Kenneth W. (October 2009). "Delegates or Trustees? A Theory of Political Accountability". The Journal of Politics. 71 (4): 1225–1237. doi:10.1017/S0022381609990260. ISSN 0022-3816. S2CID 9879793.
  34. ^ a b c d Min, Brian; Golden, Miriam (February 2014). "Electoral cycles in electricity losses in India". Energy Policy. 65: 619–625. Bibcode:2014EnPol..65..619M. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.09.060.
  35. ^ a b c Harding, Robin (October 2015). "Attribution And Accountability: Voting for roads in Ghana". World Politics. 67 (4): 656–689. doi:10.1017/S0043887115000209. ISSN 0043-8871. S2CID 20470554.
  36. ^ a b Miller, Michael K. (October 2015). "Electoral Authoritarianism and Human Development". Comparative Political Studies. 48 (12): 1526–1562. doi:10.1177/0010414015582051. ISSN 0010-4140. S2CID 154285722.
  37. ^ a b Miller, Michael K. (May 2015). "Elections, Information, and Policy Responsiveness in Autocratic Regimes". Comparative Political Studies. 48 (6): 691–727. doi:10.1177/0010414014555443. ISSN 0010-4140. S2CID 154879177.
  38. ^ a b Pierskalla, Jan H.; Sacks, Audrey (October 2020). "Personnel Politics: Elections, Clientelistic Competition and Teacher Hiring in Indonesia". British Journal of Political Science. 50 (4): 1283–1305. doi:10.1017/S0007123418000601. ISSN 0007-1234. S2CID 149452970.
  39. ^
    • Barro, Robert J. (March 1973). "The control of politicians: An economic model". Public Choice. 14–14 (1): 19–42. doi:10.1007/bf01718440. ISSN 0048-5829. S2CID 154999534.
    • Besley, Timothy J.; Burgess, Robin (2002). "The Political Economy of Government Responsiveness: Theory and Evidence from India" (PDF). SSRN Working Paper Series. doi:10.2139/ssrn.319012. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 8657561.
    • Ferejohn, John (1986). "Incumbent performance and electoral control". Public Choice. 50 (1–3): 5–25. doi:10.1007/bf00124924. ISSN 0048-5829. S2CID 153577661.
    • Manin, Bernard; Przeworski, Adam; Stokes, Susan C. (13 September 1999), "Elections and Representation", Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, Cambridge University Press, pp. 29–54, doi:10.1017/cbo9781139175104.002, ISBN 978-0-521-64616-1
    • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (5 April 2010). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. doi:10.4324/9780203857090. ISBN 9780203857090.
  40. ^ a b Madestam, Andreas; Shoag, Daniel; Veuger, Stan; Yanagizawa-Drott, David (30 September 2013). "Do Political Protests Matter? Evidence from the Tea Party Movement*" (PDF). The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 128 (4): 1633–1685. doi:10.1093/qje/qjt021. ISSN 0033-5533.
  41. ^ a b Bratton, Michael; van de Walle, Nicolas (July 1992). "Popular Protest and Political Reform in Africa". Comparative Politics. 24 (4): 419. doi:10.2307/422153. ISSN 0010-4159. JSTOR 422153.
  42. ^ a b Anderson, Sarah E.; Buntaine, Mark T.; Liu, Mengdi; Zhang, Bing (8 May 2019). "Non-Governmental Monitoring of Local Governments Increases Compliance with Central Mandates: A National-Scale Field Experiment in China". American Journal of Political Science. 63 (3): 626–643. doi:10.1111/ajps.12428. ISSN 0092-5853. S2CID 164557135.
  43. ^ a b Baldwin, Kate; Holzinger, Katharina (16 June 2019). "Traditional Political Institutions and Democracy: Reassessing Their Compatibility and Accountability". Comparative Political Studies. 52 (12): 1747–1774. doi:10.1177/0010414019852686. ISSN 0010-4140. S2CID 197832991.
  44. ^ a b c Tsai, Lily (2007). "Solidary Groups, Informal Accountability, and Local Public Goods Provision in Rural China". The American Political Science Review. 101 (2): 355–372. doi:10.1017/S0003055407070153. S2CID 146348780.
  45. ^ a b c Baldwin, Kate (2015). The Paradox of Traditional Chiefs in Democratic Africa. Cambridge University Press.
  46. ^
    • Besley, Timothy J. (2007). Making autocracy work. Centre for Economic Policy Research. OCLC 255778387.
    • Baldwin, Kate (2019). "Elected MPs, Traditional Chiefs, and Local Public Goods: Evidence on the Role of Leaders in Co-Production From Rural Zambia". Comparative Political Studies. 52 (12): 1925–1956. doi:10.1177/0010414018774372. ISSN 0010-4140. S2CID 158062055.
  47. ^ Bates, Robert (1981). Markets and States in Tropical Africa: The Political Basis of Agricultural Policies. University of California Press.
  48. ^ a b Besley, Timothy J.; Kudamatsu, Masayuki (May 2007), Making Autocracy Work (PDF), LSE STICERD Research Paper No. DEDPS48
  49. ^ Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce; Morrow, James D.; Siverson, Randolph M.; Smith, Alastair (17 September 2002). "Political Institutions, Policy Choice and the Survival of Leaders". British Journal of Political Science. 32 (4): 559–590. doi:10.1017/s0007123402000236. ISSN 0007-1234. S2CID 40514840.
  50. ^
    • Boix, Carles; Posner, Daniel N. (October 1998). "Social Capital: Explaining Its Origins and Effects on Government Performance". British Journal of Political Science. 28 (4): 686–693. doi:10.1017/s0007123498000313. ISSN 0007-1234. S2CID 4503343.
    • EDWARDS, BOB; FOLEY, MICHAEL W. (September 1998). "Civil Society and Social Capital Beyond Putnam". American Behavioral Scientist. 42 (1): 124–139. doi:10.1177/0002764298042001010. ISSN 0002-7642. S2CID 144681913.
    • Ehrenberg, John (1999). Civil Society: The critical History of an Idea. New York University Press.
    • Putnam, Robert D.; Leonardi, Robert; Nonetti, Raffaella Y. (27 May 1994). Making Democracy Work. Princeton University Press. doi:10.2307/j.ctt7s8r7. ISBN 978-1-4008-2074-0. S2CID 155009926.
  51. ^ a b Ofosu, George Kwaku (2 August 2019). "Do Fairer Elections Increase the Responsiveness of Politicians?" (PDF). American Political Science Review. 113 (4): 963–979. doi:10.1017/s0003055419000479. ISSN 0003-0554. S2CID 201385531.
  52. ^ a b Carreri, Maria (2018). "Can Good Politicians Compensate for Bad Institutions? Evidence from an Original Survey of Italian Mayors". SSRN Working Paper Series. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3239492. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 160023663.
  53. ^ a b c Berry, Christopher R.; Howell, William G. (August 2007). "Accountability and Local Elections: Rethinking Retrospective Voting". The Journal of Politics. 69 (3): 844–858. doi:10.1111/j.1468-2508.2007.00579.x. ISSN 0022-3816. S2CID 42972242.
  54. ^ Grossman, Guy; Michelitch, Kristin (1 February 2018). "Information Dissemination, Competitive Pressure, and Politician Performance between Elections: A Field Experiment in Uganda". American Political Science Review. 112 (2): 280–301. doi:10.1017/s0003055417000648. ISSN 0003-0554. S2CID 15659219.
  55. ^ Dunning, Thad; Grossman, Guy; Humphreys, Macartan; Hyde, Susan D.; McIntosh, Craig; Nellis, Gareth, eds. (4 July 2019). Information, Accountability, and Cumulative Learning. doi:10.1017/9781108381390. ISBN 9781108381390. S2CID 243627947.
  56. ^ a b c Highton, Benjamin (May 2008). "Job Approval and Senate Election Outcomes in the United States". Legislative Studies Quarterly. 33 (2): 245–261. doi:10.3162/036298008784311019. ISSN 0362-9805.
  57. ^ a b Brown, Adam R.; Jacobson, Gary C. (December 2008). "Party, Performance, and Strategic Politicians: The Dynamics of Elections for Senator and Governor in 2006". State Politics & Policy Quarterly. 8 (4): 384–409. doi:10.1177/153244000800800403. ISSN 1532-4400. S2CID 154373150.
  58. ^ Erikson, Robert S.; Bafumi, Joseph; Wilson, Bret (October 2001). "Was the 2000 Presidential Election Predictable?". Political Science & Politics. 34 (4): 815–819. doi:10.1017/S1049096501000750. ISSN 1049-0965. S2CID 153487954.
