fbpx
Wikipedia

Fisher's principle

Fisher's principle is an evolutionary model that explains why the sex ratio of most species that produce offspring through sexual reproduction is approximately 1:1 between males and females. A. W. F. Edwards has remarked that it is "probably the most celebrated argument in evolutionary biology".[1]

Fisher's principle was outlined by Ronald Fisher in his 1930 book The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection[2] (but has been incorrectly attributed as original to Fisher[1]). Fisher couched his argument in terms of parental expenditure, and predicted that parental expenditure on both sexes should be equal. Sex ratios that are 1:1 are hence known as "Fisherian", and those that are not 1:1 are "non-Fisherian" or "extraordinary" and occur because they break the assumptions made in Fisher's model.[3][4]

Basic explanation edit

W. D. Hamilton gave the following simple explanation in his 1967 paper on "Extraordinary sex ratios",[3] given the condition that males and females cost equal amounts to produce:

  1. Suppose male births are less common than female.
  2. A newborn male then has better mating prospects than a newborn female, and therefore can expect to have more offspring.
  3. Therefore parents genetically disposed to produce males tend to have more than average numbers of grandchildren born to them.
  4. Therefore the genes for male-producing tendencies spread, and male births become more common.
  5. As the 1:1 sex ratio is approached, the advantage associated with producing males dies away.
  6. The same reasoning holds if females are substituted for males throughout. Therefore 1:1 is the equilibrium ratio.

In modern language, the 1:1 ratio is the evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS).[5]

Parental investment edit

Fisher wrote the explanation described by Eric Charnov and James J. Bull as being "characteristically terse" and "cryptic":[6] in Chapter 6: "Sexual Reproduction and Sexual Selection":[2]

In organisms of all kinds the young are launched upon their careers endowed with a certain amount of biological capital derived from their parents. This varies enormously in amount in different species, but, in all, there has been, before the offspring is able to lead an independent existence, a certain expenditure of nutriment in addition, almost universally, to some expenditure of time or activity, which the parents are induced by their instincts to make for the advantage of their young. Let us consider the reproductive value of these offspring at the moment when this parental expenditure on their behalf has just ceased. If we consider the aggregate of an entire generation of such offspring it is clear that the total reproductive value of the males in this group is exactly equal to the total value of all the females, because each sex must supply half the ancestry of all future generations of the species. From this it follows that the sex ratio will so adjust itself, under the influence of Natural Selection, that the total parental expenditure incurred in respect of children of each sex, shall be equal; for if this were not so and the total expenditure incurred in producing males, for instance, were less than the total expenditure incurred in producing females, then since the total reproductive value of the males is equal to that of the females, it would follow that those parents, the innate tendencies of which caused them to produce males in excess, would, for the same expenditure, produce a greater amount of reproductive value; and in consequence would be the progenitors of a larger fraction of future generations than would parents having a congenital bias towards the production of females. Selection would thus raise the sex-ratio until the expenditure upon males became equal to that upon females.[2]

Development of the argument edit

Fisher's principle is an early example of a model in which genes for greater production of either sex become equalized in the population, because each sex supplies exactly half the genes of all future generations.

Fisher's principle is rooted in the concept of frequency-dependent selection, though Fisher's principle is not frequency-dependent selection per se. Frequency-dependent selection, in this scenario, is the logic that the probability of an individual being able to breed is dependent on the frequency of the opposite sex in relation to its own sex. It was first described by Darwin in 1871.

Fisher's principle extends frequency dependence to explain how natural selection can act on genes that affect the frequency of an individual's grandchildren without affecting the frequency of their children. Fisher predicted that parents will invest their resources equally between each sex of offspring, because each sex supplies exactly half the genes of all future generations. As a result, those genes that cause parents to invest unequally in the sexes will tend to be selected against. Fisher was aware that in humans, more boys are born, but boys are also more likely to die in infancy. As a consequence, he reasoned that because parents tend to invest less in boys – because more boys die before the end of the period of parental care – there is a higher rate of male births to equalise parental investment in each sex.

