fbpx
Wikipedia

Inflation targeting

In macroeconomics, inflation targeting is a monetary policy where a central bank follows an explicit target for the inflation rate for the medium-term and announces this inflation target to the public. The assumption is that the best that monetary policy can do to support long-term growth of the economy is to maintain price stability, and price stability is achieved by controlling inflation. The central bank uses interest rates as its main short-term monetary instrument.[1][2][3]

An inflation-targeting central bank will raise or lower interest rates based on above-target or below-target inflation, respectively. The conventional wisdom is that raising interest rates usually cools the economy to rein in inflation; lowering interest rates usually accelerates the economy, thereby boosting inflation. The first three countries to implement fully-fledged inflation targeting were New Zealand, Canada and the United Kingdom in the early 1990s, although Germany had adopted many elements of inflation targeting earlier.[4][5]

History edit

Early proposals of monetary systems targeting the price level or the inflation rate, rather than the exchange rate, followed the general crisis of the gold standard after World War I. Irving Fisher proposed a "compensated dollar" system in which the gold content in paper money would vary with the price of goods in terms of gold, so that the price level in terms of paper money would stay fixed. Fisher's proposal was a first attempt to target prices while retaining the automatic functioning of the gold standard. In his Tract on Monetary Reform (1923), John Maynard Keynes advocated what we would now call an inflation targeting scheme. In the context of sudden inflations and deflations in the international economy right after World War I, Keynes recommended a policy of exchange-rate flexibility, appreciating the currency as a response to international inflation and depreciating it when there are international deflationary forces, so that internal prices remained more or less stable. Interest in inflation targeting waned during the Bretton Woods era (1944–1971), as they were inconsistent with the exchange rate pegs that prevailed during three decades after World War II.

New Zealand, Canada, United Kingdom edit

Inflation targeting was pioneered in New Zealand in 1990.[6] Canada was the second country to formally adopt inflation targeting in February 1991.[4][5]

The United Kingdom adopted inflation targeting in October 1992 after exiting the European Exchange Rate Mechanism.[4][7] The Bank of England's Monetary Policy Committee was given sole responsibility in 1998 for setting interest rates to meet the Government's Retail Prices Index (RPI) inflation target of 2.5%.[8] The target changed to 2% in December 2003 when the Consumer Price Index (CPI) replaced the Retail Prices Index as the UK Treasury's inflation index.[9] If inflation overshoots or undershoots the target by more than 1%, the Governor of the Bank of England is required to write a letter to the Chancellor of the Exchequer explaining why, and how he will remedy the situation.[10][11][12] The success of inflation targeting in the United Kingdom has been attributed to the Bank's focus on transparency.[7] The Bank of England has been a leader in producing innovative ways of communicating information to the public, especially through its Inflation Report, which have been emulated by many other central banks.[4]

Inflation targeting then spread to other advanced economies in the 1990s and began to spread to emerging markets beginning in the 2000s.

European Central Bank edit

Although the ECB does not consider itself to be an inflation-targeting central bank,[13] after the inception of the euro in January 1999, the objective of the European Central Bank (ECB) has been to maintain price stability within the Eurozone.[14] The Governing Council of the ECB in October 1998[15] defined price stability as inflation of under 2%, "a year-on-year increase in the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) for the euro area of below 2%" and added that price stability "was to be maintained over the medium term".[16] The Governing Council confirmed this definition in May 2003 following a thorough evaluation of the ECB's monetary policy strategy. On that occasion, the Governing Council clarified that "in the pursuit of price stability, it aims to maintain inflation rates below, but close to, 2% over the medium term".[15] Since then, the numerical target of 2% has become common for major developed economies, including the United States (since January 2012) and Japan (since January 2013).[17]

In 2021, the ECB tweaked its inflation target to a symmetrical 2%.[18]

Emerging markets edit

In 2000, Frederic S. Mishkin concluded that "although inflation targeting is not a panacea and may not be appropriate for many emerging market countries, it can be a highly useful monetary policy strategy in a number of them".[19]

Armenia edit

The Central Bank of Armenia (CBA) announced in 2006 that it will implement an inflation targeting strategy. The process of full transition to inflation targeting was supposed to end in 2008. Operational, macroeconomic and institutional preconditions for inflation targeting should have been met to ensure a full transition. CBA believes that it has managed to meet all the preconditions successfully and should concentrate on building a public trust in the new monetary policy regime. A specific model has been developed to estimate CBA's reaction function and the results showed that the inertia of inflation rate and interest rate are most vital in the reaction function. This can be an evidence that the announcement of the strategy is a trustworthy commitment. Obviously, there are people who claim that inflation targeting is too restrictive for dealing with positive supply shocks. On the other hand, the IMF claims that inflation targeting strategy is good for developing economies, however it requires a lot of information for forecasting.[20]

The Central Bank continued to pursue a policy of tightening monetary conditions during the reporting period, increasing the policy interest rate by a total of 2.75 percentage points. At the same time, about half of the tightening, 1.25 percentage points, was carried out in 2022 in March, reacting to the high inflation situation formed in the case of unprecedented uncertainties.[21]

Being constantly hit by external shocks to the national economy over the past three years, Armenia is still on the path of recovery thanks to economic management efforts. According to the 3-year Stand-By Arrangement, which came to its end on May 16, 2022, important structural and institutional reforms have been implemented. Those include improvement of tax compliance, budget process refinement, strengthening the stability of financial sector and most importantly fostering the inflation targeting framework.[22]

Chile edit

In Chile, a 20% inflation rate pushed the Central Bank of Chile to announce at the end of 1990 an inflation objective for the annual inflation rate for the year ending in December 1991.[19] However, Chile was not regarded as a fully-fledged inflation targeter until October 1999.[5][23] According to Pablo García Silva, member of the board of the Central Bank of Chile, this has allowed to attenuate inflation. García Silva exemplifies this with the limited inflation seen in Chile during the 2002 Brazilian general election and the Great Recession of 2008–2009.[23]

Czech Republic edit

The Czech National Bank (CNB) is an example of an inflation targeting central bank in a small open economy with a recent history of economic transition and real convergence to its Western European peers. Since 2010 the CNB uses 2 percent with a +/- 1pp range around it as the inflation target.[24] The CNB places a lot of emphasis on transparency and communication; indeed, a recent study of more than 100 central banks found the CNB to be among the four most transparent ones.[25]

In 2012, inflation was expected to fall well below the target, leading the CNB to gradually reduce the level of its basic monetary policy instrument, the 2-week repo rate, until the zero lower bound (actually 0.05 percent) was reached in late 2012. In light of the threat of a further fall in inflation and possibly even of a protracted period of deflation, on 7 November 2013 the CNB declared an immediate commitment to weaken the exchange rate to the level of 27 Czech korunas per 1 euro (day-on-day weakening by about 5 percent) and to keep the exchange rate from getting stronger than this value until at least the end of 2014 (later on this was changed to the second half of 2016). The CNB thus decided to use the exchange rate as a supplementary tool to make sure that inflation returns to the 2 percent target level. Such a use of the exchange rate as tool within the regime of inflation targeting should not be confused with a fixed exchange-rate system or with a currency war.[26][27][28]

United States edit

In a historic shift on 25 January 2012, U.S. Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke set a 2% target inflation rate, bringing the Fed in line with many of the world's other major central banks.[29] Until then, the Fed's policy committee, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), did not have an explicit inflation target but regularly announced a desired target range for inflation (usually between 1.7% and 2%) measured by the personal consumption expenditures price index.

Prior to adoption of the target, some people argued that an inflation target would give the Fed too little flexibility to stabilise growth and/or employment in the event of an external economic shock. Another criticism was that an explicit target might turn central bankers into what Mervyn King, former Governor of the Bank of England, had in 1997 colorfully termed "inflation nutters"[30]—that is, central bankers who concentrate on the inflation target to the detriment of stable growth, employment, and/or exchange rates. King went on to help design the Bank's inflation targeting policy,[31] and asserts that the buffoonery has not actually happened, as did Chairman of the U.S. Federal Reserve Ben Bernanke, who stated in 2003 that all inflation targeting at the time was of a flexible variety, in theory and practice.[32]

Former Chairman Alan Greenspan, as well as other former FOMC members such as Alan Blinder, typically agreed with the benefits of inflation targeting, but were reluctant to accept the loss of freedom involved; Bernanke, however, was a well-known advocate.[33]

In August 2020, the FOMC released a revised Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy.[34] The review announced the FED would seek to achieve inflation that 'averages' 2% over time. In practice this means that following periods when inflation has been running persistently below 2 percent, appropriate monetary policy will likely aim to achieve inflation moderately above 2 percent for some time.[35] This way, the fed hopes to better anchor longer-term inflation expectations, which they say would foster price stability and moderate long-term interest rates and enhance the Committee's ability to promote maximum employment in the face of significant economic disturbances.

