fbpx
Wikipedia

Market concentration

In economics, market concentration is a function of the number of firms and their respective shares of the total production (alternatively, total capacity or total reserves) in a market.[1] Market concentration is the portion of a given market's market share that is held by a small number of businesses. To ascertain whether an industry[2] is competitive or not, it is employed in antitrust law[3] and economic regulation. When market concentration is high, it indicates that a few firms dominate the market and oligopoly[4] or monopolistic competition is likely to exist. In most cases, high market concentration produces undesirable consequences such as reduced competition and higher prices.[5]

The market concentration ratio measures the concentration of the top firms in the market, this can be through various metrics such as sales, employment numbers, active users or other relevant indicators.[1] In theory and in practice, market concentration is closely associated with market competitiveness, and therefore is important to various antitrust agencies when considering proposed mergers and other regulatory issues.[6] Market concentration is important in determining firm market power in setting prices and quantities.

Market concentration is affected through various forces, including barriers to entry and existing competition. Market concentration ratios also allows users to more accurately determine the type of market structure they are observing, from a perfect competitive, to a monopolistic, monopoly or oligopolistic market structure.[7]

Market concentration is related to industrial concentration, which concerns the distribution of production within an industry, as opposed to a market. In industrial organization, market concentration may be used as a measure of competition, theorized to be positively related to the rate of profit in the industry, for example in the work of Joe S. Bain.[8]

An alternative economic interpretation is that market concentration is a criterion that can be used to rank order various distributions of firms' shares of the total production (alternatively, total capacity or total reserves) in a market.

Factors affecting market concentration edit

The 2020 Australian Telecommunications firms market share: an example of a highly concentrated market with an estimated HHI of 3034.

  Telstra (37%)
  Optus (30%)
  Vodafone (27%)
  Other (6%)

There are various factors that affect the concentration of specific markets which include; barriers to entry(high start-up costs, high economies of scale, brand loyalty), industry size and age, product differentiation and current advertising levels. There are also firm specific factors affecting market concentration, including: research and development levels, and the human capital requirements.[9]

Although fewer competitors doesn't always indicate high market concentration, it can be a strong indicator of the market structure and power allocation.

Metrics edit

After determining the relevant market and firms, through defining the product and geographical parameters, various metrics can be employed to determine the market concentration. This can be quantified using the SSNIP test.

A simple measure of market concentration is to calculate 1/N where N is the number of firms in the market. A result of 1 would indicate a pure monopoly, and will decrease with the number of active firms in the market, and nonincreasing in the degree of symmetry between them.[clarification needed] This measure of concentration ignores the dispersion among the firms' shares. This measure is practically useful only if a sample of firms' market shares is believed to be random, rather than determined by the firms' inherent characteristics.

Any criterion that can be used to compare or rank distributions (e.g. probability distribution, frequency distribution or size distribution) can be used as a market concentration criterion. Examples are stochastic dominance and Gini coefficient.

Herfindahl–Hirschman Index edit

The Herfindahl–Hirschman Index (HHI) (the most commonly used market concentration) is added portion of market attentiveness. It is derived by adding the squares of all the market participants[10] market shares. A higher HHI indicates a higher level of market concentration. A market concentration level of less than 1000 is typically seen as low, whilst one of more than 1500 is regarded as excessive.

 

Where   is the market share of firm i, conventionally expressed as a percentage,[11] and N is the number of firms in the relevant market.

If market shares are expressed as decimals, an HHI of 0 represents a perfectly competitive industry while an HHI index of 1 represents a monopolised industry. Regardless whether the decimal or percentage HHI is used, a higher HHI indicates higher concentration within a market.[12]

Section 1 of the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission's Horizontal Merger Guidelines is entitled "Market Definition, Measurement and Concentration" and states that the Herfindahl index is the measure of concentration that these Guidelines will use.[13]

 
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index

https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=jMJCLwBJYnQ

Concentration ratio edit

The concentration ratio (CR) is a measure of how concentrated a market is. By dividing the overall market share by the sum of the market shares of the largest enterprises, it is calculated. It can be used to assess the market's strength over both the short and long haul. Generally speaking, a CR of less than 40% and a CR of more than 60% are regarded as modest and high levels of market concentration, respectively.Another common measure is the concentration tio (CR).[14] This ratio simply measures the concentration of the largest firms in the form

 

where N is usually between 3 and 5.

Relationship between Market Structure and Market Concentration Metrics
Type of Market CR Range HHI Range
Monopoly 1 6000 - 10 000 (Depending on Region)
Oligopoly 0.5 - 1 2000 - 6000 (Depending on Region)
Competitive 0 - 0.5 0 - 2000 (Depending on Region)

Regulatory usage edit

Historical usage edit

Since the introduction of the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890, in response to growing monopolies and anti-competitive firms in the 1880s, antitrust agencies regularly use market concentration as an important metric to evaluate potential violations of competition laws.[15] Since the passing of the act, these metrics have also been used to evaluate potential mergers' effect on overall market competition and overall consumer welfare. The first major example of the Sherman Act being imposed on a company to prevent potential consumer abuse through excessive market concentration was in the 1911 court case of Standard Oil Co. of New Jersey v. United States where after determining Standard Oil was monopolising the petroleum industry, the court-ordered remedy was the breakup into 34 smaller companies.[16]

Modern usage edit

Modern regulatory bodies state that an increase in market concentration can inhibit innovation, and have detrimental effects on overall consumer welfare.