Fisher's principle is also a precursor to evolutionary game theory. R.H. MacArthur (1965) first suggested applying to sex ratios the language of game theory,[7] and this was subsequently picked up by W.D. Hamilton (1967) who termed the equilibrium point the "unbeatable strategy".[3] Hamilton's unbeatable strategy was refined by John Maynard Smith and George R. Price (1973) into their concept of the evolutionarily stable strategy, i.e. one which cannot be invaded by a mutant strategy.[5]

Fisher's concept of parental expenditure (now termed parental investment), developed particularly by Robert Trivers, is now an important concept in ecology.

Psychiatrist Randolph M. Nesse has argued that Fisher's principle illustrates the dominance of individual-level selection over group selection because, regardless of the hypothetical sex imbalance of a group, the genes of a parental organism produce offspring of the less frequent sex in order to maximize their transmission to subsequent generations but at substantial cost to the group growth rate.[8]

Fisher's sources edit

Historical research by A.W.F. Edwards has shown that, although the idea has been attributed to Fisher, Charles Darwin had originally formulated a similar argument in the first edition of The Descent of Man but removed it for the second edition – Fisher only had a copy of the second edition – and quotes Darwin in The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection.[1][9][2]

Carl Düsing of the University of Jena published a similar argument in three works between 1883 and 1884,[9] which is essentially identical to Shaw and Mohler's later model.[10] It has been argued that Darwin's argument and Fisher's are different, in that Darwin assumes monogamy whereas Fisher's does not; the same author contends that Fisher's argument is very much like Dusing's, except that Fisher introduced the idea of parental investment and calculated the sex ratio that should exist at the age of independence, which may precede the age of reproduction.[11]

References edit

  1. ^ a b c Edwards, A.W.F. (1998). "Natural selection and the sex ratio: Fisher's sources". American Naturalist. 151 (6): 564–569. doi:10.1086/286141. PMID 18811377. S2CID 40540426.
  2. ^ a b c d Fisher, R.A. (1930). "Chapter 6: Sexual Reproduction and Sexual Selection § Natural Selection and the sex-ratio". The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press. p. 141.
  3. ^ a b c Hamilton, W.D. (1967). "Extraordinary sex ratios". Science. 156 (3774): 477–488. Bibcode:1967Sci...156..477H. doi:10.1126/science.156.3774.477. PMID 6021675.
  4. ^ Charnov, E., and Bull, J. (1989). "Non-fisherian sex ratios with sex change and environmental sex determination", Nature 338, pp. 148–150. https://doi.org/10.1038/338148a0 Retrieved 29 March 2022.
  5. ^ a b Maynard Smith, J.; Price, G.R. (1973). "The logic of animal conflict". Nature. 246 (5427): 15–18. Bibcode:1973Natur.246...15S. doi:10.1038/246015a0. S2CID 4224989.
  6. ^ Bull, J.J.; Charnov, E.L. (1988). "How fundamental are Fisherian sex ratios?". In Harvey, P.H.; Partridge, L. (eds.). Oxford Surveys on Evolutionary Biology. Vol. 5. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. pp. 96–135.
  7. ^ MacArthur, R.H. (1965). Waterman, T.; Horowitz, H. (eds.). Theoretical and Mathematical Biology. New York, NY: Blaisdell.
  8. ^ Nesse, Randolph M. (2019). Good Reasons for Bad Feelings: Insights from the Frontier of Evolutionary Psychiatry. Dutton. pp. 164–166. ISBN 978-1101985663.
  9. ^ a b Edwards, A.W.F. (2000). "Carl Düsing (1884) on the Regulation of the Sex-Ratio". Theoretical Population Biology. 58 (3): 255–257. doi:10.1006/tpbi.2000.1482. PMID 11120652.
  10. ^ Shaw, R.F.; Mohler, J.D. (1953). "The selective significance of the sex ratio". American Naturalist. 87 (837): 337–342. doi:10.1086/281794. JSTOR 2458523. S2CID 85283716.
  11. ^ Sober, E. (2011). Did Darwin Write the Origin Backwards? Philosophical Essays on Darwin's Theory. Amherst, NY: Prometheus Books.