Theoretical questions edit

New classical macroeconomics and rational expectations hypothesis can explain how and why inflation targeting works. Expectations of firms (or the subjective probability distribution of outcomes) will be around the prediction of the theory itself (the objective probability distribution of those outcomes) for the same information set.[36] So, rational agents expect the most probable outcome to emerge. However, there is limited success at specifying the relevant model, and the full and perfect knowledge of a given macroeconomic system can be regarded as a comfortable presumption at best. Knowledge of the relevant model is not feasible, even if high-level econometrical techniques were accessible or adequate identification of the relevant explanatory variables were performed. So, estimation bias depends on the quantity and quality of information to which the modeller has access. In other words, estimations are asymptotically unbiased with respect to the exploited information.

Meanwhile, consistency can be interpreted similarly. On the basis of asymptotical unbiasedness, a moderated version of the rational expectations hypothesis can be suggested in which familiarity with the theoretical parameters is not a requirement for the relevant model. An agent with access to sufficiently vast, quality information and high-level methodological skills could specify its own quasi-relevant model describing a specific macroeconomic system. By increasing the amount of information processed, this agent could further reduce its bias. If this agent were also focal, such as a central bank, then other agents would likely accept the proposed model and adjust their expectations accordingly. In this way, individual expectations become unbiased as much as possible, albeit against a background of considerable passivity. According to some researches, this is the theoretical background of the functionality of inflation targeting regimes.[37]

Empirical issues edit

Target band size edit

While most inflation targeting countries set their target band at 2 percentage points, the band sizes are wide-ranging across countries and inflation targeters frequently update their target bands.[38]

Track record edit

Inflation targeting countries' track records in maintaining inflation within the central banks' target bands differ substantially and financial markets differentiate inflation targeters by behaviors.[39][38]

Debate edit

There is some empirical evidence that inflation targeting does what its advocates claim, that is, making the outcomes, if not the process, of monetary policy more transparent.[40][41] A 2021 study in the American Political Science Review found that independent central banks with rigid inflation targeting policies produce worse outcomes in banking crises than independent central banks whose policy mandate does not rigidly prioritize inflation.[42]

Benefits edit

Inflation targeting allows monetary policy to "focus on domestic considerations and to respond to shocks to the domestic economy", which is not possible under a fixed exchange-rate system. Also, investor uncertainty is reduced and therefore investors may more easily factor in likely interest rate changes into their investment decisions. Inflation expectations that are better anchored "allow monetary authorities to cut policy interest rates countercyclically".[43]

Transparency is another key benefit of inflation targeting. Central banks in developed countries that have successfully implemented inflation targeting tend to "maintain regular channels of communication with the public". For example, the Bank of England pioneered the "Inflation Report" in 1993, which outlines the bank's "views about the past and future performance of inflation and monetary policy".[44] Although it was not an inflation-targeting country until January 2012, up until then, the United States' "Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy" enumerated the benefits of clear communication—it "facilitates well-informed decisionmaking by households and businesses, reduces economic and financial uncertainty, increases the effectiveness of monetary policy, and enhances transparency and accountability, which are essential in a democratic society".[45]

An explicit numerical inflation target increases a central bank's accountability, and thus it is less likely that the central bank falls prey to the time-inconsistency trap. This accountability is especially significant because even countries with weak institutions can build public support for an independent central bank. Institutional commitment can also insulate the bank from political pressure to undertake an overly expansionary monetary policy.[19]

An econometric analysis found that although inflation targeting results in higher economic growth, it does not necessarily guarantee stability based on their study of 36 emerging economies from 1979 to 2009.[46]

Shortcomings edit

Supporters of a nominal income target criticize the propensity of inflation targeting to neglect output shocks by focusing solely on the price level. Adherents of market monetarism, led by Scott Sumner, argue that in the United States, the Federal Reserve's mandate is to stabilize both output and the price level, and that consequently a nominal income target would better suit the Fed's mandate.[47] Australian economist John Quiggin, who also endorses nominal income targeting, stated that it "would maintain or enhance the transparency associated with a system based on stated targets, while restoring the balance missing from a monetary policy based solely on the goal of price stability".[48] Quiggin blamed the late-2000s recession on inflation targeting in an economic environment in which low inflation is a "drag on growth". In practice, many central banks conduct "flexible inflation targeting" where the central bank strives to keep inflation near the target except when such an effort would imply too much output volatility.[49][50]

Quiggin also criticized former Fed Chair Alan Greenspan and former European Central Bank President Jean-Claude Trichet for "ignor[ing] or even applaud[ing] the unsustainable bubbles in speculative real estate that produced the crisis, and to react[ing] too slowly as the evidence emerged".[48]

In a 2012 op-ed, University of Nottingham economist Mohammed Farhaan Iqbal suggested that inflation targeting "evidently passed away in September 2008", referencing the 2007–2012 global financial crisis. Frankel suggested "that central banks that had been relying on [inflation targeting] had not paid enough attention to asset-price bubbles", and also criticized inflation targeting for "inappropriate responses to supply shocks and terms-of-trade shocks". In turn, Iqbal suggested that nominal income targeting or product-price targeting would succeed inflation targeting as the dominant monetary policy regime.[51] The debate continues and many observers expect that inflation targeting will continue to be the dominant monetary policy regime, perhaps after certain modifications.[52]

Empirically, it is not so obvious that inflation targeteers have better inflation control. Some economists argue that better institutions increase a country's chances of successfully targeting inflation.[53] As regards the impact of the 2007–2012 financial crisis, John Williams, a high-ranking Federal Reserve official, concludes that "when gauged by the behavior of inflation since the crisis, inflation targeting delivered on its promise".[54]

In an article written since the COVID-19 pandemic, critics have pointed out that the Bank of Canada’s inflation-targeting has had unintended consequences, with persistently low interest rates over the last 12 years fuelling an increase in home prices by encouraging borrowing; and contributing to wealth inequalities by supporting higher equity values.[55]

Choosing a positive, zero, or negative inflation target edit

Choosing a positive inflation target has at least two drawbacks.

  1. Over time, the compounded effect of small annual price increases will significantly reduce a currency's purchasing power. (For example, successfully hitting a target of +2% each year for 40 years would cause the price of a $100 basket of goods to rise to $220.80.) This drawback would be minimized or reversed by choosing a zero inflation target or a negative target.
  2. Vendors must expend resources more frequently to reprice their goods and services. This drawback would be minimized by choosing a zero inflation target.

However, policymakers feel the drawbacks are outweighed by the fact that a positive inflation target reduces the chance of an economy falling into a period of deflation.

Some economists argue that fear of deflation is unfounded, citing studies that show inflation is more likely than deflation to cause an economic contraction.[56][57] Andrew Atkeson and Patrick J. Kehoe wrote,

According to standard economic theory, deflation is the necessary consequence of optimal monetary policy. In 1969, Milton Friedman argued that under the optimal policy, the nominal interest rate should be zero and the price level should fall steadily at the real rate of interest. Since then, Friedman’s argument has been confirmed in a formal setting. (See, for example, V. V. Chari, Lawrence Christiano, and Patrick Kehoe 1996 and Harold Cole and Narayana Kocherlakota 1998.)[58]

Effectively, Friedman was arguing for a negative (moderately deflationary) inflation target.

Numerical target edit

The typical numerical target of 2% has come under debate since the period of rapid inflation experienced following the monetary expansion during the COVID-19 pandemic.