  59. ^ a b c De Vries, Catherine E.; Solaz, Hector (11 May 2017). "The Electoral Consequences of Corruption". Annual Review of Political Science. 20 (1): 391–408. doi:10.1146/annurev-polisci-052715-111917. ISSN 1094-2939.
  60. ^
    • Ferraz, Claudio; Finan, Frederico (1 May 2008). "Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effects of Brazil's Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 123 (2): 703–745. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.222.8752. doi:10.1162/qjec.2008.123.2.703. ISSN 0033-5533. S2CID 8148400.
    • Helping Countries Combat Corruption. The Role of the World Bank. World Bank. 1997.
  61. ^ a b Chong, Alberto; De La O, Ana L.; Karlan, Dean; Wantchekon, Leonard (1 January 2015). "Does Corruption Information Inspire the Fight or Quash the Hope? A Field Experiment in Mexico on Voter Turnout, Choice, and Party Identification". The Journal of Politics. 77 (1): 55–71. doi:10.1086/678766. ISSN 0022-3816. S2CID 8379010.
  62. ^ a b c Klašnja, Marko; Little, Andrew T.; Tucker, Joshua A. (July 2018). "Political Corruption Traps*". Political Science Research and Methods. 6 (3): 413–428. doi:10.1017/psrm.2016.45. ISSN 2049-8470. S2CID 155201513.
  63. ^ a b c d Gandhi, Jennifer; Ruiz-Rufino, Rubén (2015). Routledge handbook of comparative political institutions. Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge. ISBN 978-1-315-73137-7. OCLC 907374446.
  64. ^ Mcmillan, John; Zoido, Pablo (December 2004). "How to Subvert Democracy: Montesinos in Peru" (PDF). Journal of Economic Perspectives. 18 (4): 69–92. doi:10.1257/0895330042632690. ISSN 0895-3309. S2CID 219372153.
  65. ^ Kiewiet, D. Roderick; McCubbins, Mathew D. (18 June 1991). The Logic of Delegation. University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0-226-43531-2.
  66. ^ Brierley, Sarah (2020). "Unprincipled Principals: Co-opted Bureaucrats and Corruption in Ghana". American Journal of Political Science. 64 (2): 209–222. doi:10.1111/ajps.12495. ISSN 1540-5907. S2CID 202313542.
  67. ^ Fisman, Raymond; Golden, Miriam A. (2017). Corruption: What Everyone Needs to Know. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-046397-7.
  68. ^ Jiang, Junyan; Shao, Zijie; Zhang, Zhiyuan (n.d.). "The Price of Probity: Anticorruption and Adverse Selection in the Chinese Bureaucracy". British Journal of Political Science. 52: 41–64. doi:10.1017/S0007123420000393. ISSN 0007-1234. S2CID 234411216.
  69. ^ Fisman, Raymond; Golden, Miriam (26 May 2017). "How to fight corruption". Science. 356 (6340): 803–804. Bibcode:2017Sci...356..803F. doi:10.1126/science.aan0815. ISSN 0036-8075. PMID 28546172. S2CID 206658780.
  70. ^ Walker, Samuel E. (2005). The New World of Police Accountability (1st ed.). Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publications, Inc. ISBN 978-1-412-90943-3. OCLC 56334321.
  71. ^ De Angelis & Wold, J & B (2016). "Perceived accountability and public attitudes toward local police". Criminal Justice Studies. 29 (3): 232–252. doi:10.1080/1478601X.2016.1158177. S2CID 148242583.
  72. ^ Romm, Norma R.A. (2001). Accountability in Social Research. New York: Klower Academic. ISBN 978-0-306-46564-2.
  73. ^ Truman, Carole (2010). "Review of New Racism: Revisiting Researcher Accountabilities". Sociological Research Online. Retrieved 27 August 2012.
  74. ^ Thompson, Dennis F. (2005). "The Problem of Many Hands". Restoring Responsibility: Ethics in Government, Business and Healthcare. Cambridge University Press. pp. 33–49. ISBN 978-0-521-54722-2.
  75. ^ Thompson, Dennis F. (9 March 2014). "Responsibility for Failures of Government: The Problem of Many Hands". The American Review of Public Administration. 44 (3). SAGE Publications: 259–273. doi:10.1177/0275074014524013. ISSN 0275-0740. S2CID 154304430.
  76. ^ Harriman, Ed (28 September 2007). . London: Guardian. Archived from the original on 12 April 2008. Retrieved 26 August 2009.
  77. ^ . National Council on Measurement in Education. Archived from the original on 22 July 2017. Retrieved 6 December 2019.
  78. ^
    • Greenberg, Daniel (1992). "'Ethics' is a Course Taught By Life Experience". Education in America: A View from Sudbury Valley. The Sudbury Valley School. pp. 60–62. ISBN 978-1-888947-07-6.
    • Greenberg, Daniel (1987). . Archived from the original on 11 May 2011.
    • Feldman, Jay (2001), The Moral Behavior of Children and Adolescents at a Democratic School
    • "Law and Order: Foundations of Discipline". The Crisis in American Education: An Analysis and a Proposal. The Sudbury Valley School. 1970. pp. 49–55. ISBN 978-1-888947-05-2.
    • Greenberg, Daniel (1992). "Democracy Must be Experienced to be Learned". Education in America: A View from Sudbury Valley. The Sudbury Valley School. pp. 103–107. ISBN 978-1-888947-07-6.
    • Reiss, Steven (2010). "Whatever Happened to Personal Responsibility?". Psychology Today.
  79. ^ Brunetti, Aymo; Weder, Beatrice (2003), "A free press is bad news for corruption", Journal of Public Economics, 87 (7–8): 1801–1824, doi:10.1016/s0047-2727(01)00186-4
  80. ^
    • Adserà, Alícia; Boix, Carles; Payne, Mark (2000), "Are You Being Served?: Political Accountability and Quality of Government" (PDF), Working Paper, no. 438, Inter-American Development Bank Research Department, retrieved 17 August 2014
    • Adserà, Alícia; Boix, Carles; Payne, Mark (2003), "Are You Being Served? Political Accountability and Quality of Government" (PDF), Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 19 (2): 445–490, doi:10.1093/jleo/19.2.445, hdl:10419/87999, retrieved 31 August 2014
  81. ^ a b Snyder, James M.; Strömberg, David (2010), "Press Coverage and Political Accountability", Journal of Political Economy, 118 (2): 355–408, CiteSeerX 10.1.1.210.8371, doi:10.1086/652903, S2CID 154635874
  82. ^ a b Besley, Timothy; Burgess, Robin (2001), "Political agency, government responsiveness and the role of the media", European Economic Review, 45 (4–6): 629–640, doi:10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00133-7
  83. ^ Barbera, Pablo; Casas, Andreu; Nagler, Jonathan; Egan, Patrick; Bonneau, Richard; Jost, John; Tucker, Joshua (2019), "Who Leads? Who Follows? Measuring Issue Attention and Agenda Setting by Legislators and the Mass Public Using Social Media Data", American Political Science Review, 113 (4): 883–901, doi:10.1017/S0003055419000352, PMC 7672368, PMID 33303996
  84. ^ Ferraz, Claudio; Finan, Frederico (2008), "Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effect of Brazil's Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123 (2): 703–745, doi:10.1162/qjec.2008.123.2.703, S2CID 8148400
  85. ^ Besley, Timothy; Prat, Andrea (2006), "Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability" (PDF), American Economic Review, 96 (3): 720–736, doi:10.1257/aer.96.3.720, S2CID 13849989
  86. ^
    • Munger, Kevin; Bonneau, Richard; Nagler, Jonathan; Tucker, Joshua (2019), "Elites Tweet to Get Feet Off the Streets: Measuring Regime Social Media Strategies During Protest", Political Science Research and Methods, 7 (4): 815–834, doi:10.1017/psrm.2018.3
    • King, Gary; Pan, Jennifer; Roberts, Margaret (2013), "How Censorship in China Allows Government Criticism but Silences Collective Expression", American Political Science Review, 107 (2): 326–343, doi:10.1017/S0003055413000014, S2CID 53577293
    • King, Gary; Pan, Jennifer; Roberts, Margaret (2013), "How the Chinese Government Fabricates Social Media Posts for Strategic Distraction, Not Engaged Argument", American Political Science Review, 111 (3): 484–501, doi:10.1017/S0003055417000144
  87. ^ Boas, Taylor; Hidalgo, F. Daniel (2011), "Controlling the Airwaves: Incumbency Advantage and Community Radio in Brazil", American Journal of Political Science, 55 (4): 869–885, doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2011.00532.x
  88. ^ Starr, Paul (2012), "An Unexpected Crisis: The News Media in Post-industrial Democracies" (PDF), International Journal of Press/Politics, 17 (2): 234–242, doi:10.1177/1940161211434422, S2CID 146729965, retrieved 31 August 2014, Since 2000, the newspaper industry alone has lost an estimated "$1.6 billion in annual reporting and editing capacity... or roughly 30 per cent", but the new non-profit money coming into journalism has made up less than one-tenth that amount.