Further reading edit

As the most celebrated argument in evolutionary biology, (Edwards, 1998, pp. 564–569) Fisher's principle is a staple of popular science books on evolution. For example, see:

For those wishing more advanced treatment, see

  • Pen, Ido; Weissing, Franz J. (2002). "chapters 1 and 2". In Hardy, Ian C.W. (ed.). Sex Ratios: Concepts and Research Methods.

fisher, principle, evolutionary, model, that, explains, ratio, most, species, that, produce, offspring, through, sexual, reproduction, approximately, between, males, females, edwards, remarked, that, probably, most, celebrated, argument, evolutionary, biology,. Fisher s principle is an evolutionary model that explains why the sex ratio of most species that produce offspring through sexual reproduction is approximately 1 1 between males and females A W F Edwards has remarked that it is probably the most celebrated argument in evolutionary biology 1 Fisher s principle was outlined by Ronald Fisher in his 1930 book The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection 2 but has been incorrectly attributed as original to Fisher 1 Fisher couched his argument in terms of parental expenditure and predicted that parental expenditure on both sexes should be equal Sex ratios that are 1 1 are hence known as Fisherian and those that are not 1 1 are non Fisherian or extraordinary and occur because they break the assumptions made in Fisher s model 3 4 Contents 1 Basic explanation 2 Parental investment 3 Development of the argument 4 Fisher s sources 5 References 6 Further readingBasic explanation editW D Hamilton gave the following simple explanation in his 1967 paper on Extraordinary sex ratios 3 given the condition that males and females cost equal amounts to produce Suppose male births are less common than female A newborn male then has better mating prospects than a newborn female and therefore can expect to have more offspring Therefore parents genetically disposed to produce males tend to have more than average numbers of grandchildren born to them Therefore the genes for male producing tendencies spread and male births become more common As the 1 1 sex ratio is approached the advantage associated with producing males dies away The same reasoning holds if females are substituted for males throughout Therefore 1 1 is the equilibrium ratio In modern language the 1 1 ratio is the evolutionarily stable strategy ESS 5 Parental investment editMain article Parental investment Fisher wrote the explanation described by Eric Charnov and James J Bull as being characteristically terse and cryptic 6 in Chapter 6 Sexual Reproduction and Sexual Selection 2 In organisms of all kinds the young are launched upon their careers endowed with a certain amount of biological capital derived from their parents This varies enormously in amount in different species but in all there has been before the offspring is able to lead an independent existence a certain expenditure of nutriment in addition almost universally to some expenditure of time or activity which the parents are induced by their instincts to make for the advantage of their young Let us consider the reproductive value of these offspring at the moment when this parental expenditure on their behalf has just ceased If we consider the aggregate of an entire generation of such offspring it is clear that the total reproductive value of the males in this group is exactly equal to the total value of all the females because each sex must supply half the ancestry of all future generations of the species From this it follows that the sex ratio will so adjust itself under the influence of Natural Selection that the total parental expenditure incurred in respect of children of each sex shall be equal for if this were not so and the total expenditure incurred in producing males for instance were less than the total expenditure incurred in producing females then since the total reproductive value of the males is equal to that of the females it would follow that those parents the innate tendencies of which caused them to produce males in excess would for the same expenditure produce a greater amount of reproductive value and in consequence would be the progenitors of a larger fraction of future generations than would parents having a congenital bias towards the production of females Selection would thus raise the sex ratio until the expenditure upon males became equal to that upon females 2 Development of the argument editFisher s principle is an early example of a model in which genes for greater production of either sex become equalized in the population because each sex supplies exactly half the genes of all future generations Fisher s principle is rooted in the concept of frequency dependent selection though Fisher s principle is not frequency dependent selection per se Frequency dependent selection in this scenario is the logic that the probability of an individual being able to breed is dependent on the frequency of the opposite sex in relation to its own sex It was first described by Darwin in 1871 Fisher s principle extends frequency dependence to explain how natural selection