Mohamed El-Erian has suggested the Federal Reserve raise it inflation target to a (stable) 3% rate of inflation saying "There's nothing scientific about 2%".[59]

Variations edit

Contrast to the usual inflation rate targeting, Laurence M. Ball proposed targeting on long-run inflation, targeting which takes the exchange rate into account and monetary conditions index targeting.[60] In his proposal, the monetary conditions index is a weighted average of the interest rate and exchange rate. It will be easy to put many other things into this monetary conditions index.

In the "constrained discretion" framework, inflation targeting combines two contradicting monetary policies—a rule-based approach and a discretionary approach—as a precise numerical target is given for inflation in the medium term and a response to economic shocks in the short term. Some inflation targeters associate this with more economic stability.[2][61]

Countries edit

There were 27 countries regarded by the Bank of England's Centre for Central Banking Studies as fully fledged inflation targeters at the beginning of 2012.[5] Other lists count 26 or 28 countries as of 2010.[62][63] Since then, the United States and Japan have also adopted inflation targets although the Federal Reserve, like the European Central Bank,[13] does not consider itself to be an inflation-targeting central bank.

Country Central bank Year adopted inflation targeting Notes
New Zealand Reserve Bank of New Zealand 12/1989[5] The pioneer; see Section 8: Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act of 1989.
Canada Bank of Canada 02/1991[5]
United Kingdom Bank of England 10/1992[5] First in Europe, although Germany had adopted many elements of inflation targeting earlier.[4]
Sweden Sveriges Riksbank 01/1993[5] The inflation target regime was announced in January 1993 and applied as of 1995.[5] The Riksbank had practiced price-level targeting since abandonment of the gold standard in 1931.
Australia Reserve Bank of Australia 06/1993[5][64]
Israel Bank of Israel 06/1997[5] Informally since 1992. Fully fledged inflation targeting from June 1997.[5][65]
Czech Republic Czech National Bank 12/1997[5][66] First in Central and Eastern Europe.
Poland National Bank of Poland 1998[5]
Brazil Brazilian Central Bank 06/1999[5]
Chile Central Bank of Chile 09/1999[5] At the end of 1990, a 20% inflation rate pushed the Central Bank of Chile to announce an inflation objective for the annual inflation rate for the year ending in December 1991.[19]
Colombia Banco de la República 10/1999[5]
South Africa South African Reserve Bank 02/2000[5]
Thailand Bank of Thailand 05/2000[5]
Hungary Hungarian National Bank 06/2001[67]
Mexico Bank of Mexico 2001[5] Some sources say 1999.[68]
Norway Norges Bank 03/2001[5][69][70]
Iceland Central Bank of Iceland 03/2001[71]
Peru Central Reserve Bank of Peru 01/2002[5]
Philippines Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas 01/2002[5][72]
Guatemala Bank of Guatemala 01/2005[5]
Indonesia Bank Indonesia 07/2005[5]
Romania National Bank of Romania 08/2005[5]
Armenia, Republic of Central Bank of Armenia 01/2006[5]
Turkey Türkiye Cumhuriyet Merkez Bankası 01/2006[5]
Ghana Bank of Ghana 05/2007[5] Informally in 2002, formally from May 2007.[5]
Georgia National Bank of Georgia 01/2009[73]
Serbia, Republic of National Bank of Serbia 01/2009[5]
United States Federal Reserve 01/2012[74]
Japan Bank of Japan 01/2013[75]
Russian Federation Central Bank of Russia 01/2014[76]
Republic of Kazakhstan National Bank of Republic of Kazakhstan 08/2015[77]
Ukraine National Bank of Ukraine 08/2015[78] Official document about implementation of inflation targeting in Ukraine[79]
India Reserve Bank of India 08/2016[80] Decision taken after India had ~10% inflation rate for around 5 years.
Argentina Central Bank of Argentina 09/2016[81] Until September 2018, when the Central Bank changed its monetary policy to crawling peg.