  89. ^ . Archived from the original on 17 May 2013. Retrieved 6 December 2019.
  90. ^ Website: . Archived from the original on 8 September 2013. Retrieved 6 December 2019.
  91. ^ Webpage: . Archived from the original on 3 July 2013. Retrieved 28 July 2013.
  92. ^ ActionAid (2005). ALPS - Accountability, Learning, and Planning System

Further reading edit

  • Bovens, Mark (1998). The Quest for Responsibility: Accountability and Citizenship in Complex Organisations. Cambridge University Press.
  • Bovens, Mark (2010). "Two concepts of accountability: accountability as a virtue and as a mechanism". West European Politics. 33 (5): 946–967. doi:10.1080/01402382.2010.486119. hdl:1874/204069. S2CID 154886643.
  • Harwood, Sterling (1994). "Accountability". In Roth, John K. (ed.). Ethics: Ready Reference. Salem Press.
  • Luban, David; Strudler, Alan; Wasserman, David (1992). "Moral Responsibility in the Age of Bureaucracy". Michigan Law Review. 90 (8): 2348–2392. doi:10.2307/1289575. JSTOR 1289575.
  • Mastop, Rosja (2010). "Characterising Responsibility in Organisational Structures: The Problem of Many Hands". In Governatori, G.; Sartor, G. (eds.). Deontic Logic in Computer Science. Berlin: Springer-Verlag. pp. 274–287. ISBN 978-3-540-70524-6.
  • Painter-Morland, Mollie; Deslandes, Ghislain (2 April 2015). "Authentic leading as relational accountability: Facing up to the conflicting expectations of media leaders" (PDF). Leadership. 13 (4). SAGE Publications: 424–444. doi:10.1177/1742715015578307. ISSN 1742-7150. S2CID 2430595.
  • Romm, Norma R.A. (31 May 2001). Accountability in Social Research. Springer Science & Business Media. ISBN 978-0-306-46564-2.
  • Thompson, Dennis F. (2005). "The Responsibility of Advisers". Restoring Responsibility: Ethics in Government, Business, and Healthcare. New York: Cambridge University Press. pp. 33–49. ISBN 978-0-521-54722-2.
  • Thompson, Dennis F. (2014). "Responsibility for Failures of Government: The Problem of Many Hands". American Review of Public Administration. 44 (3): 259–273. doi:10.1177/0275074014524013. S2CID 154304430.
  • Williams, Christopher (2006). Leadership accountability in a globalizing world. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

External links edit

  •   Media related to Accountability at Wikimedia Commons
  • Citizens' Circle for Accountability

accountability, terms, ethics, governance, equated, with, answerability, culpability, liability, expectation, account, giving, aspect, governance, been, central, discussions, related, problems, public, sector, nonprofit, private, corporate, individual, context. Accountability in terms of ethics and governance is equated with answerability culpability liability and the expectation of account giving 1 As in an aspect of governance it has been central to discussions related to problems in the public sector nonprofit private corporate and individual contexts In leadership roles 2 accountability is the acknowledgment of and assumption of responsibility for actions products decisions and policies such as administration governance and implementation including the obligation to report justify and be answerable for resulting consequences In governance accountability has expanded beyond the basic definition of being called to account for one s actions 3 It is frequently described as an account giving relationship between individuals e g A is accountable to B when A is obliged to inform B about A s past or future actions and decisions to justify them and to suffer punishment in the case of eventual misconduct 4 Accountability cannot exist without proper accounting practices in other words an absence of accounting means an absence of accountability citation needed Another key area that contributes to accountability is good records management 5 Contents 1 History and etymology 2 Political 2 1 Electoral 2 1 1 Electoral manipulation and accountability 2 2 Administrative 2 2 1 Public goods 3 Non electoral 3 1 Political protests 3 2 Selectorates 3 3 Civil societies 3 4 Public opinion polls 3 5 Shared interests 4 Accountability and corruption 5 Police accountability 6 Organizational 6 1 Ethical 6 2 Security 6 3 Individuals within organizations 6 4 Public private overlap 7 In education 8 Media and accountability 9 Standards 10 See also 11 Footnotes 12 Further reading 13 External linksHistory and etymology edit Accountability derives from the late Latin accomptare to account a prefixed form of computare to calculate which in turn is derived from putare to reckon 6 While the word itself does not appear in English until its use in 13th century Norman England 7 the concept of account giving has ancient roots in record keeping activities related to governance and money lending systems that first developed in Ancient Egypt 8 Israel 9 Babylon 10 Greece 11 and later Rome 12 Political editPolitical accountability is when a politician makes choices on behalf of the people and the people have the ability to reward or sanction the politician 13 In representative democracies citizens delegate power to elected officials through periodic elections and such officials are empowered to represent or act in the citizens interest 13 A challenge is how to see to it that those with such power who presumably have divergent interests from the citizens nonetheless act in their best interests 14 Citizens can rely on rewards or sanctions to reward or threaten politicians who might otherwise act in a manner that is antithetical to the people s interest 14 Accountability occurs when citizens only vote to re elect representatives who act in their interests and if representatives then select policies that will help them be re elected 14 Governments are accountable if voters can discern whether governments are acting in their interest and sanction them appropriately so that those incumbents who act in the best interest of the citizens win reelection and those who do not lose them 14 Representatives can be held accountable through two mechanisms electoral replacement and rational anticipation 15 In electoral replacement citizens vote to replace representatives who are out of step with their interests Rational anticipation requires that representatives anticipate the consequences of being out of step with their constituency and then govern in accordance with citizens wishes to avoid negative consequences 15 Accountability can still be achieved even if citizens are not perfectly knowledgeable about their representatives actions as long as representatives believe that they will be held accountable by citizens they will still be motivated to act in accordance with the citizens interests 16 Electoral edit Electoral accountability refers to citizens using their vote to sanction or reward politicians 14 Some researchers have considered accountability using formal theory which makes assumptions about the state of the world to draw larger conclusions Voters can hold representatives accountable through the process of sanctioning voting the incumbent out of office in response to poor performance 14 While politicians face a decrease in vote share as a result of poor performance they are less likely to see an increase in vote share for good performance 17 Selection voters choosing candidates based on who will best represent their interests is another method by which voters hold their representatives accountable 14 These methods of accountability can occur simultaneously with voters holding representatives accountable using both sanctioning and selection 14 These conclusions rely on the assumption that voters do not observe the policy implemented by the incumbent but do know their own welfare clarification needed 14 Some factors make it harder for voters to sanction incumbents When politicians do not have control over outcomes it becomes harder how to hold them accountable 17 Additionally when organizations are unable to monitor elections and provide information to voters then voters struggle to sanction the incumbent 18 When voters are better informed about the incumbent s performance the incumbent is more vulnerable to voter sanctioning 18 Furthermore when incumbents face sanctioning challengers are more likely to enter the race 18 While elections provide a mechanism which can theoretically increase government accountability to citizens they may instead lead to less egalitarian policy outcomes because those who hold the government accountable tend to be from wealthier segments of society 19 For example a study of elected versus appointed property assessors in the state of New York shows that the election of property assessors leads to policies that severely undertax wealthier homes relative to poorer homes 19 Electoral manipulation and accountability edit Studies on political accountability have emphasized the key role of elections in promoting accountability in democratic settings It is through elections that citizens hold governments accountable for past performance 14 20 However the role of elections in fostering accountability is often undermined by electoral manipulation and fraud 21 By preventing citizens from removing leaders through elections based on their performance in office electoral manipulation breaks down accountability and may undercut the consolidation of democratic institutions 22 Electoral manipulation is not rare some estimates are that in the 1990s and 2000s up to one fourth of elections suffered some form of substantial manipulation 21 This includes a large array of pre election and election day tactics such as outlawing rival parties and candidates employing violence and intimidation and manipulating voter registration and vote count 23 Some efforts to improve accountability by preventing