can act on genes that affect the frequency of an individual s grandchildren without affecting the frequency of their children Fisher predicted that parents will invest their resources equally between each sex of offspring because each sex supplies exactly half the genes of all future generations As a result those genes that cause parents to invest unequally in the sexes will tend to be selected against Fisher was aware that in humans more boys are born but boys are also more likely to die in infancy As a consequence he reasoned that because parents tend to invest less in boys because more boys die before the end of the period of parental care there is a higher rate of male births to equalise parental investment in each sex Fisher s principle is also a precursor to evolutionary game theory R H MacArthur 1965 first suggested applying to sex ratios the language of game theory 7 and this was subsequently picked up by W D Hamilton 1967 who termed the equilibrium point the unbeatable strategy 3 Hamilton s unbeatable strategy was refined by John Maynard Smith and George R Price 1973 into their concept of the evolutionarily stable strategy i e one which cannot be invaded by a mutant strategy 5 Fisher s concept of parental expenditure now termed parental investment developed particularly by Robert Trivers is now an important concept in ecology Psychiatrist Randolph M Nesse has argued that Fisher s principle illustrates the dominance of individual level selection over group selection because regardless of the hypothetical sex imbalance of a group the genes of a parental organism produce offspring of the less frequent sex in order to maximize their transmission to subsequent generations but at substantial cost to the group growth rate 8 Fisher s sources editHistorical research by A W F Edwards has shown that although the idea has been attributed to Fisher Charles Darwin had originally formulated a similar argument in the first edition of The Descent of Man but removed it for the second edition Fisher only had a copy of the second edition and quotes Darwin in The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection 1 9 2 Carl Dusing of the University of Jena published a similar argument in three works between 1883 and 1884 9 which is essentially identical to Shaw and Mohler s later model 10 It has been argued that Darwin s argument and Fisher s are different in that Darwin assumes monogamy whereas Fisher s does not the same author contends that Fisher s argument is very much like Dusing s except that Fisher introduced the idea of parental investment and calculated the sex ratio that should exist at the age of independence which may precede the age of reproduction 11 References edit a b c Edwards A W F 1998 Natural selection and the sex ratio Fisher s sources American Naturalist 151 6 564 569 doi 10 1086 286141 PMID 18811377 S2CID 40540426 a b c d Fisher R A 1930 Chapter 6 Sexual Reproduction and Sexual Selection Natural Selection and the sex ratio The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection Oxford UK Clarendon Press p 141 a b c Hamilton W D 1967 Extraordinary sex ratios Science 156 3774 477 488 Bibcode 1967Sci 156 477H doi 10 1126 science 156 3774 477 PMID 6021675 Charnov E and Bull J 1989 Non fisherian sex ratios with sex change and environmental sex determination Nature 338 pp 148 150 https doi org 10 1038 338148a0 Retrieved 29 March 2022 a b Maynard Smith J Price G R 1973 The logic of animal conflict Nature 246 5427 15 18 Bibcode 1973Natur 246 15S doi 10 1038 246015a0 S2CID 4224989 Bull J J Charnov E L 1988 How fundamental are Fisherian sex ratios In Harvey P H Partridge L eds Oxford Surveys on Evolutionary Biology Vol 5 Oxford UK Oxford University Press pp 96 135 MacArthur R H 1965 Waterman T Horowitz H eds Theoretical and Mathematical Biology New York NY Blaisdell Nesse Randolph M 2019 Good Reasons for Bad Feelings Insights from the Frontier of Evolutionary Psychiatry Dutton pp 164 166 ISBN 978 1101985663 a b Edwards A W F 2000 Carl Dusing 1884 on the Regulation of the Sex Ratio Theoretical Population Biology 58 3 255 257 doi 10 1006 tpbi 2000 1482 PMID 11120652 Shaw R F Mohler J D 1953 The selective significance of the sex ratio American Naturalist 87 837 337 342 doi 10 1086 281794 JSTOR 2458523 S2CID 85283716 Sober E 2011 Did Darwin Write the Origin Backwards Philosophical Essays on Darwin s Theory Amherst NY Prometheus Books Further reading editAs the most celebrated argument in evolutionary biology Edwards 1998 pp 564 569 Fisher s principle is a staple of popular science books on evolution For example see Gould Stephen Jay 2002 The Structure of Evolutionary Theory pp 648 649 678 692 Dawkins Richard Wong Yan 2004 The Seal s Tale The Ancestor s Tale A pilgrimage to the dawn of life revised amp expanded ed Boston MA Houghton Mifflin Company ISBN 0 618 00583 8 For those wishing more advanced treatment see Pen Ido Weissing Franz J 2002 chapters 1 and 2 In Hardy Ian C W ed Sex Ratios Concepts and Research Methods Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Fisher 27s principle amp oldid 1152159705, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.