fbpx
Wikipedia

History of debt relief

Debt relief, or debt forgiveness, has been practiced in many societies since antiquity. Periodic debt remission was institutionalised in the Ancient Near East and contributed to the stability of its societies. In ancient Greece and Rome the laws were more creditor-friendly and debt cancellation was one of the major demands of the poor, only occasionally implemented by the government. Medieval canon law contained provisions for the annulment of debts owed by borrowers in distress, which influenced modern personal bankruptcy law.

Ancient Near East edit

 
Urukagina's reform text mentions the cancelling of obligations of indentured families as part of his reforms

Debt relief existed in many societies of the Ancient Near East in the form of debt remission, whereby certain debts were declared void and the foreclosed property reverted to the original owners. Debts were often cancelled by a new ruler issuing a clean slate decree after assuming the throne or following a natural or man-made calamity. Usually only personal debt was cancelled, whereas debts incurred by merchants were unaffected.[1]

The periodical debt remissions played a large role in the Ancient Near East. They contributed to the stability of the society.[2] Most of the loans were taken by peasants to enable them to subsist until the next harvest, and often the land was pledged as collateral. If the borrower was unable to repay the loan the land passed to the lender, with the borrower himself becoming a bondsman.[3] The debt remissions checked the power of elites, who would otherwise amass great fortunes of land cultivated by serfs, and ensured that enough free labourers were available to serve in the army and for public work duties.[1]

The earliest known debt cancellation was proclaimed by Enmetena of Lagash c. 2400 BCE. Similar measures were enacted by later Sumerian, Babylonian and Assyrian rulers of Mesopotamia, where they were known as "freedom decrees" (ama-gi in Sumerian).[4] This same theme was found in an ancient bilingual Hittite-Hurrian text entitled "The Song of Debt Release".[5] In Ancient Egypt interest-bearing debt did not exist for most of its history. When it started spreading in the Late Period, the rulers of Egypt regulated it and a number of debt remissions are known to have occurred during the Ptolemaic era, including the one whose proclamation was inscribed on the Rosetta Stone.[6][7] Diodorus Siculus provides the following rationale for abolishing the debt bondage by pharaoh Bakenranef:[8]

"For it would be absurd... that a soldier, at the moment perhaps when he was setting forth to fight for his fatherland, should be haled to prison by his creditor for an unpaid loan, and that the greed of private citizens should in this way endanger the safety of all"

Debt forgiveness is mentioned in the Torah, in which God commanded the Israelites to forgive debts in certain cases at the end of Shmita, the last year of the seven-year agricultural cycle. Hebrew slaves were also set free either at the same time or at the end of the 49-year cycle, depending on interpretation. At the end of the longer cycle, during Jubilee year the land also reverted to its original owners. According to Michael Hudson, the Jubilee law likely appeared in response to a debt crisis and took debt cancellation from the hands of the rulers, making it periodical and automatic.[9] No contracts survive attesting to the compliance, or lack of it, with the Jubilee law.[10]

Due to the First Exile, the laws of debt remission were no longer applicable, due to most the fact most Jews were not living in the land of Israel, and the fact that the remission was tied to the restitution of ancestral land. Later Rabbis would decree that debts should continue to be remitted. Around the beginning of the 1st century CE Hillel established the prozbul loophole which enabled lenders to offer loans which could not be remitted, by redirecting the recipient of the repayment as the local Bet Din (court of law), which would then forward it to the original lender. Since the debt would be owed to a public institution instead of a private individual, it would not be remitted.[11] Hillel argued that otherwise the poor would not be able to get a loan in the year preceding the remission.[12][13]

Ancient Greece and Rome edit

 
The obverse of Hadrian's sestertius commemorating the cancellation of tax arrears shows the emperor burning tax records

In general the law in ancient Greece and Rome was more creditor-friendly and "harsh and unyielding" towards debtors.[14] Throughout antiquity the cancellation of debts, alongside land redistribution, was the main rallying cry of the poor.[15]