electoral manipulation and fraud have obtained a certain measure of success such as using cell phone applications for monitoring and disseminating polling station results 24 and employing domestic or international election observers 25 26 However governments may simply alter the type of manipulation or where it occurs in order to deceive observers and monitoring agencies 25 26 Governments politicians and political parties are more likely to resort to electoral manipulation and fraud when they believe they might be removed from office and when they face few institutional constraints to their power 27 Low political competition has also been linked to some forms of manipulation such as abolishing presidential term limits 28 Well connected how candidates are more likely to resort to vote count fraud 24 Governments may engage in electoral manipulation not only to obtain victory at a given election or to remain in office longer but also for post election reasons such as reducing the strength of the opposition or increasing their own bargaining power in the subsequent period 21 Administrative edit Public goods edit Politicians may be incentivized to provide public goods as a means of accountability clarification needed 29 The ability of voters to attribute the credit and blame of outcomes also determines the extent of public goods provision 29 30 Research suggests that public goods provision is conditional on vague being able to attribute outcomes to politicians as opposed to civil servants 30 This attribution can be enhanced by more short run and visible inputs and outcomes such as famine relief or access to drinking water whereas lower visibility issues such as sanitation and education may be more difficult to attribute credit for and thus less likely to provide for 29 Another condition determining how voters use the provision of public goods to hold leaders accountable is whether the prioritization of public goods is determined either directly via vote or delegated to a governing body 31 32 An experiment in New Mexico regarding proposed spending during the state s 2008 special summer legislative session provides evidence that legislators update their positions when learning about voters policy preferences indicating that a representative democracy can increase accountability when politicians learn about voters preferences 31 A 2016 experiment in Afghanistan regarding rural development projects however finds that when voters directly prioritize their preferences at the ballot box they perceive the quality of local government to be higher than when a governing committee prioritizes development projects 32 These contrasting outcomes highlight a debate between trustees and delegates though the lack of objective superior outcomes in projects decided by vote as opposed to committee in the Afghanistan experiment indicate neither is superior to the other in determining which public goods should be given priority 33 Other research indicates that voters use elections to hold politicians accountable for the provision of public goods 34 35 In India rural areas are charged a flat rate for electricity but in the province of Uttar Pradesh line loss electricity that is consumed but not billed is significantly higher in election years than non election years and increases in line loss reliably predict electoral gains 34 Voters rewarded incumbent politicians with a 12 increase in party seats in response to a 10 increase of unbilled electricity in 2007 elections 34 In Ghana the improvement of road conditions is linked to an increasing vote share for incumbent parties 35 Both of these research outcomes hinge on voters being able to attribute the service of public goods to politicians 34 35 30 Politicians may also have incentives to respond to pressure for public goods provision in electoral autocracies 36 37 There is evidence that as autocratic governments lose seats in their party s legislatures they respond by increasing spending on public goods such as education healthcare and pensions 36 There is further evidence suggesting higher quality of life civil liberties and human development in electoral autocracies lending credence to the theory that autocratic rulers use elections as a bellwether against popular discontent and citizen opposition and in turn increase public goods provision to dampen the grievances of disgruntled citizens even in non democracies 37 While the introduction of elections is generally thought to improve public goods provision in some cases researchers have shown that it may reduce its quality 38 For example the introduction of direct elections for local district office in Indonesia resulted in political interference in the hiring process for bureaucrats in the public education sector reducing the quality of education provision politicians were incentivized to dole out patronage positions in the education sector especially in election years and where such positions were added student test scores were lower 38 Non electoral editGovernments are held accountable if citizens can punish or reward the government to influence it to pursue their best interests 14 While scholars who study democratic theory emphasize the role of elections in ensuring accountability 39 another strand of scholars investigates non electoral forms of accountability in democracies and non democracies 40 41 42 43 and the conditions that make unelected leaders represent the interests of the general public 44 45 46 Political protests edit Political changes after protests can be the result of the protests per se or symptoms of shifts in political preferences underneath the observable phenomena of the protests One study of the Tea Party movement in the United States has shown that protests per se have an impact on political change 40 Other scholars studied the effect of protests on political changes in developing countries Mass protests instigated by economic hardship and political repression occurred in 16 sub Saharan African countries and 21 governments in the region implemented significant political reforms such as the adoption of multi party elections 41 Authoritarian regimes in Africa distorted the market and reduced the cost of farm produce in favor of urban workers at the cost of rural farmers in the 1980s to prevent urban unrest which is more visible and easier to mobilize than rural protests 47 Selectorates edit Belsky et al point out that whereas under more democratic governance accountability is built into the institution of the state by a habit of regular elections accountability in autocratic regimes 48 relies on a selectorate a group that legitimizes or delegitimizes the autocrat s powers according to selectorate theory Selectorates are those on whom a leader depends in order to hold onto power and those who have the ability to depose a leader 49 When a selectorate s hold on power is not overly dependent on the leader in office selectorates can remove poorly performing leaders and this accountability by selectorates renders it possible for autocracies to perform better for the benefit of all 48 Beyond that institutions specify can act as credible restraints on autocracy as well how Civil societies edit In democracies voluntary associations interest groups and associational activity can improve the performance of the government 50 One study showed that civil society organizations such as NGOs can increase the performance of local government according to the central government s standards by monitoring and disclosing information about local government performance in authoritarian regimes like China 42 Solidarity groups in rural China in which members share moral obligations and interests can hold local officials accountable as well 44 when i the solidarity group encompasses everyone under the local government s jurisdiction and ii local officials are embedded in the group as members The social standing and recognition of these groups encourages local officials to perform well as they value high moral standing in the group 44 At the local level various accountability measures exist that impact the job performance of elected officials 51 52 53 In Uganda civil society organizations CSOs that divulge to the public how well an incumbent is performing their job duties in a district with an upcoming competitive election increase the performance of the politician for the rest of their term 54 In contrast to these works a meta analysis released in 2019 uncovers no effects from CSO voter information campaigns on political accountability after examining the results from seven trials across six countries 55 In Ghana election day monitoring of polling centers for district level positions as well as an increase in the awareness of monitoring in an upcoming election increases job performance among incumbents who spend more of their annual Constituency Development Fund allocations from the central government on public goods for the electorate 51 In locales with weaker institutions when citizens elect leaders with higher levels of competency these officials have a greater ability to overcome the barriers of bad informal institutions and deliver more goods and long term investment projects for the constituency without needing to raise taxes 52 Additionally many local elections are for positions that involve performing jobs with a single function such as a school board member or a sheriff These elected officials are held accountable to their positions mainly through information provided to the public through the media 53 When the media focuses attention on data trends associated with these positions constituents are then able to use this information to retrospectively vote for or against an incumbent based