The United States Department of Justice determined that any merger that increases the HHI by more than 200 proposes a legitimate concern to antitrust laws and consumer welfare .[17] Therefore, when considering potential mergers, especially in horizontal integration applications, antitrust agencies will consider the whether the increase in efficiency is worth the potential decrease in consumer welfare, through increased costs or reduction in quantity produced.[18]

Whereas the European Commission is unlikely to contest any horizontal integration, which post merger HHI is under 2000 (except in special circumstances).[19]

Modern examples of market concentration being utilised to protect consumer welfare include:

  • 2014 Attempted purchase of Time Warner Cable by Comcast, was abandoned after the US DOJ threatened to file an antitrust lawsuit, citing that the HHI of the national television industry would increase by 639 points to a HHI of 2454, and feared this merger would lead to increased prices for consumers.[20]
  • Halliburton and Baker Hughes (at the time the 2nd and 3rd largest oilfield services companies, respectively) attempted 2014 merger was blocked by the US DOJ, after fears that the merger would increase costs for oil companies in 23 separate product markets, and therefore would stiffen innovation in the oil sector.[21]
  • General Electric's attempted acquisition of Honeywell in 2001, was approved in the United States, however the condition's that European Commission enforced for the approval were too impactful for General Electric, and was abandoned.[22] This is an example on how different regulatory bodies view mergers.

Motivation for firms edit

The relationship between market concentration and profitability can be divided into two arguments: greater market concentration increases the likelihood of collusion between firms which, resulting in higher pricing. In contrast, market concentration occurs as a result of the efficiency obtained in the course of being a large firm, which is more profitable in comparison to smaller firms and their lack of efficiency.[23]

Collusion edit

There are game theoretic models of market interaction (e.g. among oligopolists) that predict that an increase in market concentration will result in higher prices and lower consumer welfare even when collusion in the sense of cartelization (i.e. explicit collusion) is absent. Examples are Cournot oligopoly, and Bertrand oligopoly for differentiated products. Bain's (1956) original concern with market concentration was based on an intuitive relationship between high concentration and collusion which led to Bain's finding that firms in concentrated markets should be earning supra-competitive profits.[8][24] Collins and Preston (1969) shared a similar view to Bain with focus on the reduced competitive impact of smaller firms upon larger firms.[25] Demsetz held an alternative view where he found a positive relationship between the margins of specifically the largest firms within a concentrated industry and collusion as to pricing.[26]

Although theoretical models predict a strong correlation between market concentration and collusion, there is little empirical evidence linking market concentration to the level of collusion in an industry.[27] In the scenario of a merger, some studies have also shown that the asymmetric market structure produced by a merger will negatively affect collusion despite the increased concentration of the market that occurs post-merger.[28]

Efficiency edit

As an economic tool market concentration is useful because it reflects the degree of competition in the market. Understanding the market concentration is important for firms when deciding their marketing strategy. As well, empirical evidence shows that there exists an inverse relationship between market concentration and efficiency, such that firms display an increase in efficiency when their relevant market concentration decreases.[29] The above positions of Bain (1956) as well as Collins and Preston (1969) are not only supportive of collusion but also of the efficiency-profitability hypothesis: profits are higher for bigger firms within a greater concentrated market as this concentration signifies greater efficiency through mass production.[30] In particular, economies of scale was the greatest kind of efficiency that large firms could achieve in influencing their costs, granting them greater market share. Notably however, Rosenbaum (1994) observed that most studies assumed the relationship between actual market share and observed profitability by following the implication that large firms hold greater market share due to their efficiency, demonstrating that the relationship between these efficiency and market share is not clearly defined.[23]

Industry effects edit

Implications of market concentration

A high level of market concentration can lead to a decrease in competition[31] and increased market power for the dominant firms. This might lead to greater costs, less quality, fewer options, and less innovation. Thus, consumers and society may be negatively impacted by large levels of market concentration.

Innovation edit

Schumpeter (1950) first recognised the relationship between market concentration and innovation in that a higher concentrated market would facilitate innovation. He reasoned that firms with the greatest market share have the greatest opportunity to benefit from their innovations, particularly through investment into R&D.[32] This can be contrasted with the position taken by Arrow (1962) that a greater market concentration will decrease incentive to innovate because a firm within a monopoly or monopolistic market would have already reached profit levels that greatly exceed costs.[33]

In practice, there are complications in observing the direct correlation between market concentration and its effect on. In collecting empirical evidence, issues have also arisen as to how innovation, a firm's control and gaps between R&D and firm size are measured. There has also been a lack of consensus. For example, a negative correlation was established by Connelly and Hirschey (1984) who explained that the correlation evidenced a decreased expenditure on R&D by oligopolistic firms to benefit from greater monopolised profits. However, Blundell et al. observed a positive correlation by tallying the patents lodged by firms. This general observation was also shared by Aghion et al. in 2005.[32]

Schumpeter also failed to distinguish between the different technologies that contribute to innovation and did not properly define “creative destruction”. Petit and Teece (2021) argued that technological opportunities, a variable which Schumpeter and Arrow did not include during their time, would be included in this definition as it enables new entrants to make a “breakthrough” into the industry.[33]

Research presented by Aghion et al. (2005) suggested an inverted U-shape model that represents the relationship between market concentration and innovation. Delbono and Lambertini modelled empirical evidence onto a graph and found that the pattern demonstrated by the data supported the existence of a U-shaped relationship between these two variables.[34]

Regulation of market concentration

The existence of economic regulations like the Competition Act and antitrust laws like the Sherman Act is due to the necessity of maintaining market competition in order to avoid the formation of monopolies. These laws typically require firms to report their market share and limit the degree of market concentration that is allowed. In some cases, antitrust laws may require the breakup of firms or the establishment of “firewalls” that prevent the potential abuse of power.

