fbpx
Wikipedia

Value (economics)

In economics, economic value is a measure of the benefit provided by a good or service to an economic agent, and value for money represents an assessment of whether financial or other resources are being used effectively in order to secure such benefit. Economic value is generally measured through units of currency, and the interpretation is therefore "what is the maximum amount of money a person is willing and able to pay for a good or service?” Value for money is often expressed in comparative terms, such as "better", or "best value for money",[1] but may also be expressed in absolute terms, such as where a deal does, or does not, offer value for money.[2]

Among the competing schools of economic theory there are differing theories of value.

Economic value is not the same as market price, nor is economic value the same thing as market value. If a consumer is willing to buy a good, it implies that the customer places a higher value on the good than the market price. The difference between the value to the consumer and the market price is called "consumer surplus".[3] It is easy to see situations where the actual value is considerably larger than the market price: purchase of drinking water is one example.

Overview edit

The economic value of a good or service has puzzled economists since the beginning of the discipline. First, economists tried to estimate the value of a good to an individual alone, and extend that definition to goods that can be exchanged. From this analysis came the concepts value in use and value in exchange.

Value is linked to price through the mechanism of exchange. When an economist observes an exchange, two important value functions are revealed: those of the buyer and seller. Just as the buyer reveals what he is willing to pay for a certain amount of a good, so too does the seller reveal what it costs him to give up the good.

Additional information about market value is obtained by the rate at which transactions occur, telling observers the extent to which the purchase of the good has value over time.

Said another way, value is how much a desired object or condition is worth relative to other objects or conditions. Economic values are expressed as "how much" of one desirable condition or commodity will, or would be given up in exchange for some other desired condition or commodity. Among the competing schools of economic theory there are differing metrics for value assessment and the metrics are the subject of a theory of value. Value theories are a large part of the differences and disagreements between the various schools of economic theory.

Explanations edit

In neoclassical economics, the value of an object or service is often seen as nothing but the price it would bring in an open and competitive market. This is determined primarily by the demand for the object relative to supply in a perfectly competitive market. Many neoclassical economic theories equate the value of a commodity with its price, whether the market is competitive or not. As such, everything is seen as a commodity and if there is no market to set a price then there is no economic value.

In classical economics, the value of an object or condition is the amount of discomfort/labor saved through the consumption or use of an object or condition (Labor Theory of Value). Though exchange value is recognized, economic value is not, in theory, dependent on the existence of a market and price and value are not seen as equal. This is complicated, however, by the efforts of classical economists to connect price and labor value. Karl Marx, for one, saw exchange value as the "form of appearance" (This interpretation of Marx is along the lines of the Marxist thinker Michael Heinrich) [Erscheinungsform] of value, in his critique of political economy which implies that, although value is separate from exchange value, it is meaningless without the act of exchange.

In this tradition, Steve Keen makes the claim that "value" refers to "the innate worth of a commodity, which determines the normal ('equilibrium') ratio at which two commodities exchange."[4] To Keen and the tradition of David Ricardo, this corresponds to the classical concept of long-run cost-determined prices, what Adam Smith called "natural prices" and Marx called "prices of production". It is part of a cost-of-production theory of value and price. Ricardo, but not Keen, used a "labor theory of price" in which a commodity's "innate worth" was the amount of labor needed to produce it.

"The value of a thing in any given time and place", according to Henry George, "is the largest amount of exertion that anyone will render in exchange for it. But as men always seek to gratify their desires with the least exertion this is the lowest amount for which a similar thing can otherwise be obtained."[5]

In another classical tradition, Marx distinguished between the "value in use" (use-value, what a commodity provides to its buyer), labor cost which he calls "value" (the socially-necessary labour time it embodies), and "exchange value" (how much labor-time the sale of the commodity can claim, Smith's "labor commanded" value). By most interpretations of his labor theory of value, Marx, like Ricardo, developed a "labor theory of price" where the point of analyzing value was to allow the calculation of relative prices. Others see values as part of his sociopolitical interpretation and critique of capitalism and other societies, and deny that it was intended to serve as a category of economics. According to a third interpretation, Marx aimed for a theory of the dynamics of price formation but did not complete it.

In 1860, John Ruskin published a critique of the economic concept of value from a moral point of view. He entitled the volume Unto This Last, and his central point was this: "It is impossible to conclude, of any given mass of acquired wealth, merely by the fact of its existence, whether it signifies good or evil to the nation in the midst of which it exists. Its real value depends on the moral sign attached to it, just as strictly as that of a mathematical quantity depends on the algebraic sign attached to it. Any given accumulation of commercial wealth may be indicative, on the one hand, of faithful industries, progressive energies, and productive ingenuities: or, on the other, it may be indicative of mortal luxury, merciless tyranny, ruinous chicanery." Gandhi was greatly inspired by Ruskin's book and published a paraphrase of it in 1908.[non sequitur]

Economists such as Ludwig von Mises asserted that "value" is a subjective judgment. Prices can only be determined by taking these subjective judgments into account, and that this is done through the price mechanism in the market. Thus, it was false to say that the economic value of a good was equal to what it cost to produce or to its current replacement cost.