on their performance in office 53 Public opinion polls edit Approval ratings generated through public opinion polling create a measure of job performance during an incumbent s term that has implications for whether the official will retain their seat or if reelection will even be sought 56 57 These approval ratings predict election outcomes when combined with other factors included in Bayesian Model Averaging forecasts 58 In the United States senator job approval ratings affect whether a senator will retire the quality of candidates that seek to challenge them the amount of money the senator can raise to seek reelection if they decide to run and the outcome of the election itself 56 Strategic incumbent senators will seek reelection less when their approval ratings are low during their time in office 56 57 Shared interests edit Traditional leaders in Zambia provide local public goods despite the fact that they lack an electoral incentive to do so 45 Many customary chiefs never leave the communities they lead and depend on local sources for a significant portion of their income thus traditional leaders may facilitate bringing in local public goods and benefit from the community s development over time just like stationary bandits definition needed in Olson s argument definition needed 43 45 Accountability and corruption editPolitical corruption refers to the misuse or the abuse of public office for private gains Corrupt practices include fraud appropriation of public funds and accepting bribes 59 60 Corruption can cause people to negatively evaluate politicians since citizens may perceive corruption as a signal of poor performance motivating them to sanction an incumbent 61 As the model of retrospective voting suggests that voters incentivize good politicians behavior by rewarding good performance and punishing bad performance citizens are expected to sanction corrupt politicians 59 However studies suggest that though voters have a distaste for corruption they often fail to punish corrupt incumbents some of them receive benefits from their representatives corrupt practices and prefer to retain this type of politician 62 59 In high corruption contexts voters may become more tolerant of or even prefer corrupt politicians because others are also perceived as corrupt leading to a corrupt equilibrium where voters are generally willing to retain corrupt politicians referred to as a political corruption trap 62 This high corruption equilibrium is difficult to break due to interaction between corrupt politicians voters who tolerate and retain corrupt politicians and potential entrants or challengers who also engage in corrupt practices leading to the maintenance of corruption 62 Democracy does not seem to reduce corruption 63 Economic development is associated with a decrease in corruption 63 Freedom of the press contributes to the reduction of corruption by exposing corrupt actions 63 Documentation on how a corrupt government e g Alberto Fujimori s government from 1998 to 2000 in Peru can strategically undermine checks and balances institutions suggests that the news media i e newspapers and mainly television is crucial to the dissemination of information to the public 64 There is also evidence about the importance of local media such as local radio stations in holding corrupt incumbents accountable and in promoting non corrupt politicians citation needed Information about corruption may not only lead to vote losses for the incumbent parties but also for challenging parties as well the erosion of partisan attachments which implies that information about corruption also provokes citizens disengagement from the political process 61 Scholarly literature about corruption finds mixed results about the role of political institutions on the level of a country s corruption 63 For example some scholarly research suggests that more horizontal accountability or oversight across branches of government would generally decrease corruption 65 However other research shows that increased oversight could increase corruption when actors in one branch can pressure actors in another to collude in Ghana bureaucrats are more likely to engage in corruption on behalf of politicians when politicians have higher levels of discretion to oversee the bureaucracy e g by threatening to transfer noncompliant bureaucrats 66 Low accountability for corruption is difficult to combat and some anti corruption activities may also lead to perverse consequences 67 For example in places where private sector work pays better than public sector work e g China highly qualified individuals engaging in public sector work may only find such work attractive because it allows for further compensation through corrupt activities Government anti corruption activities can therefore decrease the quality and overall representativeness of the bureaucracy as a result 68 On the other hand there is evidence that despite strategic evasion and unintentional consequences anti corruption initiatives are beneficial as they lower malfeasance and increase social welfare even where strategic evasion is relatively large 69 Police accountability editThis section is an excerpt from Police accountability edit Police accountability involves holding both individual police officers as well as law enforcement agencies responsible for effectively delivering basic services of crime control and maintaining order while treating individuals fairly and within the bounds of law Police are expected to uphold laws regarding due process search and seizure arrests discrimination as well as other laws relating to equal employment sexual harassment etc Holding police accountable is important for maintaining the public s faith in the system 70 42 Research has shown that the public prefers independent review of complaints against law enforcement rather than relying on police departments to conduct internal investigations There is a suggestion that such oversight would improve the public s view on the way in which police officers are held accountable 71 Organizational editEthical edit See also Social accounting and Environmental accounting Within an organization the principles and practices of ethical accountability aim to improve both the internal standard of individual and group conduct as well as external factors such as sustainable economic and ecologic strategies Also ethical accountability plays an important role in academic fields such as laboratory experiments and field research Debates around the practice of ethical accountability on the part of researchers in the social field vague whether professional or others were explored by Norma R A Romm in her work on Accountability in Social Research 72 and elsewhere 73 Researcher accountability implies that researchers are cognizant of and take some responsibility for the potential impact of their ways of doing research and of writing it up on the social fields of which the research is part Accountability is linked to considering carefully and being open to challenge in relation to one s choices concerning how research agendas are framed and the styles in which research results are written Security edit The traceability of actions performed on a system to a specific system entity user process device also affects accountability For example the use of unique user identification and authentication supports accountability and the use of shared user IDs and passwords degrades accountability Individuals within organizations edit Because many individuals in large organizations contribute in many ways to decisions and policies it is difficult even in principle to identify who should be accountable for the results This is what is known following Dennis F Thompson as the problem of many hands 74 It creates a dilemma for accountability If individuals are held accountable or responsible individuals who could not have prevented the results are either unfairly punished or they take responsibility in a symbolic ritual without suffering any consequences If only organizations are held accountable then all individuals in the organization are equally blameworthy or all are excused Various solutions have been proposed One is to broaden the criteria for individual responsibility so that individuals are held accountable for not anticipating failures in the organization Another solution recently proposed by Thompson is to hold individuals accountable for the design of the organization both retrospectively and prospectively 75 Accountability is an element of a responsibility assignment matrix which indicates who is ultimately answerable for the correct and thorough completion of a deliverable or task as well as the delegation of the work to those responsible Public private overlap edit With the increase in public service provided by private entities especially in Britain and the United States some have called for increased political accountability mechanisms for otherwise non political entities Legal scholar Anne Davies for instance argues that the line between public institutions and private entities like corporations is becoming blurred in certain areas of public service in the United Kingdom and that this can compromise political accountability in those areas She and others argue that some administrative law reform is necessary to address this accountability gap citation needed With respect to the public private overlap in the United States public concern over the contracting of government services including military and the resulting accountability gap was highlighted following the Nisour Square massacre perpetrated by the Blackwater security firm in Iraq 76 In education editAs defined by National Council on Measurement in Education