Market concentration reveals a market's degree of concentration. It is employed to ascertain the level of industrial competition. A high degree of market concentration is typically undesirable since it might result in less competition and more power for the leading enterprises on the market. Antitrust laws and other economic regulations safeguard market competition and the avoidance of monopolies.

Alternative metrics edit

Although, not as common as the Herfindahl–Hirschman Index or Concentration Ratio metrics, various alternative measures of market concentration can also be used.

(a) The U Index (Davies, 1980):

  where   is an accepted measure of inequality (in practice the coefficient of variation is suggested),   is a constant or a parameter (to be estimated empirically) and N is the number of firms. Davies (1979) suggests that a concentration index should in general depend on both N and the inequality of firms' shares.
The "number of effective competitors" is the inverse of the Herfindahl index.
Terrence Kavyu Muthoka defines distribution just as functionals in the Swartz space which is the space of functions with compact support and with all derivatives existing. The Media:Dirac_Distribution or the Dirac function is a good example.

(b) The Linda index (1976)

 
where Qi is the ratio between the average share of the first   firms and the average share of the remaining   firms and   is the concentration coefficient for the first   firms. Although it doesn't capture the peripheral firms like the HHI formula, it works to capture the "core" of the market, and masure the degree of inequality between the size variable accounted for by various sib-samples of firms. This index, does assume pre-calculation on the users' behalf to determine the relevant value of  [35] However, there is little empirical evidence of regulatory usage of the Linda Index.

(c) Comprehensive concentration index (Horwath 1970):

 
Where s1 is the share of the largest firm. The index is similar to   except that greater weight is assigned to the share of the largest firm. When compared to the HHI index, it does present some advantages, such as giving more weight to the quantity of small firms, however the arbitrary choice to only include the absolute value of one firm has led to criticism over its accuracy and usefulness.[36]

(d) The Rosenbluth (1961) index (also Hall and Tideman, 1967):

  where symbol i indicates the firm's rank position.
The Rosenbluth index assigns more weight to smaller competitors when there are more firms present in the marketplace, and is sensitive to the amount of competitors in the market, even if there is a small amount of large firms dominating. Its coefficients and ranking are similar to results produced through the use of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index.[36]

(e) The Gini coefficient (1912)