Silvio Gesell denied value theory in economics. He thought that value theory is useless and prevents economics from becoming science and that a currency administration guided by value theory is doomed to sterility and inactivity.[6]

Connected concepts edit

The theory of value is closely related to that of allocative efficiency, the quality by which firms produce those goods and services most valued by society. The market value of a machine part, for example, will depend upon a variety of objective facts involving its efficiency versus the efficiency of other types of part or other types of machine to make the kind of products that consumers will value in turn. In such a case, market value has both objective and subjective components.

Economy, efficiency and effectiveness, often referred to as the "Three Es", may be used as complementary factors contributing to an assessment of the value for money provided by a purchase, project or activity. The UK National Audit Office uses the following summaries to explain the meaning of each term:

  • Economy: minimising the cost of resources used or required (inputs) – spending less;
  • Efficiency: the relationship between the output from goods or services and the resources to produce them – spending well; and
  • Effectiveness: the relationship between the intended and actual results of public spending (outcomes) – spending wisely.[7]

Sometimes a fourth 'E', equity, is also added.[7][8]

In philosophy, economic value is a subcategory of a more general philosophical value, as defined in goodness and value theory or in the science of value.

 
Value or price

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Department of Finance (Northern Ireland), Definition of best value for money, endorsed by the Northern Ireland Executive on 22 March 2011, accessed 8 December 2023
  2. ^ BBC News, Ferry to be built at Ferguson yard despite not being 'value for money', published 16 May 2023, accessed 8 December 2023
  3. ^ "Consumer Surplus" (PDF). p. 7-1, 7-2.
  4. ^ Steve Keen, Debunking Economics, New York, Zed Books (2001) p. 271, ISBN 1-86403-070-4, OCLC 45804669
  5. ^ "The Science of Political Economy, Chapter 8". Politicaleconomy.org. Retrieved 2012-04-17.
  6. ^ . Archived from the original on 2017-12-10.
  7. ^ a b National Audit Office, Assessing value for money, accessed 15 March 2019
  8. ^ Jackson, P., Value for money and international development: Deconstructing myths to promote a more constructive discussion, OECD, May 2012