In response to a debt crisis in the 6th century BCE, the Athenians implemented a law of Solon providing for seisachtheia (σεισάχθεια), which cancelled all debts and retroactively annulled previous debts that had resulted in slavery and serfdom, freeing debt slaves and debt serfs.[16] According to Plutarch, interest-bearing debts were made illegal by the democratic government of Megara in the 6th century BCE while the creditors were forced to return the collected interest. This was treated as an extreme populist measure by Greek sources,[17] and historians are divided as regards the historicity of these events, considered to reflect later anti-democratic political thought.[18] The Spartan kings also implemented debt cancellations in their attempt to reform the state in the 3rd century BC.[19] The Roman equivalent was called novae tabulae.

In the Ancient Rome the debt bondage known as nexum was abolished in 313 BCE.[20] However even after that the debtors were still required to perform compulsory labour, and could be imprisoned following a court judgement.[14] Appian mentions an attempt by praetor Asellio to revive the old law prohibiting the taking of interest in 89 BC which led to his murder, presumably by the creditors.[21] Later, partial debt cancellations were enacted by Sulla (by 10%) and then by Lucius Cornelius Cinna and Lucius Valerius Flaccus (by three quarters) in order to stabilise the economy ruined by the civil war.[22][23] The Roman elites were firmly against debt relief, with Cicero denouncing it as an attack on property and the propertied classes.[24]

The predecessors of the bankruptcy law emerged in early Imperial Rome. Augustus instituted cessio bonorum, allowing debtors to voluntarily surrender their property to creditors and thereby avoid personal arrest and loss of legal standing (infamia).[25]

While Rome never enacted complete debt cancellation, several emperors wrote off tax arrears, that is, debts to the state treasury.[26]

China edit

The indebtedness of rural population was a constant government concern from the days of the Han dynasty. A variety of means were employed to deal with it, including full or partial debt relief. Often those loans whose repaid interest exceeded the principal were annulled.[27] The government accused the Buddhist monasteries (which had become major lenders to the peasantry by the 6th century CE) of issuing high-interest loans. During the purge of Buddhist monasteries in 845, more than 150,000 temple serfs were released from bondage, according to the official reports.[28]

Medieval Europe edit

Medieval canon law built upon Roman law and extensively discussed provisions to mitigate the harshness of debtors' punishments. Most commentators allowed for a debtor to be discharged and make a fresh start, after ceding to his creditors all his goods (or possibly all his goods except some bare necessities). These provisions later influenced English bankruptcy law.[25]

Modern period edit

In the modern period debt discharge typically occurs through the process of bankruptcy. One of the first countries to establish personal bankruptcy (rather than company bankruptcy) was the United Kingdom, where the Bankruptcy Act 1869 allowed all people to file for bankruptcy. Currently, the benchmark for personal bankruptcy legislation is the US personal bankruptcy legislation, passed in 1978. Most Western European countries followed suit in the 1980s and 1990s while in southern and eastern Europe personal bankruptcy legislation was passed in the 2000s and 2010s.[29]