NCME accountability is a program often legislated that attributes the responsibility for student learning to teachers school administrators and or students Test results typically are used to judge accountability and often consequences are imposed for shortcomings 77 Student accountability is traditionally based on school and classroom rules combined with sanctions for infringement In contrast some educational establishments such as Sudbury schools believe that students are personally responsible for their acts and that traditional schools do not permit students to choose their course of action fully they do not permit students to embark on the course once chosen and they do not permit students to suffer the consequences of the course once taken Freedom of choice freedom of action freedom to bear the results of action are considered the three great freedoms that constitute personal responsibility Sudbury schools claim that Ethics is a course taught by life experience They adduce that the essential ingredient for acquiring values and for moral action is personal responsibility that schools will become involved in the teaching of morals when they become communities of people who fully respect each other s right to make choices and that the only way the schools can become meaningful purveyors of ethical values is if they provide students and adults with real life experiences that are bearers of moral import Students are given complete responsibility for their own education and the school is run by a direct democracy in which students and staff are equals 78 Media and accountability editEconometric research has found that countries with greater press freedom tend to have less corruption 79 Greater political accountability and lower corruption were more likely where newspaper consumption was higher according to data from roughly 100 countries and from different states in the US 80 Congressmen where who receive less press coverage are less likely to produce a positive impact for their constituencies are less likely to stand witness before clarification needed congressional hearings and federal spending for their district is lower 81 One explanation for the positive impact of media on accountability stems from Besley and Burgess work 82 They argue that media resolves the information asymmetries between citizens and government and provides a way of overcoming obstacles preventing political action 82 When elected officials and the public gain information the public is better equipped to hold politicians accountable and politicians are more responsive 83 81 Ferraz amp Finan demonstrate this in the Brazilian context In their work they find releasing audit reports prior to elections creates a more informed electorate which holds incumbent officials accountable 84 While evidence supports the positive impact of press freedom on political accountability other work highlights the significance of factors such as media concentration and ownership as government tools for influencing or controlling news content 85 Non democratic regimes use media for a variety of purposes such as i to enhance regime resilience ii censor or iii strategically distract the public 86 Control of the media may also be especially beneficial to incumbents in new or developing democracies who consider media control a spoil of office 87 An analysis of the evolution of mass media in the U S and Europe since World War II noted mixed results from the growth of the Internet The digital revolution has been good for freedom of expression and information but has had mixed effects on freedom of the press It has disrupted traditional sources of funding and new forms of Internet journalism have replaced only a tiny fraction of what s been lost 88 Various systems have been proposed for increasing the funds available for investigative journalism that allow individual citizens to direct small amounts of government funds to news outlets or investigative journalism projects of their choice Standards editAccountability standards have been established that organizations can voluntarily commit to Standards apply in particular to the non profit world and to Corporate Social Responsibility initiatives Accountability standards include the INGO Accountability Charter signed by a large number of NGOs to demonstrate their commitment to accountability and transparency 89 AccountAbility s AA1000 series principles based standards to help organisations become more accountable responsible and sustainable They address issues affecting governance business models and organizational strategy as well as providing operational guidance on sustainability assurance and stakeholder engagement 90 Humanitarian Accountability Partnership 2010 standards for humanitarian organizations to help them design implement assess improve and recognize accountable programmes 91 In addition some non profit organizations set up their own commitments to accountability Accountability Learning and Planning System ALPS by ActionAid a framework that sets out key accountability requirements guidelines and processes 92 See also editAccountability partner Person who helps another to keep a commitment Accountability software Type of surveillance software Accountability for reasonableness Ethical framework for decision making Campaign finance reform in the United States United States efforts to regulate fundraising for democratic election campaigns Committee on Standards in Public Life UK ethical standards advisory body Euthenics Study of improving living conditions to increase well being Exit Voice and Loyalty Book on economic and political theory Exit Voice and Loyalty Model Framework for modelling political and economic behavior Freedom of information laws by country Good governance Performing public services competently for the benefit of all citizens Government Accountability Office US federal government agency Moral responsibility Concept in ethics One World Trust Global trust Open government Practice of sharing state documents and proceedings publicly and reusably Right to be forgotten Legal concept Special district United States Independent special purpose governmental units other than school districts Supreme audit institution Independent governmental audit agencies Transparency International International non governmental organization Worldwide Governance Indicators six key dimensions of governance researched by the World BankPages displaying wikidata descriptions as a fallback World Bank s Inspection PanelFootnotes edit Dykstra Clarence A February 1938 The Quest for Responsibility American Political Science Review 33 1 1 25 doi 10 2307 1949761 JSTOR 1949761 S2CID 143587418 Williams Reyes 2006 Leadership accountability in a globalizing world London Palgraave Macmillan Mulgan Richard 2000 Accountability An Ever Expanding Concept Public Administration 78 3 555 573 doi 10 1111 1467 9299 00218 Sinclair Amanda 1995 The Chameleon of Accountability Forms and Discourses Accounting Organizations and Society 20 2 3 219 237 doi 10 1016 0361 3682 93 E0003 Y Schedler Andreas 1999 Conceptualizing Accountability In Andreas Schedler Larry Diamond Marc F Plattner eds The Self Restraining State Power and Accountability in New Democracies London Lynne Rienner Publishers pp 13 28 ISBN 978 1 55587 773 6 David Rodreck 2017 Contribution of records management to audit opinions and accountability in government South Africa Journal of Information Management 19 1 AOSIS doi 10 4102 sajim v19i1 771 ISSN 1560 683X S2CID 168907338 Oxford English Dictionary 2nd ed page needed Dubnick Melvin 1998 Clarifying Accountability An Ethical Theory Framework In Charles Sampford Noel Preston C A Bois eds Public Sector Ethics Finding And Implementing Values Leichhardt NSW Australia The Federation Press Routledge pp 68 81 Seidman Gary I Winter 2005 The Origins of Accountability Everything I Know About the Sovereign s Immunity I Learned from King Henry III St Louis University Law Journal 49 2 393 480 Ezzamel Mahmoud December 1997 Accounting Control and Accountability Preliminary Evidence from Ancient Egypt Critical Perspectives on Accounting 8 6 563 601 doi 10 1006 cpac 1997 0123 Walzer Michael 1994 The Legal Codes of Ancient Israel In Ian Shapiro ed the Rule of Law NY New York University Press pp 101 119 Urch Edwin J July 1929 The Law Code of Hammurabi American Bar Association Journal 15 7 437 441 Roberts Jennifer T 1982 Accountability in Athenian Government Madison WI University of Wisconsin Press ISBN 9780299086800 Plescia Joseph January 2001 Judicial Accountability and Immunity in Roman Law American Journal of Legal History 45 1 51 70 doi 10 2307 3185349 JSTOR 3185349 a b Fearon James 1999 Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance Cambridge MA Cambridge University Press a b c d e f g h i j k Przeworski Adam Stokes Susan Carol Manin Bernard 2003 Democracy accountability and representation Cambridge University Press ISBN 9780521641531 OCLC 58400209 a b Stimson James A MacKuen Michael B Erikson Robert S Dynamic Representation American Political Science Review 98 3 543 565 Arnold R Douglas 1990 The logic of congressional action Yale University Press ISBN 0300056591 OCLC 472546186 a b Martin Lucy Raffler Pia 4 August 2019 Fault Lines The Effects of Bureaucratic Power on Electoral Accountability PDF American Journal of Political Science Archived PDF from the original on 6 December 2019 Retrieved 6 December 2019 a b c Grossman Guy Michelitch Kristin Grace Prato Carlo 2 March 2022 The Effect of Sustained Transparency on Electoral Accountability Center for Open Science doi 10 31219 osf io qwcek a b Sances Michael W January 2016 The Distributional Impact of Greater Responsiveness Evidence from New York