value, economics, confused, with, market, value, this, article, needs, additional, citations, verification, please, help, improve, this, article, adding, citations, reliable, sources, unsourced, material, challenged, removed, find, sources, value, economics, n. Not to be confused with Market value This article needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Value economics news newspapers books scholar JSTOR December 2016 Learn how and when to remove this template message In economics economic value is a measure of the benefit provided by a good or service to an economic agent and value for money represents an assessment of whether financial or other resources are being used effectively in order to secure such benefit Economic value is generally measured through units of currency and the interpretation is therefore what is the maximum amount of money a person is willing and able to pay for a good or service Value for money is often expressed in comparative terms such as better or best value for money 1 but may also be expressed in absolute terms such as where a deal does or does not offer value for money 2 Among the competing schools of economic theory there are differing theories of value Economic value is not the same as market price nor is economic value the same thing as market value If a consumer is willing to buy a good it implies that the customer places a higher value on the good than the market price The difference between the value to the consumer and the market price is called consumer surplus 3 It is easy to see situations where the actual value is considerably larger than the market price purchase of drinking water is one example Contents 1 Overview 2 Explanations 3 Connected concepts 4 See also 5 ReferencesOverview editThe economic value of a good or service has puzzled economists since the beginning of the discipline First economists tried to estimate the value of a good to an individual alone and extend that definition to goods that can be exchanged From this analysis came the concepts value in use and value in exchange Value is linked to price through the mechanism of exchange When an economist observes an exchange two important value functions are revealed those of the buyer and seller Just as the buyer reveals what he is willing to pay for a certain amount of a good so too does the seller reveal what it costs him to give up the good Additional information about market value is obtained by the rate at which transactions occur telling observers the extent to which the purchase of the good has value over time Said another way value is how much a desired object or condition is worth relative to other objects or conditions Economic values are expressed as how much of one desirable condition or commodity will or would be given up in exchange for some other desired condition or commodity Among the competing schools of economic theory there are differing metrics for value assessment and the metrics are the subject of a theory of value Value theories are a large part of the differences and disagreements between the various schools of economic theory Explanations editIn neoclassical economics the value of an object or service is often seen as nothing but the price it would bring in an open and competitive market This is determined primarily by the demand for the object relative to supply in a perfectly competitive market Many neoclassical economic theories equate the value of a commodity with its price whether the market is competitive or not As such everything is seen as a commodity and if there is no market to set a price then there is no economic value In classical economics the value of an object or condition is the amount of discomfort labor saved through the consumption or use of an object or condition Labor Theory of Value Though exchange value is recognized economic value is not in theory dependent on the existence of a market and price and value are not seen as equal This is complicated however by the efforts of classical economists to connect price and labor value Karl Marx for one saw exchange value as the form of appearance This interpretation of Marx is along the lines of the Marxist thinker Michael Heinrich Erscheinungsform of value in his critique of political economy which implies that although value is separate from exchange value it is meaningless without the act of exchange In this tradition Steve Keen makes the claim that value refers to the innate worth of a commodity which determines the normal equilibrium ratio at which two commodities exchange 4 To Keen and the tradition of David Ricardo this corresponds to the classical concept of long run cost determined prices what Adam Smith called natural prices and Marx called prices of production It is part of a cost of production theory of value and price Ricardo but not Keen used a labor theory of price in which a commodity s innate worth was the amount of labor needed to produce it The value of a thing in any given time and place according to Henry George is the largest amount of exertion that anyone will render in exchange for it But as men always seek to gratify their desires with the least exertion this is the lowest amount for which a similar thing can otherwise be obtained 5 In another classical tradition Marx distinguished between the value in use use value what a commodity provides to its buyer labor cost which he calls value the socially necessary labour time it embodies and exchange value how much labor time the sale of the commodity can claim Smith s labor commanded value By most interpretations of his labor theory of value Marx like Ricardo developed a labor theory of price where the point of analyzing value was to allow the calculation of relative prices Others see values as part of his sociopolitical interpretation and critique of capitalism and other societies and deny that it was intended to serve as a category of economics According to a third interpretation Marx aimed for a theory of the dynamics of price formation but did not complete it In 1860 John Ruskin published a critique of the economic concept of value from a moral point of view He entitled the volume Unto This Last and his central point was this It is impossible to conclude of any given mass of acquired wealth merely by the fact of its existence whether it signifies good or evil to the nation in the midst of which it exists Its real value depends on the moral sign attached to it just as strictly as that of a mathematical quantity depends on the algebraic sign attached to it Any given accumulation of commercial wealth may be indicative on the one hand of faithful industries progressive energies and productive ingenuities or on the other it may be indicative of mortal luxury merciless tyranny ruinous chicanery Gandhi was greatly inspired by Ruskin s book and published a paraphrase of it in 1908 non sequitur Economists such as Ludwig von Mises asserted that value is a subjective judgment Prices can only be determined by taking these subjective judgments into account and that this is done through the price mechanism in the market Thus it was false to say that the economic value of a good was equal to what it cost to produce or to its current replacement cost Silvio Gesell denied value theory in economics He thought that value theory is useless and prevents economics from becoming science and that a currency administration guided by value theory is doomed to sterility and inactivity 6 Connected concepts editThe theory of value is closely related to that of allocative efficiency the quality by which firms produce those goods and services most valued by society The market value of a machine part for example will depend upon a variety of objective facts involving its efficiency versus the efficiency of other types of part or other types of machine to make the kind of products that consumers will value in turn In such a case market value has both objective and subjective components Economy efficiency and effectiveness often referred to as the Three Es may be used as complementary factors contributing to an assessment of the value for money provided by a purchase project or activity The UK National Audit Office uses the following summaries to explain the meaning of each term Economy minimising the cost of resources used or required inputs spending less Efficiency the relationship between the output from goods or services and the resources to produce them spending well and Effectiveness the relationship between the intended and actual results of public spending outcomes spending wisely 7 Sometimes a fourth E equity is also added 7 8 In philosophy economic value is a subcategory of a more general philosophical value as defined in goodness and value theory or in the science of value nbsp Value or priceSee also edit nbsp Business and economics portalAsset pricing Labour theory of value Law of value Marginal theory of value Market price Non extractive economic value Objective theory of value Paradox of value Real versus nominal value economics Store of value Subjective theory of value Theory of value economics Use value Utility Value marketing Value form Value networkReferences edit Department of Finance Northern Ireland Definition of best value for money endorsed by the Northern Ireland Executive on 22 March 2011 accessed 8 December 2023 BBC News Ferry to be built at Ferguson yard despite not being value for money published 16 May 2023 accessed 8 December 2023 Consumer Surplus PDF p 7 1 7 2 Steve Keen Debunking Economics New York Zed Books 2001 p 271 ISBN 1 86403 070 4 OCLC 45804669 The Science of Political Economy Chapter 8 Politicaleconomy org Retrieved 2012 04 17 The Natural Economic Order Part III Chapter 3 Bibliowiki Archived from the original on 2017 12 10 a b National Audit Office Assessing value for money accessed 15 March 2019 Jackson P Value for money and international development Deconstructing myths to promote a more constructive discussion OECD May 2012 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Value economics amp oldid 1189274668, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.