In addition, South Korea (Bank of Korea) and Iceland (Central Bank of Iceland) and others.[5]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Coy, Peter (7 November 2005). . BusinessWeek. No. The New Fed. Archived from the original on 28 July 2011.
  2. ^ a b Jahan, Sarwat. "Inflation Targeting: Holding the Line". International Monetary Funds, Finance & Development. Retrieved 28 December 2014.
  3. ^ Fisher, Irving (1922). "Dollar Stabilization" . In Chisholm, Hugh (ed.). Encyclopædia Britannica (12th ed.). London & New York: The Encyclopædia Britannica Company.
  4. ^ a b c d e "Inflation Targeting Has Been A Successful Monetary Policy Strategy". NBER. Retrieved 31 October 2016.
  5. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r s t u v w x y z aa ab ac ad ae af (PDF). Bank of England – Centre for Central Banking Studies. 2012: 17, 18–44. Archived from the original (PDF) on 11 August 2017. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  6. ^ Andrew G. Haldane (1995). Targeting Inflation: A Conference of Central Banks on the Use of Inflation Targets Organised by the Bank of England, 9-10 March 1995. London: Bank of England. ISBN 9781857300734.
  7. ^ a b "Targeting Inflation: The United Kingdom in Retrospect" (PDF). IMF. Retrieved 31 October 2016.
  8. ^ . Bank of England. Archived from the original on 29 June 2007. Retrieved 20 September 2007.
  9. ^ "Remit of the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England and the New Inflation Target" (PDF). HM Treasury. 10 December 2003. (PDF) from the original on 26 September 2007. Retrieved 20 September 2007.
  10. ^ "Monetary Policy Framework". Bank of England. Retrieved 31 October 2016.
  11. ^ "CCBS Lecture Series - Inflation Targeting: The British Experience". Bank of England. January 1999. Retrieved 31 October 2016.
  12. ^ "Inflation targeting is 25 years old, but has it worked?". BBC. 11 March 2015. Retrieved 31 October 2016; "Why do we target 2pc inflation? (And does it matter if we keep missing it?)". The Telegraph. 16 June 2015. Retrieved 31 October 2016.
  13. ^ a b Governor Laurence H. Meyer (17 July 2001). "Inflation Targets and Inflation Targeting". The Federal Reserve Board. Retrieved 1 December 2016.
  14. ^ wikisource consolidation
  15. ^ a b THE EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK HISTORY, ROLE AND FUNCTIONS BY HANSPETER K. SCHELLER SECOND REVISED EDITION 2006, ISBN 92-899-0022-9 (print) ISBN 92-899-0027-X (online) page 81 at the pdf online version
  16. ^ . European Central Bank. Archived from the original on 16 December 2008. Retrieved 10 March 2009.
  17. ^ Noyer, Christian (12 January 2016). "Thoughts on the zero lower bound in relation with monetary and financial stability". Bank for International Settlements. Retrieved 18 January 2016. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  18. ^ "ECB to discuss new guidance after inflation target tweak -Vice President". Reuters. 12 July 2021. Retrieved 12 July 2021.
  19. ^ a b c d Mishkin, Frederic S. (2000). "Inflation Targeting in Emerging-Market Countries" (PDF). American Economic Review. 90 (2): 105–109. doi:10.1257/aer.90.2.105. S2CID 16768021.
  20. ^ Kemme, David & Banaian, King & Sargsyan, Grigor. (2008). Inflation Targeting in Armenia: Monetary Policy in Transition. Comparative Economic Studies. 50. 421-437. 10.1057/ces.2008.22.
  21. ^ "Inflation report" (PDF). cba.am. Central Bank of Armenia. Retrieved 11 December 2022.
  22. ^ INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND. Republic of Armenia: Sixth Review under the Stand-by Arrangement-Press Release; and Staff Report.
  23. ^ a b García Silva, Pablo (1 May 2014). "A Quince Años de las Metas de Inflación en Chile" [Fifteen Years into the Implementation of Fully-fledged Inflation Targeting in Chile]. Economic Policy Papers of the Central Bank of Chile (in Spanish). Central Bank of Chile. 48.
  24. ^ See the Czech National Bank's website
  25. ^ N. Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen (2014): "Central Bank Transparency and Independence: Updates and New Measures", International Journal of Central Banking, March 2014, pp. 189-253.
  26. ^ Ali Alichi, Jaromir Benes, Joshua Felman, Irene Feng, Charles Freedman, Douglas Laxton, Evan Tanner, David Vavra, and Hou Wang (2015): "Frontiers of Monetary Policymaking: Adding the Exchange Rate as a Tool to Combat Deflationary Risks in the Czech Republic", International Monetary Fund, Working Paper No. 15/74.
  27. ^ Michal Franta, Tomas Holub, Petr Kral, Ivana Kubicova, Katerina Smidkova, Borek Vasicek (2014): "The Exchange Rate as an Instrument at Zero Interest Rates: The Case of the Czech Republic", Czech National Bank, Research and Policy Note No. 3/2014.
  28. ^ Skorepa, M., and Hampl, M. (2014): "Evolution of the Czech National Bank’s holdings of foreign exchange reserves", BIS Papers No. 78, pp. 159-169.
  29. ^ "Why does the Federal Reserve aim for 2 percent inflation over time?". The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Retrieved 8 March 2015.
  30. ^ As quoted on page 158 of Poole, W. (2006), "Inflation targeting", speech delivered to Junior Achievement of Arkansas, Inc., Little Rock, Arkansas, 16 February 2006. Published in Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, vol. 88, no. 3 (May–June 2006), pp. 155-164.
  31. ^ Fraher, John (5 June 2008). "King May Be More Irritant Than Ally for Brown at BOE". Bloomberg Exclusive. Retrieved 5 August 2008.
  32. ^ Bernanke, Ben S. (25 March 2003). A Perspective on Inflation Targeting. Annual Washington Policy Conference of the National Association of Business Economists. Washington, D.C.
  33. ^ Ben S. Bernanke and Frederic S. Mishkin, (1997), "Inflation targeting: a new framework for monetary policy?", The Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 11, no. 2 (Spring 1997), pp. 97-116.
  34. ^ "Review of Monetary Policy Strategy, Tools, and Communications". www.federalreserve.gov. Federal Reserve. Retrieved 17 April 2022.
  35. ^ "2020 Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy". www.federalreserve.gov. Federal Reserve. Retrieved 17 April 2022.
  36. ^ Muth, John F. (1961). "Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements". Econometrica. 29 (3): 315–335. doi:10.2307/1909635. JSTOR 1909635.
  37. ^ Galbács, Peter (2015). "The Rational Expectations Hypothesis as a Key Element of New Classical Macroeconomics". The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics. A Positive Critique. Contributions to Economics. Heidelberg/New York/Dordrecht/London: Springer. pp. 53–90. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-17578-2. ISBN 978-3-319-17578-2.
  38. ^ a b "Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words? Assessing the Effects of Inflation Targeting Track Records on Macroeconomic Performance". IMF. Retrieved 8 January 2023.
  39. ^ "Stock Returns and Inflation Redux: An Explanation from Monetary Policy in Advanced and Emerging Markets". IMF. Retrieved 8 January 2023.
  40. ^ Bernanke, Ben S.; Laubach, Thomas; Mishkin, Frederic S.; Posen, Adam S. (2001). Inflation targeting: lessons from the international experience. Princeton Univ. Press. ISBN 9780691086897.
  41. ^ John C. Williams , President and CEO , Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco (31 October 2014). "Inflation Targeting and the Global Financial Crisis: Successes and Challenges". Federal Reserve Board of San Francisco. Retrieved 1 December 2016.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  42. ^ Hansen, Daniel (2021). "The Economic Consequences of Banking Crises: The Role of Central Banks and Optimal Independence". American Political Science Review. 116 (2): 453–469. doi:10.1017/S0003055421001325. ISSN 0003-0554. S2CID 244148411.
  43. ^ Maurice Obstfeld (2014). "Never Say Never: Commentary on a Policymaker's Reflections" (PDF). IMF Economic Review. 62 (4): 656–693. doi:10.1057/imfer.2014.12. S2CID 154975315.
  44. ^ . Bank of England. Archived from the original on 7 July 2016. Retrieved 20 January 2016.
  45. ^ Janet L. Yellen (24 February 2015). Monetary Policy Report (PDF). Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
  46. ^ Amira, Beldi; Mouldi, Djelassi; Feridun, Mete (2012). "Growth effects of inflation targeting revisited: empirical evidence from emerging markets". Applied Economics Letters. 20 (6): 587–591. doi:10.1080/13504851.2012.718054. S2CID 154966050.
  47. ^ Benchimol, Jonathan; Fourçans, André (2019). "Central bank losses and monetary policy rules: a DSGE investigation". International Review of Economics & Finance. 61 (1): 289–303. doi:10.1016/j.iref.2019.01.010. S2CID 159290669.
  48. ^ a b Quiggin, John (26 January 2012). "Inflation target tyranny". Retrieved 28 January 2012.
  49. ^ Svensson, Lars (21 September 2009). "Flexible inflation targeting – lessons from the financial crisis" (PDF). speech at the workshop "Towards a new framework for monetary policy? Lessons from the crisis", organized by the Netherlands Bank, Amsterdam.
  50. ^ "BoJ to pursue inflation target 'flexibly'". Financial Times. 11 April 2013. Retrieved 20 January 2016.
  51. ^ Frankel, Jeffrey (16 May 2012). "The Death of Inflation Targeting". Project Syndicate.
  52. ^ Lucrezia Reichlin and Richard Baldwin, eds. (2013), "Is Inflation Targeting Dead? Central Banking After the Crisis", Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR)
  53. ^ Haizhou Huang; Shang-Jin Wei (September 2006). "Monetary Policies for Developing Countries: The Role of Institutional Quality". Journal of International Economics. 70: 239–52. doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.09.001. S2CID 33698841.
  54. ^ John C. Williams, (2014), "Inflation Targeting and the Global Financial Crisis: Successes and Challenges", Essay presentation to the South African Reserve Bank Conference on Fourteen Years of Inflation Targeting in South Africa and the Challenge of a Changing Mandate, Pretoria, South Africa
  55. ^ "GESSAROLI: Artificially low interest rates -- we're paying the price". torontosun. Retrieved 14 April 2022.
  56. ^ Herbener, Jeffrey. "Written Testimony before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy and Technology" (PDF). U.S. House of Representatives Financial Services Committee. Retrieved 22 October 2016.
  57. ^ "Should We Fear Deflation?". Retrieved 22 October 2016.
  58. ^ Atkeson, Andrew; Kehoe, Patrick J. (2004). "Deflation and Depression: Is There an Empirical Link?" (PDF). American Economic Review. 94 (2): 99–103. doi:10.1257/0002828041301588.
  59. ^ Ryssdal, Kai (3 August 2023). "El-Erian advises Federal Reserve to rethink its 2% inflation target". Marketplace. Retrieved 8 August 2023.
  60. ^ (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 17 September 2009.
  61. ^ "Inflation-Targeting, Flexible Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Performance since the Great Recession" (PDF). The Centre for European Policy Studies. March 2014. Retrieved 28 December 2014.
  62. ^ Jahan, Sarwat (28 March 2012). "Inflation Targeting: Holding the Line". IMF. Retrieved 18 January 2016.
  63. ^ Roger, Scott (March 2010). "Inflation Targeting Turns 20". Finance & Development. 47 (1). Retrieved 18 January 2016.
  64. ^ "Speech: Talk by Governor". 4 August 1993.
  65. ^ Leiderman, Leonardo (1 May 2000). "Monetary Policy Rules and Transmission Mechanisms Under Inflation Targeting in Israel" (PDF). Documentos de Trabajo. No. Banco Central de Chile. Retrieved 18 October 2009.
  66. ^ Singer, M. (2015): "From a Peg to Inflation Targeting: CNB Experience", presentation at the High-level Seminar on the Benefits of Adopting a Structured Approach to Policy Analysis, Rabat, Morocco, 21 May 2015
  67. ^ "Inflation targeting". www.mnb.hu.
  68. ^ Galindo, Luis Miguel (13 May 2005). "Alternatives to inflation targeting in Mexico" (PDF). No. Amherst/CEDES Conference on Inflation targeting, Buenos Aires. Retrieved 18 October 2009.
  69. ^ Marit Tronier Halvorsen (26 September 2013). "Norges Bank holder fast ved inflasjonsmålet". Dagens Næringsliv (in Norwegian).
  70. ^ "Forsiden". 2 February 2019.
  71. ^ "Inflation target". www.cb.is.
  72. ^ Rocel C. Felix (2 January 2002). "BSP adopts inflation targeting starting this year". The Philippine Star.
  73. ^ "National Bank of Georgia". www.nbg.gov.ge. Retrieved 3 January 2018.
  74. ^ "In historic shift, Fed sets inflation target". Reuters. 26 January 2012. Retrieved 18 January 2016.
  75. ^ "Doubt Greets Bank of Japan's Easing Shift". The Wall Street Journal. 22 January 2013. Retrieved 18 January 2016.
  76. ^ "404 | Банк России" (PDF). cbr.ru. {{cite web}}: Cite uses generic title (help)
  77. ^ Решения (IR.KZ), Интернет. "Қазақстан Ұлттық Банкі". nationalbank.kz.
  78. ^ "Про монетарну політику". Національний банк України.
  79. ^ "Про Основні засади грошово-кредитної політики на 2016 - 2020 роки".
  80. ^ "India adopts inflation target of 4% for next five years under monetary policy framework".
  81. ^ "Inflation Targeting Regime in Argentina. Press conference".