 
The Gini coefficient measures the difference between firms' sizes without including the number of firms operating in a market. This is known as a relative concentration measure and differs from absolute concentration measures (like the Rosenbluth index) which includes the number of firms and firms' distribution sizes. It is used in conjunction with the Lorenz curve. Originally, the Lorenz curve measured the inequality of income distributed with a population and ranked individuals from highest to lowest earnings.[37] Therefore, in this context the Gini coefficient is located between the 45° line representing an equal distribution of income and the Lorenz curve representing the actual distribution of income within the population.[38] In a market concentration context, the Lorenz curve can be plotted ranking firms' market shares from smallest to largest to simulate a concentration curve. The firms’ cumulative percentage shares would remain on the y axis and the cumulative percentage of sellers would remain on the x axis.   would the sum of weighted market share located in the area above the concentration curve. The Gini coefficient is 0 when the concentration curve aligns with the 45° line representing a single firm's market share, meaning the market is a monopoly.[37]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b "What is Market Concentration? Definition of Market Concentration, Market Concentration Meaning". The Economic Times. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  2. ^ "Industry", Wikipedia, 2023-01-23, retrieved 2023-04-24
  3. ^ "Competition law", Wikipedia, 2023-04-12, retrieved 2023-04-24
  4. ^ "Oligopoly", Wikipedia, 2023-04-24, retrieved 2023-04-24
  5. ^ Turner, Scott F.; Mitchell, Will; Bettis, Richard A. (2010). "Responding to Rivals and Complements: How Market Concentration Shapes Generational Product Innovation Strategy". Organization Science. 21 (4): 856. doi:10.1287/orsc.1090.0486. hdl:10161/4440.
  6. ^ "What We Can Learn from Merger Deals That Never Happened". Harvard Business Review. 2016-06-21. ISSN 0017-8012. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  7. ^ "Market structure", Wikipedia, 2023-04-23, retrieved 2023-04-24
  8. ^ a b Bain, Joe, S (1951). "Relation of Profit Rate to Industry Concentration: American Manufacturing, 1936-1940". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 65 (3): 293–324. doi:10.2307/1882217. JSTOR 1882217 – via JSTOR.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  9. ^ Janashvili '02, David (2002-04-26). "Market Concentration: The Effects of Technology". Honors Projects.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  10. ^ "Market participant", Wikipedia, 2021-03-29, retrieved 2023-04-24
  11. ^ "Herfindahl-Hirschman Index - United States Department of Justice". US Department of Justice. Retrieved 2022-11-09.
  12. ^ Evans, Anthony J. (2014). Markets for Managers: A Managerial Economics Primer. John Wiley & Sons Ltd. p. 69.
  13. ^ "Herfindahl-Hirschman Index". www.justice.gov. 2015-06-25. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  14. ^ J. Gregory Sidak, Evaluating Market Power Using Competitive Benchmark Prices Instead of the Hirschman-Herfindahl Index, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 387, 387-388 (2007).
  15. ^ Brock, James W.; Obst, Norman P. (2009-03-01). "Market Concentration, Economic Welfare, and Antitrust Policy". Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade. 9 (1): 65–75. doi:10.1007/s10842-007-0026-6. ISSN 1573-7012. S2CID 154631137.
  16. ^ "Standard Oil | History, Monopoly, & Breakup". Encyclopædia Britannica. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  17. ^ "HERFINDAHL-HIRSCHMAN INDEX". The United States Department of Justice. 25 June 2015.
  18. ^ Brock, James W.; Obst, Norman P. (2007-10-03). "Market Concentration, Economic Welfare, and Antitrust Policy". Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade. 9 (1): 65–75. doi:10.1007/s10842-007-0026-6. ISSN 1566-1679. S2CID 154631137.
  19. ^ "EUR-Lex - 52004XC0205(02) - EN". Official Journal C 031, 05/02/2004, p. 0005-0018. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  20. ^ Fernholz, Tim. "Why the Time Warner-Comcast merger isn't going to happen—at least the way it looks today". Quartz. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  21. ^ "Halliburton and Baker Hughes Abandon Anticompetitive Merger". www.justice.gov. 2017-03-15. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  22. ^ "U.S./EU: Analysis -- What Killed The GE-Honeywell Merger?". RadioFreeEurope/RadioLiberty. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  23. ^ a b Rosenbaum, David I. (1994). "Efficiency v. Collusion: Evidence Cast in Cement". Review of Industrial Organization. 9 (4): 379–392. doi:10.1007/BF01029512. JSTOR 41798521. S2CID 153620070.
  24. ^ Schmalensee, Richard (1987). "Inter-Industry Studies of Structure and Performance". Handbook of Industrial Organization. (Working Paper No. 1874-87).
  25. ^ Collins, Norman R.; Preston, Lee E. (1969). "Price-Cost Margins and Industry Structure". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 51 (3): 271–286. doi:10.2307/1926562. JSTOR 1926562.
  26. ^ Demsetz, Harold (1973). "Industry Structure, Market Rivalry, and Public Policy". Journal of Law and Economics. 16 (1): 1–9. doi:10.1086/466752. JSTOR 724822. S2CID 154506488.
  27. ^ Salinger, Michael (1990). "The Concentration-Margins Relationship Reconsidered" (PDF). Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Microeconomics. 1990: 287–335. doi:10.2307/2534784. JSTOR 2534784.
  28. ^ Fonseca, Miguel A.; Normann, Hans-Theo (2008). "Mergers, Asymmetries and Collusion: Experimental Evidence". The Economic Journal. 118 (527): 387–400. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02126.x. JSTOR 20108803. S2CID 154378955.
  29. ^ "Highly concentrated markets are bad for consumers and bad for investors". MoneyWeek. Retrieved 2021-04-28.
  30. ^ Martin, Stephen (1988). "Market Power and/or Efficiency?". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 70 (2): 331–335. doi:10.2307/1928318. JSTOR 1928318.
  31. ^ "Competition", Wikipedia, 2023-03-15, retrieved 2023-04-24
  32. ^ a b Sonenshine, Ralph M. (2010). "The Stock Market's Valuation of R&D and Market Concentration in Horizontal Mergers". Review of Industrial Organization. 37 (2): 119–140. doi:10.1007/s11151-010-9262-8. JSTOR 41799483. S2CID 155085616.
  33. ^ a b Petit, Nicolas; Teece, David J. (2021). "Original Article Innovating Big Tech firms and competition policy: favoring dynamic over static competition". Industrial and Corporate Change. 30 (1168–1198). doi:10.1093/icc/dtab049. hdl:1814/74432.
  34. ^ Delbono, Flavio; Lambertini, Luca (2022). "Innovation and product market concentration: Schumpeter, arrow, and the inverted U-shape curve". Oxford Economic Papers. 74 (1): 297–311. doi:10.1093/oep/gpaa044. hdl:11585/831079.
  35. ^ Bukvić, Rajko; Pavlović, Radica; Gajić, Аlеksаndаr M. (2014). "Possibilities of Application of the Index Concentration of Linda in Small Economy: Example of Serbian Food Industries". mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de. Retrieved 2021-04-27.
  36. ^ a b Romualdas, Stasys, Ginevičius, Čirba (2009). "Additive measurement of Market Concentration". Journal of Business Economics and Management. 10 (3): 191–198. doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2009.10.191-198.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  37. ^ a b du Pisanie, Johann (2013). "Concentration Measures as an element in testing the structure-conduct-performance paradigm" (PDF). Economic Research Southern Africa. (Working Papers No. 345).
  38. ^ Palan, Nicole (2010). "Measurement of Specialization # The Choice of Indices" (PDF). Research Centre International Economics, Vienna. (FIW Working Paper No. 62).
  • Bain, J. (1956). Barriers to New Competition. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard Univ. Press.
  • Curry, B. and K. D. George (1983). "Industrial concentration: A survey" Jour. of Indust. Econ. 31(3): 203–55
  • Shughart II, William F. (2008). "Industrial Concentration". In David R. Henderson (ed.). Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (2nd ed.). Indianapolis: Library of Economics and Liberty. ISBN 978-0865976658. OCLC 237794267.
  • Tirole, J. (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
  • Weiss, L. W. (1989). Concentration and price. Cambridge, Massachusetts : MIT Press.