Towns The Journal of Politics 78 1 105 119 doi 10 1086 683026 ISSN 0022 3816 S2CID 155437616 Besley Timothy J Kudamatsu Masayuki 1 May 2007 Making Autocracy Work SSRN 1127017 a b c Simpser Alberto 2013 Why governments and parties manipulate elections theory practice and implications Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 1 107 30688 2 OCLC 826857655 Long James Dunway 2014 Voting Fraud and Violence Political Accountability in African Elections Thesis University of California San Diego Schedler Andreas 2002 The Menu of Manipulation Journal of Democracy 13 2 36 50 doi 10 1353 jod 2002 0031 ISSN 1086 3214 S2CID 154830665 a b Callen Michael Long James D 2015 Institutional Corruption and Election Fraud Evidence from a Field Experiment in Afghanistan PDF American Economic Review 105 1 354 381 doi 10 1257 aer 20120427 ISSN 0002 8282 S2CID 7016902 a b Ichino Nahomi Schundeln Matthias 2012 Deterring or Displacing Electoral Irregularities Spillover Effects of Observers in a Randomized Field Experiment in Ghana The Journal of Politics 74 1 292 307 doi 10 1017 S0022381611001368 ISSN 0022 3816 S2CID 10426326 a b Beaulieu Emily Hyde Susan D 2009 In the Shadow of Democracy Promotion Strategic Manipulation International Observers and Election Boycotts Comparative Political Studies 42 3 392 415 doi 10 1177 0010414008325571 ISSN 0010 4140 S2CID 155078768 Hafner Burton Emilie Marie Hyde Susan D Jablonski Ryan S 6 September 2012 When Do Governments Resort to Election Violence British Journal of Political Science Rochester N Y SSRN 1667063 McKie Kristin 2019 Presidential Term Limit Contravention Abolish Extend Fail or Respect Comparative Political Studies 52 10 1500 1534 doi 10 1177 0010414019830737 ISSN 0010 4140 S2CID 159155380 a b c Batley Richard Mcloughlin Claire October 2015 The Politics of Public Services A Service Characteristics Approach World Development 74 275 285 doi 10 1016 j worlddev 2015 05 018 a b c Martin Lucy Raffler Pia J 7 June 2020 Fault Lines The Effects of Bureaucratic Power on Electoral Accountability American Journal of Political Science 65 1 Wiley 210 224 doi 10 1111 ajps 12530 ISSN 0092 5853 S2CID 209526364 a b Butler Daniel M 22 August 2011 Can Learning Constituency Opinion Affect How Legislators Vote Results from a Field Experiment Quarterly Journal of Political Science 6 1 55 83 doi 10 1561 100 00011019 S2CID 155004601 a b Beath Andrew Christia Fotini Enikolopov Ruben 2017 Direct democracy and resource allocation Experimental evidence from Afghanistan PDF Journal of Development Economics 124 Elsevier BV 199 213 doi 10 1016 j jdeveco 2016 10 001 hdl 1721 1 127650 ISSN 0304 3878 Rehfeld Andrew May 2009 Representation Rethought On Trustees Delegates and Gyroscopes in the Study of Political Representation and Democracy American Political Science Review 103 2 214 230 doi 10 1017 S0003055409090261 ISSN 0003 0554 S2CID 53957756 Fox Justin Shotts Kenneth W October 2009 Delegates or Trustees A Theory of Political Accountability The Journal of Politics 71 4 1225 1237 doi 10 1017 S0022381609990260 ISSN 0022 3816 S2CID 9879793 a b c d Min Brian Golden Miriam February 2014 Electoral cycles in electricity losses in India Energy Policy 65 619 625 Bibcode 2014EnPol 65 619M doi 10 1016 j enpol 2013 09 060 a b c Harding Robin October 2015 Attribution And Accountability Voting for roads in Ghana World Politics 67 4 656 689 doi 10 1017 S0043887115000209 ISSN 0043 8871 S2CID 20470554 a b Miller Michael K October 2015 Electoral Authoritarianism and Human Development Comparative Political Studies 48 12 1526 1562 doi 10 1177 0010414015582051 ISSN 0010 4140 S2CID 154285722 a b Miller Michael K May 2015 Elections Information and Policy Responsiveness in Autocratic Regimes Comparative Political Studies 48 6 691 727 doi 10 1177 0010414014555443 ISSN 0010 4140 S2CID 154879177 a b Pierskalla Jan H Sacks Audrey October 2020 Personnel Politics Elections Clientelistic Competition and Teacher Hiring in Indonesia British Journal of Political Science 50 4 1283 1305 doi 10 1017 S0007123418000601 ISSN 0007 1234 S2CID 149452970 Barro Robert J March 1973 The control of politicians An economic model Public Choice 14 14 1 19 42 doi 10 1007 bf01718440 ISSN 0048 5829 S2CID 154999534 Besley Timothy J Burgess Robin 2002 The Political Economy of Government Responsiveness Theory and Evidence from India PDF SSRN Working Paper Series doi 10 2139 ssrn 319012 ISSN 1556 5068 S2CID 8657561 Ferejohn John 1986 Incumbent performance and electoral control Public Choice 50 1 3 5 25 doi 10 1007 bf00124924 ISSN 0048 5829 S2CID 153577661 Manin Bernard Przeworski Adam Stokes Susan C 13 September 1999 Elections and Representation Democracy Accountability and Representation Cambridge University Press pp 29 54 doi 10 1017 cbo9781139175104 002 ISBN 978 0 521 64616 1Schumpeter Joseph A 5 April 2010 Capitalism Socialism and Democracy doi 10 4324 9780203857090 ISBN 9780203857090 a b Madestam Andreas Shoag Daniel Veuger Stan Yanagizawa Drott David 30 September 2013 Do Political Protests Matter Evidence from the Tea Party Movement PDF The Quarterly Journal of Economics 128 4 1633 1685 doi 10 1093 qje qjt021 ISSN 0033 5533 a b Bratton Michael van de Walle Nicolas July 1992 Popular Protest and Political Reform in Africa Comparative Politics 24 4 419 doi 10 2307 422153 ISSN 0010 4159 JSTOR 422153 a b Anderson Sarah E Buntaine Mark T Liu Mengdi Zhang Bing 8 May 2019 Non Governmental Monitoring of Local Governments Increases Compliance with Central Mandates A National Scale Field Experiment in China American Journal of Political Science 63 3 626 643 doi 10 1111 ajps 12428 ISSN 0092 5853 S2CID 164557135 a b Baldwin Kate Holzinger Katharina 16 June 2019 Traditional Political Institutions and Democracy Reassessing Their Compatibility and Accountability Comparative Political Studies 52 12 1747 1774 doi 10 1177 0010414019852686 ISSN 0010 4140 S2CID 197832991 a b c Tsai Lily 2007 Solidary Groups Informal Accountability and Local Public Goods Provision in Rural China The American Political Science Review 101 2 355 372 doi 10 1017 S0003055407070153 S2CID 146348780 a b c Baldwin Kate 2015 The Paradox of Traditional Chiefs in Democratic Africa Cambridge University Press Besley Timothy J 2007 Making autocracy work Centre for Economic Policy Research OCLC 255778387 Baldwin Kate 2019 Elected MPs Traditional Chiefs and Local Public Goods Evidence on the Role of Leaders in Co Production From Rural Zambia Comparative Political Studies 52 12 1925 1956 doi 10 1177 0010414018774372 ISSN 0010 4140 S2CID 158062055 Bates Robert 1981 Markets and States in Tropical Africa The Political Basis of Agricultural Policies University of California Press a b Besley Timothy J Kudamatsu Masayuki May 2007 Making Autocracy Work PDF LSE STICERD Research Paper No DEDPS48 Bueno de Mesquita Bruce Morrow James D Siverson Randolph M Smith Alastair 17 September 2002 Political Institutions Policy Choice and the Survival of Leaders British Journal of Political Science 32 4 559 590 doi 10 1017 s0007123402000236 ISSN 0007 1234 S2CID 40514840 Boix Carles Posner Daniel N October 1998 Social Capital Explaining Its Origins and Effects on Government Performance British Journal of Political Science 28 4 686 693 doi 10 1017 s0007123498000313 ISSN 0007 1234 S2CID 4503343 EDWARDS BOB FOLEY MICHAEL W September 1998 Civil Society and Social Capital Beyond Putnam American Behavioral Scientist 42 1 124 139 doi 10 1177 0002764298042001010 ISSN 0002 7642 S2CID 144681913 Ehrenberg John 1999 Civil Society The critical History of an Idea New York University Press Putnam Robert D Leonardi Robert Nonetti Raffaella Y 27 May 1994 Making Democracy Work Princeton University Press doi 10 2307 j ctt7s8r7 ISBN 978 1 4008 2074 0 S2CID 155009926 a b Ofosu George Kwaku 2 August 2019 Do Fairer Elections Increase the Responsiveness of Politicians PDF American Political Science Review 113 4 963 979 doi 10 1017 s0003055419000479 ISSN 0003 0554 S2CID 201385531 a b Carreri Maria 2018 Can Good Politicians Compensate for Bad Institutions Evidence from an Original Survey of Italian Mayors SSRN Working Paper Series doi 10 2139 ssrn 3239492 ISSN 1556 5068 S2CID 160023663 a b c Berry Christopher R Howell William G August 2007 Accountability and Local Elections Rethinking Retrospective Voting The Journal of Politics 69 3 844 858 doi 10 1111 j 1468 2508 2007 00579 x ISSN 0022 3816 S2CID 42972242 Grossman Guy Michelitch Kristin 1 February 2018 Information Dissemination Competitive Pressure and Politician Performance between Elections A Field Experiment in Uganda American Political Science Review 112 2 280 301 doi 10 1017 s0003055417000648 ISSN 0003 0554 S2CID 15659219 Dunning Thad Grossman Guy Humphreys Macartan Hyde Susan D McIntosh Craig Nellis Gareth eds 4 July 2019 Information Accountability and Cumulative Learning doi 10 1017 9781108381390 ISBN 9781108381390 S2CID 243627947 a b c Highton Benjamin May 2008 Job Approval and Senate Election Outcomes in the United States Legislative Studies Quarterly 33 2 245 261 doi 10 3162 036298008784311019 ISSN 0362 9805 a b Brown Adam R Jacobson Gary C December 2008 Party Performance and Strategic Politicians The Dynamics of Elections for Senator and Governor in 2006 State Politics amp Policy Quarterly 8 4 384 409 doi 10 1177 153244000800800403 ISSN 1532 4400 S2CID 154373150 Erikson Robert S Bafumi Joseph Wilson Bret October 2001 Was the 2000 Presidential Election Predictable Political Science amp Politics 34 4 815 819 doi 10 1017 S1049096501000750 ISSN 1049 0965 S2CID 153487954 a b c De Vries Catherine E Solaz Hector 11 May 2017 The Electoral Consequences of Corruption Annual Review of Political Science 20 1 391 408 doi 10 1146 annurev polisci 052715 111917 ISSN 1094 2939 