External links edit

  • Table of Central Bank Inflation Targets

inflation, targeting, macroeconomics, inflation, targeting, monetary, policy, where, central, bank, follows, explicit, target, inflation, rate, medium, term, announces, this, inflation, target, public, assumption, that, best, that, monetary, policy, support, l. In macroeconomics inflation targeting is a monetary policy where a central bank follows an explicit target for the inflation rate for the medium term and announces this inflation target to the public The assumption is that the best that monetary policy can do to support long term growth of the economy is to maintain price stability and price stability is achieved by controlling inflation The central bank uses interest rates as its main short term monetary instrument 1 2 3 An inflation targeting central bank will raise or lower interest rates based on above target or below target inflation respectively The conventional wisdom is that raising interest rates usually cools the economy to rein in inflation lowering interest rates usually accelerates the economy thereby boosting inflation The first three countries to implement fully fledged inflation targeting were New Zealand Canada and the United Kingdom in the early 1990s although Germany had adopted many elements of inflation targeting earlier 4 5 Contents 1 History 1 1 New Zealand Canada United Kingdom 1 2 European Central Bank 1 3 Emerging markets 1 3 1 Armenia 1 3 2 Chile 1 3 3 Czech Republic 1 4 United States 2 Theoretical questions 3 Empirical issues 3 1 Target band size 3 2 Track record 4 Debate 4 1 Benefits 4 2 Shortcomings 4 3 Choosing a positive zero or negative inflation target 4 4 Numerical target 5 Variations 6 Countries 7 See also 8 References 9 External linksHistory editEarly proposals of monetary systems targeting the price level or the inflation rate rather than the exchange rate followed the general crisis of the gold standard after World War I Irving Fisher proposed a compensated dollar system in which the gold content in paper money would vary with the price of goods in terms of gold so that the price level in terms of paper money would stay fixed Fisher s proposal was a first attempt to target prices while retaining the automatic functioning of the gold standard In his Tract on Monetary Reform 1923 John Maynard Keynes advocated what we would now call an inflation targeting scheme In the context of sudden inflations and deflations in the international economy right after World War I Keynes recommended a policy of exchange rate flexibility appreciating the currency as a response to international inflation and depreciating it when there are international deflationary forces so that internal prices remained more or less stable Interest in inflation targeting waned during the Bretton Woods era 1944 1971 as they were inconsistent with the exchange rate pegs that prevailed during three decades after World War II New Zealand Canada United Kingdom edit Inflation targeting was pioneered in New Zealand in 1990 6 Canada was the second country to formally adopt inflation targeting in February 1991 4 5 The United Kingdom adopted inflation targeting in October 1992 after exiting the European Exchange Rate Mechanism 4 7 The Bank of England s Monetary Policy Committee was given sole responsibility in 1998 for setting interest rates to meet the Government s Retail Prices Index RPI inflation target of 2 5 8 The target changed to 2 in December 2003 when the Consumer Price Index CPI replaced the Retail Prices Index as the UK Treasury s inflation index 9 If inflation overshoots or undershoots the target by more than 1 the Governor of the Bank of England is required to write a letter to the Chancellor of the Exchequer explaining why and how he will remedy the situation 10 11 12 The success of inflation targeting in the United Kingdom has been attributed to the Bank s focus on transparency 7 The Bank of England has been a leader in producing innovative ways of communicating information to the public especially through its Inflation Report which have been emulated by many other central banks 4 Inflation targeting then spread to other advanced economies in the 1990s and began to spread to emerging markets beginning in the 2000s European Central Bank edit Although the ECB does not consider itself to be an inflation targeting central bank 13 after the inception of the euro in January 1999 the objective of the European Central Bank ECB has been to maintain price stability within the Eurozone 14 The Governing Council of the ECB in October 1998 15 defined price stability as inflation of under 2 a year on year increase in the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices HICP for the euro area of below 2 and added that price stability was to be maintained over the medium term 16 The Governing Council confirmed this definition in May 2003 following a thorough evaluation of the ECB s monetary policy strategy On that occasion the Governing Council clarified that in the pursuit of price stability it aims to maintain inflation rates below but close to 2 over the medium term 15 Since then the numerical target of 2 has become common for major developed economies including the United States since January 2012 and Japan since January 2013 17 In 2021 the ECB tweaked its inflation target to a symmetrical 2 18 Emerging markets edit In 2000 Frederic S Mishkin concluded that although inflation targeting is not a panacea and may not be appropriate for many emerging market countries it can be a highly useful monetary policy strategy in a number of them 19 Armenia edit The Central Bank of Armenia CBA announced in 2006 that it will implement an inflation targeting strategy The process of full transition to inflation targeting was supposed to end in 2008 Operational macroeconomic and institutional preconditions for inflation targeting should have been met to ensure a full transition CBA believes that it has managed to meet all the preconditions successfully and should concentrate on building a public trust in the new monetary policy regime A specific model has been developed to estimate CBA s reaction function and the results showed that the inertia of inflation rate and interest rate are most vital in the reaction function This can be an evidence that the announcement of the strategy is a trustworthy commitment Obviously there are people who claim that inflation targeting is too restrictive for dealing with positive supply shocks On the other hand the IMF claims that inflation targeting strategy is good for developing economies however it requires a lot of information for forecasting 20 The Central Bank continued to pursue a policy of tightening monetary conditions during the reporting period increasing the policy interest rate by a total of 2 75 percentage points At the same time about half of the tightening 1 25 percentage points was carried out in 2022 in March reacting to the high inflation situation formed in the case of unprecedented uncertainties 21 Being constantly hit by external shocks to the national economy over the past three years Armenia is still on the path of recovery thanks to economic management efforts According to the 3 year Stand By Arrangement which came to its end on May 16 2022 important structural and institutional reforms have been implemented Those include improvement of tax compliance budget process refinement strengthening the stability of financial sector and most importantly fostering the inflation targeting framework 22 Chile edit Further information Inflation in Chile In Chile a 20 inflation rate pushed the Central Bank of Chile to announce at the end of 1990 an inflation objective for the annual inflation rate for the year ending in December 1991 19 However Chile was not regarded as a fully fledged inflation targeter until October 1999 5 23 According to Pablo Garcia Silva member of the board of the Central Bank of Chile this has allowed to attenuate inflation Garcia Silva exemplifies this with the limited inflation seen in Chile during the 2002 Brazilian general election and the Great Recession of 2008 2009 23 Czech Republic edit The Czech National Bank CNB is an example of an inflation targeting central bank in a small open economy with a recent history of economic transition and real convergence to its Western European peers Since 2010 the CNB uses 2 percent with a 1pp range around it as the inflation target 24 The CNB places a lot of emphasis on transparency and communication indeed a recent study of more than 100 central banks found the CNB to be among the four most transparent ones 25 In 2012 inflation was expected to fall well below the target leading the CNB to gradually reduce the level of its basic monetary policy instrument the 2 week repo rate until the zero lower bound actually 0 05 percent was reached in late 2012 In light of the threat of a further fall in inflation and possibly even of a protracted period of deflation on 7 November 2013 the CNB declared an immediate commitment to weaken the exchange rate to the level of 27 Czech korunas per 1 euro day on day weakening by about 5 percent and to keep the exchange rate from getting stronger than this value until at least the end of 2014 later on this was changed to the second half of 2016 The CNB thus decided to use the exchange rate as a supplementary tool to make sure