External links edit

  • Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines

market, concentration, economics, market, concentration, function, number, firms, their, respective, shares, total, production, alternatively, total, capacity, total, reserves, market, portion, given, market, market, share, that, held, small, number, businesse. In economics market concentration is a function of the number of firms and their respective shares of the total production alternatively total capacity or total reserves in a market 1 Market concentration is the portion of a given market s market share that is held by a small number of businesses To ascertain whether an industry 2 is competitive or not it is employed in antitrust law 3 and economic regulation When market concentration is high it indicates that a few firms dominate the market and oligopoly 4 or monopolistic competition is likely to exist In most cases high market concentration produces undesirable consequences such as reduced competition and higher prices 5 The market concentration ratio measures the concentration of the top firms in the market this can be through various metrics such as sales employment numbers active users or other relevant indicators 1 In theory and in practice market concentration is closely associated with market competitiveness and therefore is important to various antitrust agencies when considering proposed mergers and other regulatory issues 6 Market concentration is important in determining firm market power in setting prices and quantities Market concentration is affected through various forces including barriers to entry and existing competition Market concentration ratios also allows users to more accurately determine the type of market structure they are observing from a perfect competitive to a monopolistic monopoly or oligopolistic market structure 7 Market concentration is related to industrial concentration which concerns the distribution of production within an industry as opposed to a market In industrial organization market concentration may be used as a measure of competition theorized to be positively related to the rate of profit in the industry for example in the work of Joe S Bain 8 An alternative economic interpretation is that market concentration is a criterion that can be used to rank order various distributions of firms shares of the total production alternatively total capacity or total reserves in a market Contents 1 Factors affecting market concentration 2 Metrics 2 1 Herfindahl Hirschman Index 2 2 Concentration ratio 3 Regulatory usage 3 1 Historical usage 3 2 Modern usage 4 Motivation for firms 4 1 Collusion 4 2 Efficiency 5 Industry effects 5 1 Innovation 6 Alternative metrics 7 See also 8 References 9 External linksFactors affecting market concentration editThe 2020 Australian Telecommunications firms market share an example of a highly concentrated market with an estimated HHI of 3034 Telstra 37 Optus 30 Vodafone 27 Other 6 There are various factors that affect the concentration of specific markets which include barriers to entry high start up costs high economies of scale brand loyalty industry size and age product differentiation and current advertising levels There are also firm specific factors affecting market concentration including research and development levels and the human capital requirements 9 Although fewer competitors doesn t always indicate high market concentration it can be a strong indicator of the market structure and power allocation Metrics editAfter determining the relevant market and firms through defining the product and geographical parameters various metrics can be employed to determine the market concentration This can be quantified using the SSNIP test A simple measure of market concentration is to calculate 1 N where N is the number of firms in the market A result of 1 would indicate a pure monopoly and will decrease with the number of active firms in the market and nonincreasing in the degree of symmetry between them clarification needed This measure of concentration ignores the dispersion among the firms shares This measure is practically useful only if a sample of firms market shares is believed to be random rather than determined by the firms inherent characteristics Any criterion that can be used to compare or rank distributions e g probability distribution frequency distribution or size distribution can be used as a market concentration criterion Examples are stochastic dominance and Gini coefficient Herfindahl Hirschman Index edit The Herfindahl Hirschman Index HHI the most commonly used market concentration is added portion of market attentiveness It is derived by adding the squares of all the market participants 10 market shares A higher HHI indicates a higher level of market concentration A market concentration level of less than 1000 is typically seen as low whilst one of more than 1500 is regarded as excessive H i 1 N s i 2 displaystyle H sum i 1 N s i 2 nbsp Where s i displaystyle s i nbsp is the market share of firm i conventionally expressed as a percentage 11 and N is the number of firms in the relevant market If market shares are expressed as decimals an HHI of 0 represents a perfectly competitive industry while an HHI index of 1 represents a monopolised industry Regardless whether the decimal or percentage HHI is used a higher HHI indicates higher concentration within a market 12 Section 1 of the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission s Horizontal Merger Guidelines is entitled Market Definition Measurement and Concentration and states that the Herfindahl index is the measure of concentration that these Guidelines will use 13 nbsp Herfindahl Hirschman Indexhttps www youtube com watch v jMJCLwBJYnQ Concentration ratio edit The concentration ratio CR is a measure of how concentrated a market is By dividing the overall market share by the sum of the market shares of the largest enterprises it is calculated It can be used to assess the market s strength over both the short and long haul Generally speaking a CR of less than 40 and a CR of more than 60 are regarded as modest and high levels of market concentration respectively Another common measure is the concentration tio CR 14 This ratio simply measures the concentration of the largest firms in the formC R n C 1 C 2 C n displaystyle CR n C 1 C 2 C n nbsp where N is usually between 3 and 5 Relationship between Market Structure and Market Concentration Metrics Type of Market CR Range HHI RangeMonopoly 1 6000 10 000 Depending on Region