References edit

  1. ^ a b Hudson 2018, p. 3.
  2. ^ De Graef, Katrien (2021). "Bad moon rising : the changing fortunes of early second-millennium BCE Ur". Rencontre Assyriologique Internationale. 62: 68. doi:10.1515/9781646021512-007. ISBN 9781646021512.
  3. ^ Hudson 2018, p. 50.
  4. ^ Hudson 2018, p. 29-30.
  5. ^ Harms, William (1996-02-01). "Linking ancient peoples". The University of Chicago Chronicle. 15 (10). Retrieved 2009-02-26.
  6. ^ Hudson 2018, p. 31.
  7. ^ Graeber 2012, p. 217-219.
  8. ^ Diodorus Siculus, Bibliotheca historica, 1, 79
  9. ^ Hudson 2018, p. 181-182.
  10. ^ Hudson 2018, p. 219.
  11. ^ ערוך השולחן חושן משפט סימן סז סעיף ז
  12. ^ Hudson 2018, p. 220-221.
  13. ^ Gittin 36a.
  14. ^ a b Finley 1973, p. 40.
  15. ^ Finley 1973, p. 80.
  16. ^ Aristotle, Athenian Constitution, The Seisachtheia
  17. ^ Graeber 2012, p. 191,427.
  18. ^ Forsdyke, Sara (2005). "Revelry and riot in Archaic Megara: democratic disorder or ritual reversal?". The Journal of Hellenic Studies. 125: 73. doi:10.1017/S0075426900007114.
  19. ^ Green 1990, p. 257.
  20. ^ Finley 1973, p. 46.
  21. ^ Appian. The Civil Wars. p. 1.6.54. Retrieved 11 June 2023.
  22. ^ Keaveney 2005, p. 56.
  23. ^ Seager 1992, p. 180.
  24. ^ Finley 1973, p. 143.
  25. ^ a b W. Pakter, The origins of bankruptcy in medieval canon and Roman law, in Proceedings of the Seventh International Congress of Medieval Canon Law, 1984, ed. P. Linehan, Vatican City, 1988, 485-506.
  26. ^ Andreau, Jean. "Personal endebtment and debt forgivness [sic] in the Roman empire". cadtm.org. Retrieved 23 June 2023.
  27. ^ Graeber 2012, p. 259.
  28. ^ Graeber 2012, p. 265.
  29. ^ Walter, György; Krenchel, Jens Valdemar (2021). "The Leniency of Personal Bankruptcy Regulations in the EU Countries". Risks. 9 (162): 162. doi:10.3390/risks9090162. hdl:10419/258246.

Sources edit

  • Seager, Robin (1992). "Sulla". In Crook, John; et al. (eds.). The last age of the Roman Republic, 146–43 BC. Cambridge Ancient History. Vol. 9 (2nd ed.). Cambridge University Press. pp. 165–207. ISBN 0-521-85073-8. OCLC 121060.
  • Keaveney, Arthur (2005). Sulla, the last republican. Routledge. ISBN 9780415336611.
  • Hudson, Michael (2018). ... And Forgive Them Their Debts. ISLET-Verlag. ISBN 9783981826029.
  • Graeber, David (2012). Debt. The First 5,000 Years. Melville House. ISBN 9781612191294.
  • Finley, Moses I. (1973). The Ancient Economy. University of California Press. ISBN 9780520024366.
  • Green, Peter (1990). Alexander to Actium: The Historical Evolution of the Hellenistic Age. University of California Press. ISBN 9780520083493.