that inflation returns to the 2 percent target level Such a use of the exchange rate as tool within the regime of inflation targeting should not be confused with a fixed exchange rate system or with a currency war 26 27 28 United States edit In a historic shift on 25 January 2012 U S Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke set a 2 target inflation rate bringing the Fed in line with many of the world s other major central banks 29 Until then the Fed s policy committee the Federal Open Market Committee FOMC did not have an explicit inflation target but regularly announced a desired target range for inflation usually between 1 7 and 2 measured by the personal consumption expenditures price index Prior to adoption of the target some people argued that an inflation target would give the Fed too little flexibility to stabilise growth and or employment in the event of an external economic shock Another criticism was that an explicit target might turn central bankers into what Mervyn King former Governor of the Bank of England had in 1997 colorfully termed inflation nutters 30 that is central bankers who concentrate on the inflation target to the detriment of stable growth employment and or exchange rates King went on to help design the Bank s inflation targeting policy 31 and asserts that the buffoonery has not actually happened as did Chairman of the U S Federal Reserve Ben Bernanke who stated in 2003 that all inflation targeting at the time was of a flexible variety in theory and practice 32 Former Chairman Alan Greenspan as well as other former FOMC members such as Alan Blinder typically agreed with the benefits of inflation targeting but were reluctant to accept the loss of freedom involved Bernanke however was a well known advocate 33 In August 2020 the FOMC released a revised Statement on Longer Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy 34 The review announced the FED would seek to achieve inflation that averages 2 over time In practice this means that following periods when inflation has been running persistently below 2 percent appropriate monetary policy will likely aim to achieve inflation moderately above 2 percent for some time 35 This way the fed hopes to better anchor longer term inflation expectations which they say would foster price stability and moderate long term interest rates and enhance the Committee s ability to promote maximum employment in the face of significant economic disturbances Theoretical questions editThis article is written like a research paper or scientific journal Please help improve the article by rewriting it in encyclopedic style and simplify overly technical phrases November 2017 Learn how and when to remove this template message New classical macroeconomics and rational expectations hypothesis can explain how and why inflation targeting works Expectations of firms or the subjective probability distribution of outcomes will be around the prediction of the theory itself the objective probability distribution of those outcomes for the same information set 36 So rational agents expect the most probable outcome to emerge However there is limited success at specifying the relevant model and the full and perfect knowledge of a given macroeconomic system can be regarded as a comfortable presumption at best Knowledge of the relevant model is not feasible even if high level econometrical techniques were accessible or adequate identification of the relevant explanatory variables were performed So estimation bias depends on the quantity and quality of information to which the modeller has access In other words estimations are asymptotically unbiased with respect to the exploited information Meanwhile consistency can be interpreted similarly On the basis of asymptotical unbiasedness a moderated version of the rational expectations hypothesis can be suggested in which familiarity with the theoretical parameters is not a requirement for the relevant model An agent with access to sufficiently vast quality information and high level methodological skills could specify its own quasi relevant model describing a specific macroeconomic system By increasing the amount of information processed this agent could further reduce its bias If this agent were also focal such as a central bank then other agents would likely accept the proposed model and adjust their expectations accordingly In this way individual expectations become unbiased as much as possible albeit against a background of considerable passivity According to some researches this is the theoretical background of the functionality of inflation targeting regimes 37 Empirical issues editTarget band size edit While most inflation targeting countries set their target band at 2 percentage points the band sizes are wide ranging across countries and inflation targeters frequently update their target bands 38 Track record edit Inflation targeting countries track records in maintaining inflation within the central banks target bands differ substantially and financial markets differentiate inflation targeters by behaviors 39 38 Debate editThere is some empirical evidence that inflation targeting does what its advocates claim that is making the outcomes if not the process of monetary policy more transparent 40 41 A 2021 study in the American Political Science Review found that independent central banks with rigid inflation targeting policies produce worse outcomes in banking crises than independent central banks whose policy mandate does not rigidly prioritize inflation 42 Benefits edit Inflation targeting allows monetary policy to focus on domestic considerations and to respond to shocks to the domestic economy which is not possible under a fixed exchange rate system Also investor uncertainty is reduced and therefore investors may more easily factor in likely interest rate changes into their investment decisions Inflation expectations that are better anchored allow monetary authorities to cut policy interest rates countercyclically 43 Transparency is another key benefit of inflation targeting Central banks in developed countries that have successfully implemented inflation targeting tend to maintain regular channels of communication with the public For example the Bank of England pioneered the Inflation Report in 1993 which outlines the bank s views about the past and future performance of inflation and monetary policy 44 Although it was not an inflation targeting country until January 2012 up until then the United States Statement on Longer Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy enumerated the benefits of clear communication it facilitates well informed decisionmaking by households and businesses reduces economic and financial uncertainty increases the effectiveness of monetary policy and enhances transparency and accountability which are essential in a democratic society 45 An explicit numerical inflation target increases a central bank s accountability and thus it is less likely that the central bank falls prey to the time inconsistency trap This accountability is especially significant because even countries with weak institutions can build public support for an independent central bank Institutional commitment can also insulate the bank from political pressure to undertake an overly expansionary monetary policy 19 An econometric analysis found that although inflation targeting results in higher economic growth it does not necessarily guarantee stability based on their study of 36 emerging economies from 1979 to 2009 46 Shortcomings edit Supporters of a nominal income target criticize the propensity of inflation targeting to neglect output shocks by focusing solely on the price level Adherents of market monetarism led by Scott Sumner argue that in the United States the Federal Reserve s mandate is to stabilize both output and the price level and that consequently a nominal income target would better suit the Fed s mandate 47 Australian economist John Quiggin who also endorses nominal income targeting stated that it would maintain or enhance the transparency associated with a system based on stated targets while restoring the balance missing from a monetary policy based solely on the goal of price stability 48 Quiggin blamed the late 2000s recession on inflation targeting in an economic environment in which low inflation is a drag on growth In practice many central banks conduct flexible inflation targeting where the central bank strives to keep inflation near the target except when such an effort would imply too much output volatility 49 50 Quiggin also criticized former Fed Chair Alan Greenspan and former European Central Bank President Jean Claude Trichet for ignor ing or even applaud ing the unsustainable bubbles in speculative real estate that produced the crisis and to react ing too slowly as the evidence emerged 48 In a 2012 op ed University of Nottingham economist Mohammed Farhaan Iqbal suggested that inflation targeting evidently passed away in September 2008 referencing the 2007 2012 global financial crisis Frankel suggested that central banks that had been relying on inflation targeting had not paid enough attention to asset price bubbles and also criticized inflation targeting for inappropriate responses to supply shocks and terms of trade shocks In turn Iqbal suggested that nominal income targeting or