Ferraz Claudio Finan Frederico 1 May 2008 Exposing Corrupt Politicians The Effects of Brazil s Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 2 703 745 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 222 8752 doi 10 1162 qjec 2008 123 2 703 ISSN 0033 5533 S2CID 8148400 Helping Countries Combat Corruption The Role of the World Bank World Bank 1997 a b Chong Alberto De La O Ana L Karlan Dean Wantchekon Leonard 1 January 2015 Does Corruption Information Inspire the Fight or Quash the Hope A Field Experiment in Mexico on Voter Turnout Choice and Party Identification The Journal of Politics 77 1 55 71 doi 10 1086 678766 ISSN 0022 3816 S2CID 8379010 a b c Klasnja Marko Little Andrew T Tucker Joshua A July 2018 Political Corruption Traps Political Science Research and Methods 6 3 413 428 doi 10 1017 psrm 2016 45 ISSN 2049 8470 S2CID 155201513 a b c d Gandhi Jennifer Ruiz Rufino Ruben 2015 Routledge handbook of comparative political institutions Milton Park Abingdon Oxon Routledge ISBN 978 1 315 73137 7 OCLC 907374446 Mcmillan John Zoido Pablo December 2004 How to Subvert Democracy Montesinos in Peru PDF Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 4 69 92 doi 10 1257 0895330042632690 ISSN 0895 3309 S2CID 219372153 Kiewiet D Roderick McCubbins Mathew D 18 June 1991 The Logic of Delegation University of Chicago Press ISBN 978 0 226 43531 2 Brierley Sarah 2020 Unprincipled Principals Co opted Bureaucrats and Corruption in Ghana American Journal of Political Science 64 2 209 222 doi 10 1111 ajps 12495 ISSN 1540 5907 S2CID 202313542 Fisman Raymond Golden Miriam A 2017 Corruption What Everyone Needs to Know Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 046397 7 Jiang Junyan Shao Zijie Zhang Zhiyuan n d The Price of Probity Anticorruption and Adverse Selection in the Chinese Bureaucracy British Journal of Political Science 52 41 64 doi 10 1017 S0007123420000393 ISSN 0007 1234 S2CID 234411216 Fisman Raymond Golden Miriam 26 May 2017 How to fight corruption Science 356 6340 803 804 Bibcode 2017Sci 356 803F doi 10 1126 science aan0815 ISSN 0036 8075 PMID 28546172 S2CID 206658780 Walker Samuel E 2005 The New World of Police Accountability 1st ed Thousand Oaks CA SAGE Publications Inc ISBN 978 1 412 90943 3 OCLC 56334321 De Angelis amp Wold J amp B 2016 Perceived accountability and public attitudes toward local police Criminal Justice Studies 29 3 232 252 doi 10 1080 1478601X 2016 1158177 S2CID 148242583 Romm Norma R A 2001 Accountability in Social Research New York Klower Academic ISBN 978 0 306 46564 2 Truman Carole 2010 Review of New Racism Revisiting Researcher Accountabilities Sociological Research Online Retrieved 27 August 2012 Thompson Dennis F 2005 The Problem of Many Hands Restoring Responsibility Ethics in Government Business and Healthcare Cambridge University Press pp 33 49 ISBN 978 0 521 54722 2 Thompson Dennis F 9 March 2014 Responsibility for Failures of Government The Problem of Many Hands The American Review of Public Administration 44 3 SAGE Publications 259 273 doi 10 1177 0275074014524013 ISSN 0275 0740 S2CID 154304430 Harriman Ed 28 September 2007 Blackwater poisons the well London Guardian Archived from the original on 12 April 2008 Retrieved 26 August 2009 Glossary of Important Assessment and Measurement Terms National Council on Measurement in Education Archived from the original on 22 July 2017 Retrieved 6 December 2019 Greenberg Daniel 1992 Ethics is a Course Taught By Life Experience Education in America A View from Sudbury Valley The Sudbury Valley School pp 60 62 ISBN 978 1 888947 07 6 Greenberg Daniel 1987 Back to Basics Archived from the original on 11 May 2011 Feldman Jay 2001 The Moral Behavior of Children and Adolescents at a Democratic School Law and Order Foundations of Discipline The Crisis in American Education An Analysis and a Proposal The Sudbury Valley School 1970 pp 49 55 ISBN 978 1 888947 05 2 Greenberg Daniel 1992 Democracy Must be Experienced to be Learned Education in America A View from Sudbury Valley The Sudbury Valley School pp 103 107 ISBN 978 1 888947 07 6 Reiss Steven 2010 Whatever Happened to Personal Responsibility Psychology Today Brunetti Aymo Weder Beatrice 2003 A free press is bad news for corruption Journal of Public Economics 87 7 8 1801 1824 doi 10 1016 s0047 2727 01 00186 4 Adsera Alicia Boix Carles Payne Mark 2000 Are You Being Served Political Accountability and Quality of Government PDF Working Paper no 438 Inter American Development Bank Research Department retrieved 17 August 2014Adsera Alicia Boix Carles Payne Mark 2003 Are You Being Served Political Accountability and Quality of Government PDF Journal of Law Economics amp Organization 19 2 445 490 doi 10 1093 jleo 19 2 445 hdl 10419 87999 retrieved 31 August 2014 a b Snyder James M Stromberg David 2010 Press Coverage and Political Accountability Journal of Political Economy 118 2 355 408 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 210 8371 doi 10 1086 652903 S2CID 154635874 a b Besley Timothy Burgess Robin 2001 Political agency government responsiveness and the role of the media European Economic Review 45 4 6 629 640 doi 10 1016 S0014 2921 01 00133 7 Barbera Pablo Casas Andreu Nagler Jonathan Egan Patrick Bonneau Richard Jost John Tucker Joshua 2019 Who Leads Who Follows Measuring Issue Attention and Agenda Setting by Legislators and the Mass Public Using Social Media Data American Political Science Review 113 4 883 901 doi 10 1017 S0003055419000352 PMC 7672368 PMID 33303996 Ferraz Claudio Finan Frederico 2008 Exposing Corrupt Politicians The Effect of Brazil s Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 2 703 745 doi 10 1162 qjec 2008 123 2 703 S2CID 8148400 Besley Timothy Prat Andrea 2006 Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand Media Capture and Government Accountability PDF American Economic Review 96 3 720 736 doi 10 1257 aer 96 3 720 S2CID 13849989 Munger Kevin Bonneau Richard Nagler Jonathan Tucker Joshua 2019 Elites Tweet to Get Feet Off the Streets Measuring Regime Social Media Strategies During Protest Political Science Research and Methods 7 4 815 834 doi 10 1017 psrm 2018 3King Gary Pan Jennifer Roberts Margaret 2013 How Censorship in China Allows Government Criticism but Silences Collective Expression American Political Science Review 107 2 326 343 doi 10 1017 S0003055413000014 S2CID 53577293King Gary Pan Jennifer Roberts Margaret 2013 How the Chinese Government Fabricates Social Media Posts for Strategic Distraction Not Engaged Argument American Political Science Review 111 3 484 501 doi 10 1017 S0003055417000144 Boas Taylor Hidalgo F Daniel 2011 Controlling the Airwaves Incumbency Advantage and Community Radio in Brazil American Journal of Political Science 55 4 869 885 doi 10 1111 j 1540 5907 2011 00532 x Starr Paul 2012 An Unexpected Crisis The News Media in Post industrial Democracies PDF International Journal of Press Politics 17 2 234 242 doi 10 1177 1940161211434422 S2CID 146729965 retrieved 31 August 2014 Since 2000 the newspaper industry alone has lost an estimated 1 6 billion in annual reporting and editing capacity or roughly 30 per cent but the new non profit money coming into journalism has made up less than one tenth that amount About the Charter Archived from the original on 17 May 2013 Retrieved 6 December 2019 Website AccountAbility Setting the Standard for Corporate Responsibility and Sustainable Development Standards Archived from the original on 8 September 2013 Retrieved 6 December 2019 Webpage HAP International RSS feed Archived from the original on 3 July 2013 Retrieved 28 July 2013 ActionAid 2005 ALPS Accountability Learning and Planning SystemFurther reading editBovens Mark 1998 The Quest for Responsibility Accountability and Citizenship in Complex Organisations Cambridge University Press Bovens Mark 2010 Two concepts of accountability accountability as a virtue and as a mechanism West European Politics 33 5 946 967 doi 10 1080 01402382 2010 486119 hdl 1874 204069 S2CID 154886643 Harwood Sterling 1994 Accountability In Roth John K ed Ethics Ready Reference Salem Press Luban David Strudler Alan Wasserman David 1992 Moral Responsibility in the Age of Bureaucracy Michigan Law Review 90 8 2348 2392 doi 10 2307 1289575 JSTOR 1289575 Mastop Rosja 2010 Characterising Responsibility in Organisational Structures The Problem of Many Hands In Governatori G Sartor G eds Deontic Logic in Computer Science Berlin Springer Verlag pp 274 287 ISBN 978 3 540 70524 6 Painter Morland Mollie Deslandes Ghislain 2 April 2015 Authentic leading as relational accountability Facing up to the conflicting expectations of media leaders PDF Leadership 13 4 SAGE Publications 424 444 doi 10 1177 1742715015578307 ISSN 1742 7150 S2CID 2430595 Romm Norma R A 31 May 2001 Accountability in Social Research Springer Science amp Business Media ISBN 978 0 306 46564 2 Thompson Dennis F 2005 The Responsibility of Advisers Restoring Responsibility Ethics in Government Business and Healthcare New York Cambridge University Press pp 33 49 ISBN 978 0 521 54722 2 Thompson Dennis F 2014 Responsibility for Failures of Government The Problem of Many Hands American Review of Public Administration 44 3 259 273 doi 10 1177 0275074014524013 S2CID 154304430 Williams Christopher 2006 Leadership accountability in a globalizing world London Palgrave Macmillan External links edit nbsp Look up accountability in Wiktionary the free dictionary nbsp Wikiquote has quotations related to Accountability nbsp Media related to Accountability at Wikimedia Commons Citizens Circle for Accountability Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Accountability amp oldid 1223220976, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.