history, debt, relief, debt, relief, debt, forgiveness, been, practiced, many, societies, since, antiquity, periodic, debt, remission, institutionalised, ancient, near, east, contributed, stability, societies, ancient, greece, rome, laws, were, more, creditor,. Debt relief or debt forgiveness has been practiced in many societies since antiquity Periodic debt remission was institutionalised in the Ancient Near East and contributed to the stability of its societies In ancient Greece and Rome the laws were more creditor friendly and debt cancellation was one of the major demands of the poor only occasionally implemented by the government Medieval canon law contained provisions for the annulment of debts owed by borrowers in distress which influenced modern personal bankruptcy law Contents 1 Ancient Near East 2 Ancient Greece and Rome 3 China 4 Medieval Europe 5 Modern period 6 References 7 SourcesAncient Near East edit nbsp Urukagina s reform text mentions the cancelling of obligations of indentured families as part of his reformsDebt relief existed in many societies of the Ancient Near East in the form of debt remission whereby certain debts were declared void and the foreclosed property reverted to the original owners Debts were often cancelled by a new ruler issuing a clean slate decree after assuming the throne or following a natural or man made calamity Usually only personal debt was cancelled whereas debts incurred by merchants were unaffected 1 The periodical debt remissions played a large role in the Ancient Near East They contributed to the stability of the society 2 Most of the loans were taken by peasants to enable them to subsist until the next harvest and often the land was pledged as collateral If the borrower was unable to repay the loan the land passed to the lender with the borrower himself becoming a bondsman 3 The debt remissions checked the power of elites who would otherwise amass great fortunes of land cultivated by serfs and ensured that enough free labourers were available to serve in the army and for public work duties 1 The earliest known debt cancellation was proclaimed by Enmetena of Lagash c 2400 BCE Similar measures were enacted by later Sumerian Babylonian and Assyrian rulers of Mesopotamia where they were known as freedom decrees ama gi in Sumerian 4 This same theme was found in an ancient bilingual Hittite Hurrian text entitled The Song of Debt Release 5 In Ancient Egypt interest bearing debt did not exist for most of its history When it started spreading in the Late Period the rulers of Egypt regulated it and a number of debt remissions are known to have occurred during the Ptolemaic era including the one whose proclamation was inscribed on the Rosetta Stone 6 7 Diodorus Siculus provides the following rationale for abolishing the debt bondage by pharaoh Bakenranef 8 For it would be absurd that a soldier at the moment perhaps when he was setting forth to fight for his fatherland should be haled to prison by his creditor for an unpaid loan and that the greed of private citizens should in this way endanger the safety of all Debt forgiveness is mentioned in the Torah in which God commanded the Israelites to forgive debts in certain cases at the end of Shmita the last year of the seven year agricultural cycle Hebrew slaves were also set free either at the same time or at the end of the 49 year cycle depending on interpretation At the end of the longer cycle during Jubilee year the land also reverted to its original owners According to Michael Hudson the Jubilee law likely appeared in response to a debt crisis and took debt cancellation from the hands of the rulers making it periodical and automatic 9 No contracts survive attesting to the compliance or lack of it with the Jubilee law 10 Due to the First Exile the laws of debt remission were no longer applicable due to most the fact most Jews were not living in the land of Israel and the fact that the remission was tied to the restitution of ancestral land Later Rabbis would decree that debts should continue to be remitted Around the beginning of the 1st century CE Hillel established the prozbul loophole which enabled lenders to offer loans which could not be remitted by redirecting the recipient of the repayment as the local Bet Din court of law which would then forward it to the original lender Since the debt would be owed to a public institution instead of a private individual it would not be remitted 11 Hillel argued that otherwise the poor would not be able to get a loan in the year preceding the remission 12 13 Ancient Greece and Rome edit nbsp The obverse of Hadrian s sestertius commemorating the cancellation of tax arrears shows the emperor burning tax recordsIn general the law in ancient Greece and Rome was more creditor friendly and harsh and unyielding towards debtors 14 Throughout antiquity the cancellation of debts alongside land redistribution was the main rallying cry of the poor 15 In response to a debt crisis in the 6th century BCE the Athenians implemented a law of Solon providing for seisachtheia seisax8eia which cancelled all debts and retroactively annulled previous debts that had resulted in slavery and serfdom freeing debt slaves and debt serfs 16 According to Plutarch interest bearing debts were made illegal by the democratic government of Megara in the 6th century BCE while the creditors were forced