product price targeting would succeed inflation targeting as the dominant monetary policy regime 51 The debate continues and many observers expect that inflation targeting will continue to be the dominant monetary policy regime perhaps after certain modifications 52 Empirically it is not so obvious that inflation targeteers have better inflation control Some economists argue that better institutions increase a country s chances of successfully targeting inflation 53 As regards the impact of the 2007 2012 financial crisis John Williams a high ranking Federal Reserve official concludes that when gauged by the behavior of inflation since the crisis inflation targeting delivered on its promise 54 In an article written since the COVID 19 pandemic critics have pointed out that the Bank of Canada s inflation targeting has had unintended consequences with persistently low interest rates over the last 12 years fuelling an increase in home prices by encouraging borrowing and contributing to wealth inequalities by supporting higher equity values 55 Choosing a positive zero or negative inflation target edit Choosing a positive inflation target has at least two drawbacks Over time the compounded effect of small annual price increases will significantly reduce a currency s purchasing power For example successfully hitting a target of 2 each year for 40 years would cause the price of a 100 basket of goods to rise to 220 80 This drawback would be minimized or reversed by choosing a zero inflation target or a negative target Vendors must expend resources more frequently to reprice their goods and services This drawback would be minimized by choosing a zero inflation target However policymakers feel the drawbacks are outweighed by the fact that a positive inflation target reduces the chance of an economy falling into a period of deflation Some economists argue that fear of deflation is unfounded citing studies that show inflation is more likely than deflation to cause an economic contraction 56 57 Andrew Atkeson and Patrick J Kehoe wrote According to standard economic theory deflation is the necessary consequence of optimal monetary policy In 1969 Milton Friedman argued that under the optimal policy the nominal interest rate should be zero and the price level should fall steadily at the real rate of interest Since then Friedman s argument has been confirmed in a formal setting See for example V V Chari Lawrence Christiano and Patrick Kehoe 1996 and Harold Cole and Narayana Kocherlakota 1998 58 Effectively Friedman was arguing for a negative moderately deflationary inflation target Numerical target edit The typical numerical target of 2 has come under debate since the period of rapid inflation experienced following the monetary expansion during the COVID 19 pandemic Mohamed El Erian has suggested the Federal Reserve raise it inflation target to a stable 3 rate of inflation saying There s nothing scientific about 2 59 Variations editContrast to the usual inflation rate targeting Laurence M Ball proposed targeting on long run inflation targeting which takes the exchange rate into account and monetary conditions index targeting 60 In his proposal the monetary conditions index is a weighted average of the interest rate and exchange rate It will be easy to put many other things into this monetary conditions index In the constrained discretion framework inflation targeting combines two contradicting monetary policies a rule based approach and a discretionary approach as a precise numerical target is given for inflation in the medium term and a response to economic shocks in the short term Some inflation targeters associate this with more economic stability 2 61 Countries editThere were 27 countries regarded by the Bank of England s Centre for Central Banking Studies as fully fledged inflation targeters at the beginning of 2012 5 Other lists count 26 or 28 countries as of 2010 62 63 Since then the United States and Japan have also adopted inflation targets although the Federal Reserve like the European Central Bank 13 does not consider itself to be an inflation targeting central bank Country Central bank Year adopted inflation targeting NotesNew Zealand Reserve Bank of New Zealand 12 1989 5 The pioneer see Section 8 Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act of 1989 Canada Bank of Canada 02 1991 5 United Kingdom Bank of England 10 1992 5 First in Europe although Germany had adopted many elements of inflation targeting earlier 4 Sweden Sveriges Riksbank 01 1993 5 The inflation target regime was announced in January 1993 and applied as of 1995 5 The Riksbank had practiced price level targeting since abandonment of the gold standard in 1931 Australia Reserve Bank of Australia 06 1993 5 64 Israel Bank of Israel 06 1997 5 Informally since 1992 Fully fledged inflation targeting from June 1997 5 65 Czech Republic Czech National Bank 12 1997 5 66 First in Central and Eastern Europe Poland National Bank of Poland 1998 5 Brazil Brazilian Central Bank 06 1999 5 Chile Central Bank of Chile 09 1999 5 At the end of 1990 a 20 inflation rate pushed the Central Bank of Chile to announce an inflation objective for the annual inflation rate for the year ending in December 1991 19 Colombia Banco de la Republica 10 1999 5 South Africa South African Reserve Bank 02 2000 5 Thailand Bank of Thailand 05 2000 5 Hungary Hungarian National Bank 06 2001 67 Mexico Bank of Mexico 2001 5 Some sources say 1999 68 Norway Norges Bank 03 2001 5 69 70 Iceland Central Bank of Iceland 03 2001 71 Peru Central Reserve Bank of Peru 01 2002 5 Philippines Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas 01 2002 5 72 Guatemala Bank of Guatemala 01 2005 5 Indonesia Bank Indonesia 07 2005 5 Romania National Bank of Romania 08 2005 5 Armenia Republic of Central Bank of Armenia 01 2006 5 Turkey Turkiye Cumhuriyet Merkez Bankasi 01 2006 5 Ghana Bank of Ghana 05 2007 5 Informally in 2002 formally from May 2007 5 Georgia National Bank of Georgia 01 2009 73 Serbia Republic of National Bank of Serbia 01 2009 5 United States Federal Reserve 01 2012 74 Japan Bank of Japan 01 2013 75 Russian Federation Central Bank of Russia 01 2014 76 Republic of Kazakhstan National Bank of Republic of Kazakhstan 08 2015 77 Ukraine National Bank of Ukraine 08 2015 78 Official document about implementation of inflation targeting in Ukraine 79 India Reserve Bank of India 08 2016 80 Decision taken after India had 10 inflation rate for around 5 years Argentina Central Bank of Argentina 09 2016 81 Until September 2018 when the Central Bank changed its monetary policy to crawling peg In addition South Korea Bank of Korea and Iceland Central Bank of Iceland and others 5 See also edit nbsp Economics portalInflationism Monetarism Nominal income target Output gap Phillips curve Taylor ruleReferences edit Coy Peter 7 November 2005 What s The Fuss Over Inflation Targeting BusinessWeek No The New Fed Archived from the original on 28 July 2011 a b Jahan Sarwat Inflation Targeting Holding the Line International Monetary Funds Finance amp Development Retrieved 28 December 2014 Fisher Irving 1922 Dollar Stabilization In Chisholm Hugh ed Encyclopaedia Britannica 12th ed London amp New York The Encyclopaedia Britannica Company a b c d e Inflation Targeting Has Been A Successful Monetary Policy Strategy NBER Retrieved 31 October 2016 a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r s t u v w x y z aa ab ac ad ae af State of the art of inflation targeting PDF Bank of England Centre for Central Banking Studies 2012 17 18 44 Archived from the original PDF on 11 August 2017 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Andrew G Haldane 1995 Targeting Inflation A Conference of Central Banks on the Use of Inflation Targets Organised by the Bank of England 9 10 March 1995 London Bank of England ISBN 9781857300734 a b Targeting Inflation The United Kingdom in Retrospect PDF IMF Retrieved 31 October 2016 Key Monetary Policy Dates Since 1990 Bank of England Archived from the original on 29 June 2007 Retrieved 20 September 2007 Remit of the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England and the New Inflation Target PDF HM Treasury 10 December 2003 Archived PDF from the original on 26 September 2007 Retrieved 20 September 2007 Monetary Policy Framework Bank of England Retrieved 31 October 2016 CCBS Lecture Series Inflation Targeting The British Experience Bank of England January 1999 Retrieved 31 October 2016 Inflation targeting is 25 years old but has it worked BBC 11 March 2015 Retrieved 31 October 2016 Why do we target 2pc inflation And does it matter if we keep missing it The Telegraph 16 June 2015 Retrieved 31 October 2016 a b Governor Laurence H Meyer 17 July 2001 Inflation Targets and Inflation Targeting The Federal Reserve Board Retrieved 1 December 2016 wikisource consolidation a b THE EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK HISTORY ROLE AND FUNCTIONS BY HANSPETER K SCHELLER SECOND REVISED EDITION 2006 ISBN 92 899 0022 9 print ISBN 92 899 0027 X online page 81 at the pdf online version Powers and responsibilities of the European Central Bank European Central Bank Archived from the original on 16 December 2008 Retrieved 10 March 2009 Noyer Christian 12 January 2016 Thoughts on the zero lower bound in relation with monetary and financial stability Bank for International Settlements