Oligopoly 0 5 1 2000 6000 Depending on Region Competitive 0 0 5 0 2000 Depending on Region Regulatory usage editHistorical usage edit Since the introduction of the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 in response to growing monopolies and anti competitive firms in the 1880s antitrust agencies regularly use market concentration as an important metric to evaluate potential violations of competition laws 15 Since the passing of the act these metrics have also been used to evaluate potential mergers effect on overall market competition and overall consumer welfare The first major example of the Sherman Act being imposed on a company to prevent potential consumer abuse through excessive market concentration was in the 1911 court case of Standard Oil Co of New Jersey v United States where after determining Standard Oil was monopolising the petroleum industry the court ordered remedy was the breakup into 34 smaller companies 16 Modern usage edit Modern regulatory bodies state that an increase in market concentration can inhibit innovation and have detrimental effects on overall consumer welfare The United States Department of Justice determined that any merger that increases the HHI by more than 200 proposes a legitimate concern to antitrust laws and consumer welfare 17 Therefore when considering potential mergers especially in horizontal integration applications antitrust agencies will consider the whether the increase in efficiency is worth the potential decrease in consumer welfare through increased costs or reduction in quantity produced 18 Whereas the European Commission is unlikely to contest any horizontal integration which post merger HHI is under 2000 except in special circumstances 19 Modern examples of market concentration being utilised to protect consumer welfare include 2014 Attempted purchase of Time Warner Cable by Comcast was abandoned after the US DOJ threatened to file an antitrust lawsuit citing that the HHI of the national television industry would increase by 639 points to a HHI of 2454 and feared this merger would lead to increased prices for consumers 20 Halliburton and Baker Hughes at the time the 2nd and 3rd largest oilfield services companies respectively attempted 2014 merger was blocked by the US DOJ after fears that the merger would increase costs for oil companies in 23 separate product markets and therefore would stiffen innovation in the oil sector 21 General Electric s attempted acquisition of Honeywell in 2001 was approved in the United States however the condition s that European Commission enforced for the approval were too impactful for General Electric and was abandoned 22 This is an example on how different regulatory bodies view mergers Motivation for firms editThe relationship between market concentration and profitability can be divided into two arguments greater market concentration increases the likelihood of collusion between firms which resulting in higher pricing In contrast market concentration occurs as a result of the efficiency obtained in the course of being a large firm which is more profitable in comparison to smaller firms and their lack of efficiency 23 Collusion edit There are game theoretic models of market interaction e g among oligopolists that predict that an increase in market concentration will result in higher prices and lower consumer welfare even when collusion in the sense of cartelization i e explicit collusion is absent Examples are Cournot oligopoly and Bertrand oligopoly for differentiated products Bain s 1956 original concern with market concentration was based on an intuitive relationship between high concentration and collusion which led to Bain s finding that firms in concentrated markets should be earning supra competitive profits 8 24 Collins and Preston 1969 shared a similar view to Bain with focus on the reduced competitive impact of smaller firms upon larger firms 25 Demsetz held an alternative view where he found a positive relationship between the margins of specifically the largest firms within a concentrated industry and collusion as to pricing 26 Although theoretical models predict a strong correlation between market concentration and collusion there is little empirical evidence linking market concentration to the level of collusion in an industry 27 In the scenario of a merger some studies have also shown that the asymmetric market structure produced by a merger will negatively affect collusion despite the increased concentration of the market that occurs post merger 28 Efficiency edit As an economic tool market concentration is useful because it reflects the degree of competition in the market Understanding the market concentration is important for firms when deciding their marketing strategy As well empirical evidence shows that there exists an inverse relationship between market concentration and efficiency such that firms display an increase in efficiency when their relevant market concentration decreases 29 The above positions of Bain 1956 as well as Collins and Preston 1969 are not only supportive of collusion but also of the efficiency profitability hypothesis profits are higher for bigger firms within a greater concentrated market as this concentration signifies greater efficiency through mass production 30 In particular economies of scale was the greatest kind of efficiency that large firms could achieve in influencing their costs granting them greater market share Notably however Rosenbaum 1994 observed that most studies assumed the relationship between actual market share and observed profitability by following the implication that large firms hold greater market share due to their efficiency demonstrating that the relationship between these efficiency and market share is not clearly defined 23 Industry effects editImplications of market concentrationA high level of market concentration can lead to a decrease in competition 31 and increased market power for the dominant firms This might lead to greater costs less quality fewer options and less innovation Thus consumers and society may be negatively impacted by large levels of market concentration Innovation edit Schumpeter 1950 first recognised the relationship between market concentration and innovation in that a higher concentrated market would facilitate innovation He reasoned that firms with the greatest market share have the greatest opportunity to benefit from their innovations particularly through investment into R amp D 32 This can be contrasted with the position taken by Arrow 1962 that a greater