to return the collected interest This was treated as an extreme populist measure by Greek sources 17 and historians are divided as regards the historicity of these events considered to reflect later anti democratic political thought 18 The Spartan kings also implemented debt cancellations in their attempt to reform the state in the 3rd century BC 19 The Roman equivalent was called novae tabulae In the Ancient Rome the debt bondage known as nexum was abolished in 313 BCE 20 However even after that the debtors were still required to perform compulsory labour and could be imprisoned following a court judgement 14 Appian mentions an attempt by praetor Asellio to revive the old law prohibiting the taking of interest in 89 BC which led to his murder presumably by the creditors 21 Later partial debt cancellations were enacted by Sulla by 10 and then by Lucius Cornelius Cinna and Lucius Valerius Flaccus by three quarters in order to stabilise the economy ruined by the civil war 22 23 The Roman elites were firmly against debt relief with Cicero denouncing it as an attack on property and the propertied classes 24 The predecessors of the bankruptcy law emerged in early Imperial Rome Augustus instituted cessio bonorum allowing debtors to voluntarily surrender their property to creditors and thereby avoid personal arrest and loss of legal standing infamia 25 While Rome never enacted complete debt cancellation several emperors wrote off tax arrears that is debts to the state treasury 26 China editThe indebtedness of rural population was a constant government concern from the days of the Han dynasty A variety of means were employed to deal with it including full or partial debt relief Often those loans whose repaid interest exceeded the principal were annulled 27 The government accused the Buddhist monasteries which had become major lenders to the peasantry by the 6th century CE of issuing high interest loans During the purge of Buddhist monasteries in 845 more than 150 000 temple serfs were released from bondage according to the official reports 28 Medieval Europe editMedieval canon law built upon Roman law and extensively discussed provisions to mitigate the harshness of debtors punishments Most commentators allowed for a debtor to be discharged and make a fresh start after ceding to his creditors all his goods or possibly all his goods except some bare necessities These provisions later influenced English bankruptcy law 25 Modern period editSee also History of bankruptcy law In the modern period debt discharge typically occurs through the process of bankruptcy One of the first countries to establish personal bankruptcy rather than company bankruptcy was the United Kingdom where the Bankruptcy Act 1869 allowed all people to file for bankruptcy Currently the benchmark for personal bankruptcy legislation is the US personal bankruptcy legislation passed in 1978 Most Western European countries followed suit in the 1980s and 1990s while in southern and eastern Europe personal bankruptcy legislation was passed in the 2000s and 2010s 29 References edit a b Hudson 2018 p 3 De Graef Katrien 2021 Bad moon rising the changing fortunes of early second millennium BCE Ur Rencontre Assyriologique Internationale 62 68 doi 10 1515 9781646021512 007 ISBN 9781646021512 Hudson 2018 p 50 Hudson 2018 p 29 30 Harms William 1996 02 01 Linking ancient peoples The University of Chicago Chronicle 15 10 Retrieved 2009 02 26 Hudson 2018 p 31 Graeber 2012 p 217 219 Diodorus Siculus Bibliotheca historica 1 79 Hudson 2018 p 181 182 Hudson 2018 p 219 ערוך השולחן חושן משפט סימן סז סעיף ז Hudson 2018 p 220 221 Gittin 36a a b Finley 1973 p 40 Finley 1973 p 80 Aristotle Athenian Constitution The Seisachtheia Graeber 2012 p 191 427 Forsdyke Sara 2005 Revelry and riot in Archaic Megara democratic disorder or ritual reversal The Journal of Hellenic Studies 125 73 doi 10 1017 S0075426900007114 Green 1990 p 257 Finley 1973 p 46 Appian The Civil Wars p 1 6 54 Retrieved 11 June 2023 Keaveney 2005 p 56 Seager 1992 p 180 Finley 1973 p 143 a b W Pakter The origins of bankruptcy in medieval canon and Roman law in Proceedings of the Seventh International Congress of Medieval Canon Law 1984 ed P Linehan Vatican City 1988 485 506 Andreau Jean Personal endebtment and debt forgivness sic in the Roman empire cadtm org Retrieved 23 June 2023 Graeber 2012 p 259 Graeber 2012 p 265 Walter Gyorgy Krenchel Jens Valdemar 2021 The Leniency of Personal Bankruptcy Regulations in the EU Countries Risks 9 162 162 doi 10 3390 risks9090162 hdl 10419 258246 Sources editSeager Robin 1992 Sulla In Crook John et al eds The last age of the Roman Republic 146 43 BC Cambridge Ancient History Vol 9 2nd ed Cambridge University Press pp 165 207 ISBN 0 521 85073 8 OCLC 121060 Keaveney Arthur 2005 Sulla the last republican Routledge ISBN 9780415336611 Hudson Michael 2018 And Forgive Them Their Debts ISLET Verlag ISBN 9783981826029 Graeber David 2012 Debt The First 5 000 Years Melville House ISBN 9781612191294 Finley Moses I 1973 The Ancient Economy University of California Press ISBN 9780520024366 Green Peter 1990 Alexander to Actium The Historical Evolution of the Hellenistic Age University of California Press ISBN 9780520083493 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title History of debt relief amp oldid 1203542001, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.