Retrieved 18 January 2016 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help ECB to discuss new guidance after inflation target tweak Vice President Reuters 12 July 2021 Retrieved 12 July 2021 a b c d Mishkin Frederic S 2000 Inflation Targeting in Emerging Market Countries PDF American Economic Review 90 2 105 109 doi 10 1257 aer 90 2 105 S2CID 16768021 Kemme David amp Banaian King amp Sargsyan Grigor 2008 Inflation Targeting in Armenia Monetary Policy in Transition Comparative Economic Studies 50 421 437 10 1057 ces 2008 22 Inflation report PDF cba am Central Bank of Armenia Retrieved 11 December 2022 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND Republic of Armenia Sixth Review under the Stand by Arrangement Press Release and Staff Report a b Garcia Silva Pablo 1 May 2014 A Quince Anos de las Metas de Inflacion en Chile Fifteen Years into the Implementation of Fully fledged Inflation Targeting in Chile Economic Policy Papers of the Central Bank of Chile in Spanish Central Bank of Chile 48 See the Czech National Bank s website N Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen 2014 Central Bank Transparency and Independence Updates and New Measures International Journal of Central Banking March 2014 pp 189 253 Ali Alichi Jaromir Benes Joshua Felman Irene Feng Charles Freedman Douglas Laxton Evan Tanner David Vavra and Hou Wang 2015 Frontiers of Monetary Policymaking Adding the Exchange Rate as a Tool to Combat Deflationary Risks in the Czech Republic International Monetary Fund Working Paper No 15 74 Michal Franta Tomas Holub Petr Kral Ivana Kubicova Katerina Smidkova Borek Vasicek 2014 The Exchange Rate as an Instrument at Zero Interest Rates The Case of the Czech Republic Czech National Bank Research and Policy Note No 3 2014 Skorepa M and Hampl M 2014 Evolution of the Czech National Bank s holdings of foreign exchange reserves BIS Papers No 78 pp 159 169 Why does the Federal Reserve aim for 2 percent inflation over time The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Retrieved 8 March 2015 As quoted on page 158 of Poole W 2006 Inflation targeting speech delivered to Junior Achievement of Arkansas Inc Little Rock Arkansas 16 February 2006 Published in Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review vol 88 no 3 May June 2006 pp 155 164 Fraher John 5 June 2008 King May Be More Irritant Than Ally for Brown at BOE Bloomberg Exclusive Retrieved 5 August 2008 Bernanke Ben S 25 March 2003 A Perspective on Inflation Targeting Annual Washington Policy Conference of the National Association of Business Economists Washington D C Ben S Bernanke and Frederic S Mishkin 1997 Inflation targeting a new framework for monetary policy The Journal of Economic Perspectives vol 11 no 2 Spring 1997 pp 97 116 Review of Monetary Policy Strategy Tools and Communications www federalreserve gov Federal Reserve Retrieved 17 April 2022 2020 Statement on Longer Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy www federalreserve gov Federal Reserve Retrieved 17 April 2022 Muth John F 1961 Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements Econometrica 29 3 315 335 doi 10 2307 1909635 JSTOR 1909635 Galbacs Peter 2015 The Rational Expectations Hypothesis as a Key Element of New Classical Macroeconomics The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics A Positive Critique Contributions to Economics Heidelberg New York Dordrecht London Springer pp 53 90 doi 10 1007 978 3 319 17578 2 ISBN 978 3 319 17578 2 a b Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words Assessing the Effects of Inflation Targeting Track Records on Macroeconomic Performance IMF Retrieved 8 January 2023 Stock Returns and Inflation Redux An Explanation from Monetary Policy in Advanced and Emerging Markets IMF Retrieved 8 January 2023 Bernanke Ben S Laubach Thomas Mishkin Frederic S Posen Adam S 2001 Inflation targeting lessons from the international experience Princeton Univ Press ISBN 9780691086897 John C Williams President and CEO Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 31 October 2014 Inflation Targeting and the Global Financial Crisis Successes and Challenges Federal Reserve Board of San Francisco Retrieved 1 December 2016 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Hansen Daniel 2021 The Economic Consequences of Banking Crises The Role of Central Banks and Optimal Independence American Political Science Review 116 2 453 469 doi 10 1017 S0003055421001325 ISSN 0003 0554 S2CID 244148411 Maurice Obstfeld 2014 Never Say Never Commentary on a Policymaker s Reflections PDF IMF Economic Review 62 4 656 693 doi 10 1057 imfer 2014 12 S2CID 154975315 Inflation Report Bank of England Archived from the original on 7 July 2016 Retrieved 20 January 2016 Janet L Yellen 24 February 2015 Monetary Policy Report PDF Washington D C Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Amira Beldi Mouldi Djelassi Feridun Mete 2012 Growth effects of inflation targeting revisited empirical evidence from emerging markets Applied Economics Letters 20 6 587 591 doi 10 1080 13504851 2012 718054 S2CID 154966050 Benchimol Jonathan Fourcans Andre 2019 Central bank losses and monetary policy rules a DSGE investigation International Review of Economics amp Finance 61 1 289 303 doi 10 1016 j iref 2019 01 010 S2CID 159290669 a b Quiggin John 26 January 2012 Inflation target tyranny Retrieved 28 January 2012 Svensson Lars 21 September 2009 Flexible inflation targeting lessons from the financial crisis PDF speech at the workshop Towards a new framework for monetary policy Lessons from the crisis organized by the Netherlands Bank Amsterdam BoJ to pursue inflation target flexibly Financial Times 11 April 2013 Retrieved 20 January 2016 Frankel Jeffrey 16 May 2012 The Death of Inflation Targeting Project Syndicate Lucrezia Reichlin and Richard Baldwin eds 2013 Is Inflation Targeting Dead Central Banking After the Crisis Centre for Economic Policy Research CEPR Haizhou Huang Shang Jin Wei September 2006 Monetary Policies for Developing Countries The Role of Institutional Quality Journal of International Economics 70 239 52 doi 10 1016 j jinteco 2005 09 001 S2CID 33698841 John C Williams 2014 Inflation Targeting and the Global Financial Crisis Successes and Challenges Essay presentation to the South African Reserve Bank Conference on Fourteen Years of Inflation Targeting in South Africa and the Challenge of a Changing Mandate Pretoria South Africa GESSAROLI Artificially low interest rates we re paying the price torontosun Retrieved 14 April 2022 Herbener Jeffrey Written Testimony before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy and Technology PDF U S House of Representatives Financial Services Committee Retrieved 22 October 2016 Should We Fear Deflation Retrieved 22 October 2016 Atkeson Andrew Kehoe Patrick J 2004 Deflation and Depression Is There an Empirical Link PDF American Economic Review 94 2 99 103 doi 10 1257 0002828041301588 Ryssdal Kai 3 August 2023 El Erian advises Federal Reserve to rethink its 2 inflation target Marketplace Retrieved 8 August 2023 Policy Rules for Open Economies PDF Archived from the original PDF on 17 September 2009 Inflation Targeting Flexible Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Performance since the Great Recession PDF The Centre for European Policy Studies March 2014 Retrieved 28 December 2014 Jahan Sarwat 28 March 2012 Inflation Targeting Holding the Line IMF Retrieved 18 January 2016 Roger Scott March 2010 Inflation Targeting Turns 20 Finance amp Development 47 1 Retrieved 18 January 2016 Speech Talk by Governor 4 August 1993 Leiderman Leonardo 1 May 2000 Monetary Policy Rules and Transmission Mechanisms Under Inflation Targeting in Israel PDF Documentos de Trabajo No Banco Central de Chile Retrieved 18 October 2009 Singer M 2015 From a Peg to Inflation Targeting CNB Experience presentation at the High level Seminar on the Benefits of Adopting a Structured Approach to Policy Analysis Rabat Morocco 21 May 2015 Inflation targeting www mnb hu Galindo Luis Miguel 13 May 2005 Alternatives to inflation targeting in Mexico PDF No Amherst CEDES Conference on Inflation targeting Buenos Aires Retrieved 18 October 2009 Marit Tronier Halvorsen 26 September 2013 Norges Bank holder fast ved inflasjonsmalet Dagens Naeringsliv in Norwegian Forsiden 2 February 2019 Inflation target www cb is Rocel C Felix 2 January 2002 BSP adopts inflation targeting starting this year The Philippine Star National Bank of Georgia www nbg gov ge Retrieved 3 January 2018 In historic shift Fed sets inflation target Reuters 26 January 2012 Retrieved 18 January 2016 Doubt Greets Bank of Japan s Easing Shift The Wall Street Journal 22 January 2013 Retrieved 18 January 2016 404 Bank Rossii PDF cbr ru a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a Cite uses generic title help Resheniya IR KZ Internet Қazakstan Ұlttyk Banki nationalbank kz Pro monetarnu politiku Nacionalnij bank Ukrayini Pro Osnovni zasadi groshovo kreditnoyi politiki na 2016 2020 roki India adopts inflation target of 4 for next five years under monetary policy framework Inflation Targeting Regime in Argentina Press conference External links editTable of Central Bank Inflation Targets Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Inflation targeting amp oldid 1184360562, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.