market concentration will decrease incentive to innovate because a firm within a monopoly or monopolistic market would have already reached profit levels that greatly exceed costs 33 In practice there are complications in observing the direct correlation between market concentration and its effect on In collecting empirical evidence issues have also arisen as to how innovation a firm s control and gaps between R amp D and firm size are measured There has also been a lack of consensus For example a negative correlation was established by Connelly and Hirschey 1984 who explained that the correlation evidenced a decreased expenditure on R amp D by oligopolistic firms to benefit from greater monopolised profits However Blundell et al observed a positive correlation by tallying the patents lodged by firms This general observation was also shared by Aghion et al in 2005 32 Schumpeter also failed to distinguish between the different technologies that contribute to innovation and did not properly define creative destruction Petit and Teece 2021 argued that technological opportunities a variable which Schumpeter and Arrow did not include during their time would be included in this definition as it enables new entrants to make a breakthrough into the industry 33 Research presented by Aghion et al 2005 suggested an inverted U shape model that represents the relationship between market concentration and innovation Delbono and Lambertini modelled empirical evidence onto a graph and found that the pattern demonstrated by the data supported the existence of a U shaped relationship between these two variables 34 Regulation of market concentrationThe existence of economic regulations like the Competition Act and antitrust laws like the Sherman Act is due to the necessity of maintaining market competition in order to avoid the formation of monopolies These laws typically require firms to report their market share and limit the degree of market concentration that is allowed In some cases antitrust laws may require the breakup of firms or the establishment of firewalls that prevent the potential abuse of power Market concentration reveals a market s degree of concentration It is employed to ascertain the level of industrial competition A high degree of market concentration is typically undesirable since it might result in less competition and more power for the leading enterprises on the market Antitrust laws and other economic regulations safeguard market competition and the avoidance of monopolies Alternative metrics editAlthough not as common as the Herfindahl Hirschman Index or Concentration Ratio metrics various alternative measures of market concentration can also be used a The U Index Davies 1980 U I a N 1 displaystyle U I a N 1 nbsp where I displaystyle I nbsp is an accepted measure of inequality in practice the coefficient of variation is suggested a displaystyle a nbsp is a constant or a parameter to be estimated empirically and N is the number of firms Davies 1979 suggests that a concentration index should in general depend on both N and the inequality of firms shares The number of effective competitors is the inverse of the Herfindahl index Terrence Kavyu Muthoka defines distribution just as functionals in the Swartz space which is the space of functions with compact support and with all derivatives existing The Media Dirac Distribution or the Dirac function is a good example b The Linda index 1976 L 1 N N 1 i 1 N 1 Q i n i i C R i C R n C R i displaystyle L frac 1 N N 1 sum i 1 N 1 Q i left frac n i i right left vert frac CR i CR n CR i right vert nbsp where Qi is the ratio between the average share of the first i displaystyle i nbsp firms and the average share of the remaining N i displaystyle N i nbsp firms and C R i displaystyle CR i nbsp is the concentration coefficient for the first i displaystyle i nbsp firms Although it doesn t capture the peripheral firms like the HHI formula it works to capture the core of the market and masure the degree of inequality between the size variable accounted for by various sib samples of firms This index does assume pre calculation on the users behalf to determine the relevant value of C R i displaystyle CR i nbsp 35 However there is little empirical evidence of regulatory usage of the Linda Index c Comprehensive concentration index Horwath 1970 C C I s 1 i 2 N s i 2 2 s i displaystyle CCI s 1 sum i 2 N s i 2 2 s i nbsp Where s1 is the share of the largest firm The index is similar to 2 H s i 3 displaystyle 2 text H sum s i 3 nbsp except that greater weight is assigned to the share of the largest firm When compared to the HHI index it does present some advantages such as giving more weight to the quantity of small firms however the arbitrary choice to only include the absolute value of one firm has led to criticism over its accuracy and usefulness 36 d The Rosenbluth 1961 index also Hall and Tideman 1967 R 1 2 i s i 1 displaystyle R frac 1 2 sum is i 1 nbsp where symbol i indicates the firm s rank position The Rosenbluth index assigns more weight to smaller competitors when there are more firms present in the marketplace and is sensitive to the amount of competitors in the market even if there is a small amount of large firms dominating Its coefficients and ranking are similar to results produced through the use of the Herfindahl Hirschman Index 36 e The Gini coefficient 1912 G 1 i 1 N S i 2 i 1 N displaystyle G 1 sum i 1 N S i frac 2i 1 N nbsp The Gini coefficient measures the difference between firms sizes without including the number of firms operating in a market This is known as a relative concentration measure and differs from absolute concentration measures like the Rosenbluth index which includes the number of firms and firms distribution sizes It is used in conjunction with the Lorenz curve Originally the Lorenz curve measured the inequality of income distributed with a population and ranked individuals from highest to lowest earnings 37 Therefore in this context the Gini coefficient is located between the 45 line representing an equal distribution of income and the Lorenz curve representing the actual distribution of income within the population 38 In a market concentration context the Lorenz curve can be plotted ranking firms market shares from smallest to largest to simulate a concentration curve The firms cumulative percentage shares would remain on the y axis and the cumulative percentage of sellers would remain on the x axis 2 i 1 N displaystyle frac 2i 1 N nbsp would the sum of weighted market share located in the area above the concentration curve The Gini coefficient is 0 when the concentration curve aligns with the 45 line representing a single firm s market share meaning the market is a monopoly 37 See also editConcentration ratio Dominance economics Gini coefficient Herfindahl index Horizontal Merger Guidelines Lorenz curve Inequality of wealth Market failure Monopoly Probability distribution Stochastic dominance Relative market shareReferences edit a b What is Market Concentration Definition of Market Concentration Market Concentration Meaning The Economic Times Retrieved 2021 04 24 Industry Wikipedia 2023 01 23 retrieved 2023 04 24 Competition law Wikipedia 2023 04 12 retrieved 2023 04 24 Oligopoly Wikipedia 2023 04 24 retrieved 2023 04 24 Turner Scott F Mitchell Will Bettis Richard A 2010 Responding to Rivals and Complements How Market Concentration Shapes Generational Product Innovation Strategy Organization Science 21 4 856 doi 10 1287 orsc 1090 0486 hdl 10161 4440 What We Can Learn from Merger Deals That Never Happened Harvard Business Review 2016 06 21 ISSN 0017 8012 Retrieved 2021 04 24 Market structure Wikipedia 2023 04 23 retrieved 2023 04 24 a b Bain Joe S 1951 Relation of Profit Rate to Industry Concentration American Manufacturing 1936 1940 The Quarterly Journal of Economics 65 3 293 324 doi 10 2307 1882217 JSTOR 1882217 via JSTOR a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Janashvili 02 David 2002 04 26 Market Concentration The Effects of Technology Honors Projects a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a CS1 maint numeric names authors list link Market participant Wikipedia 2021 03 29 retrieved 2023 04 24 Herfindahl Hirschman Index United States Department of Justice US Department of Justice Retrieved 2022 11 09 Evans Anthony J 2014 Markets for Managers A Managerial Economics Primer John Wiley amp Sons Ltd p 69 Herfindahl Hirschman Index www justice gov 2015 06 25 Retrieved 2021 04 24 J Gregory Sidak Evaluating Market Power Using Competitive Benchmark Prices Instead of the Hirschman Herfindahl Index 74 ANTITRUST L J 387 387 388 2007 Brock James W Obst Norman P 2009 03 01 Market Concentration Economic Welfare and Antitrust Policy Journal of Industry Competition and Trade 9 1 65 75 doi 10 1007 s10842 007 0026 6 ISSN 1573 7012 S2CID 154631137 Standard Oil History Monopoly amp Breakup Encyclopaedia Britannica Retrieved 2021 04 24 HERFINDAHL HIRSCHMAN INDEX The United States Department of Justice 25 June 2015 Brock James W Obst Norman P 2007 10 03 Market Concentration Economic Welfare and Antitrust Policy Journal of Industry Competition and Trade 9 1 65 75 doi 10 1007 s10842 007 0026 6 ISSN 1566 1679 S2CID 154631137 EUR Lex 52004XC0205 02 EN Official Journal C 031 05 02 2004 p 0005 0018 Retrieved 2021 04 24 Fernholz Tim Why the Time Warner Comcast merger isn t going to happen at least the way it looks today Quartz Retrieved 2021 04 24 Halliburton and Baker Hughes Abandon Anticompetitive Merger www justice gov 2017 03 15 Retrieved 2021 04 24 U S EU Analysis What Killed The GE Honeywell Merger RadioFreeEurope RadioLiberty Retrieved 2021 04 24 a b Rosenbaum David I 1994 Efficiency v Collusion Evidence Cast in Cement Review of Industrial Organization 9 4 379 392 doi 10 1007 BF01029512 JSTOR 41798521 S2CID 153620070 Schmalensee Richard 1987 Inter Industry Studies of Structure and Performance Handbook of Industrial Organization Working Paper No 1874 87 Collins Norman R Preston Lee E 1969 Price Cost Margins and Industry Structure The Review of Economics and Statistics 51 3 271 286 doi 10 2307 1926562 JSTOR 1926562 Demsetz Harold 1973 Industry Structure Market Rivalry and Public Policy Journal of Law and Economics 16 1 1 9 doi 10 1086 466752 JSTOR 724822 S2CID 154506488 Salinger Michael 1990 The Concentration Margins Relationship Reconsidered PDF Brookings Papers on Economic Activity Microeconomics 1990 287 335 doi 10 2307 2534784 JSTOR 2534784 Fonseca Miguel A Normann Hans Theo 2008 Mergers Asymmetries and Collusion Experimental Evidence The Economic Journal 118 527 387 400 doi 10 1111 j 1468 0297 2007 02126 x JSTOR 20108803 S2CID 154378955 Highly concentrated markets are bad for consumers and bad for investors MoneyWeek Retrieved 2021 04 28 Martin Stephen 1988 Market Power and or Efficiency The Review of Economics and Statistics 70 2 331 335 doi 10 2307 1928318 JSTOR 1928318 Competition Wikipedia 2023 03 15 retrieved 2023 04 24 a b Sonenshine Ralph M 2010 The Stock Market s Valuation of R amp D and Market Concentration in Horizontal Mergers Review of Industrial Organization 37 2 119 140 doi 10 1007 s11151 010 9262 8 JSTOR 41799483 S2CID 155085616 a b Petit Nicolas Teece David J 2021 Original Article Innovating Big Tech firms and competition policy favoring dynamic over static competition Industrial and Corporate Change 30 1168 1198 doi 10 1093 icc dtab049 hdl 1814 74432 Delbono Flavio Lambertini Luca 2022 Innovation and product market concentration Schumpeter arrow and the inverted U shape curve Oxford Economic Papers 74 1 297 311 doi 10 1093 oep gpaa044 hdl 11585 831079 Bukvic Rajko Pavlovic Radica Gajic Aleksandar M 2014 Possibilities of Application of the Index Concentration of Linda in Small Economy Example of Serbian Food Industries mpra ub uni muenchen de Retrieved 2021 04 27 a b Romualdas Stasys Ginevicius Cirba 2009 Additive measurement of Market Concentration Journal of Business Economics and Management 10 3 191 198 doi 10 3846 1611 1699 2009 10 191 198 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link a b du Pisanie Johann 2013 Concentration Measures as an element in testing the structure conduct performance paradigm PDF Economic Research Southern Africa Working Papers No 345 Palan Nicole 2010 Measurement of Specialization The Choice of Indices PDF Research Centre International Economics Vienna FIW Working Paper No 62 Bain J 1956 Barriers to New Competition Cambridge Massachusetts Harvard Univ Press Curry B and K D George 1983 Industrial concentration A survey Jour of Indust Econ 31 3 203 55 Shughart II William F 2008 Industrial Concentration In David R Henderson ed Concise Encyclopedia of Economics 2nd ed Indianapolis Library of Economics and Liberty ISBN 978 0865976658 OCLC 237794267 Tirole J 1988 The Theory of Industrial Organization Cambridge Massachusetts MIT Press Weiss L W 1989 Concentration and price Cambridge Massachusetts MIT Press External links editDepartment of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Market concentration amp oldid 1183960339, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.