fbpx
Wikipedia

Dixit–Stiglitz model

Dixit–Stiglitz model is a model of monopolistic competition developed by Avinash Dixit and Joseph Stiglitz (1977).[1] It has been used in many fields of economics including macroeconomics, economic geography and international trade theory. The model formalises consumers' preferences for product variety by using a CES function. Previous attempts to provide a model that accounted for variety preference (such as Harold Hotelling's location model) were indirect and failed to provide an easily interpretable and usable form for further study. In the Dixit–Stiglitz model, variety preference is inherent within the assumption of monotonic preferences because a consumer with such preferences prefers to have an average of any two bundles of goods as opposed to extremes.

Mathematical Derivation edit

The model begins with a standard CES utility function:

 

where N is the number of available goods, xi is the quantity of good i, and σ is the elasticity of substitution. Placing the restriction that σ > 1 ensures that preferences will be convex and thus monotonic for over any optimising range. Additionally, all CES functions are homogeneous of degree 1 and therefore represent homothetic preferences.

Additionally the consumer has a budget set defined by:

 

For any rational consumer the objective is to maximise their utility functions subject to their budget constraint (M) which is set exogenously. Such a process allows us to calculate a consumer's Marshallian Demand. Mathematically this means the consumer is working to achieve:

 

Since utility functions are ordinal rather than cardinal any monotonic transform of a utility function represents the same preferences. Therefore, the above constrained optimisation problem is analogous to:

 

since   is strictly increasing.

By using a Lagrange multiplier we can convert the above primal problem into the dual below (see Duality)

 

Taking first order conditions of two goods xi and xj we have

 

 

dividing through:

 

thus,

 

summing left and right hand sides over 'j' and using the fact that   we have

 

where P is a price index represented as  

Therefore, the Marshallian demand function is:

 

Under monopolistic competition, where goods are almost perfect substitutes prices are likely to be relatively close. Hence, assuming   we have:

 

From this we can see that the indirect utility function will have the form

 

hence,

 

as σ > 1 we find that utility is strictly increasing in N implying that consumers are strictly better off as variety, i.e. how many products are on offer, increases.

The derivation can also be done with a continuum of varieties, with no major difference in the approach.[2]

References edit

  1. ^ Dixit, Avinash K.; Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 1977). "Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity". The American Economic Review. American Economic Association via JSTOR. 67 (3): 297–308. JSTOR 1831401.
  2. ^ I. Dingel, Jonathan (9 June 2009). "The basics of "Dixit-Stiglitz lite"" (PDF).

Further reading edit

  • Brakman, Steven; Heijdra, Ben J., eds. (2001). The Monopolistic Competition Revolution in Retrospect. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 0-521-81991-1.

dixit, stiglitz, model, model, monopolistic, competition, developed, avinash, dixit, joseph, stiglitz, 1977, been, used, many, fields, economics, including, macroeconomics, economic, geography, international, trade, theory, model, formalises, consumers, prefer. Dixit Stiglitz model is a model of monopolistic competition developed by Avinash Dixit and Joseph Stiglitz 1977 1 It has been used in many fields of economics including macroeconomics economic geography and international trade theory The model formalises consumers preferences for product variety by using a CES function Previous attempts to provide a model that accounted for variety preference such as Harold Hotelling s location model were indirect and failed to provide an easily interpretable and usable form for further study In the Dixit Stiglitz model variety preference is inherent within the assumption of monotonic preferences because a consumer with such preferences prefers to have an average of any two bundles of goods as opposed to extremes Mathematical Derivation editThe model begins with a standard CES utility function u i 1 N x i s 1 s s s 1 displaystyle u left sum i 1 N x i frac sigma 1 sigma right frac sigma sigma 1 nbsp where N is the number of available goods xi is the quantity of good i and s is the elasticity of substitution Placing the restriction that s gt 1 ensures that preferences will be convex and thus monotonic for over any optimising range Additionally all CES functions are homogeneous of degree 1 and therefore represent homothetic preferences Additionally the consumer has a budget set defined by B x i 1 N p i x i M displaystyle B boldsymbol x sum i 1 N p i x i leq M nbsp For any rational consumer the objective is to maximise their utility functions subject to their budget constraint M which is set exogenously Such a process allows us to calculate a consumer s Marshallian Demand Mathematically this means the consumer is working to achieve max u i 1 N x i s 1 s s s 1 s t x B displaystyle max u sum i 1 N x i frac sigma 1 sigma frac sigma sigma 1 st boldsymbol x in B nbsp Since utility functions are ordinal rather than cardinal any monotonic transform of a utility function represents the same preferences Therefore the above constrained optimisation problem is analogous to max u i 1 N x i s 1 s s t x B displaystyle max u sum i 1 N x i frac sigma 1 sigma st boldsymbol x in B nbsp since f u u s 1 s displaystyle f u u frac sigma 1 sigma nbsp is strictly increasing By using a Lagrange multiplier we can convert the above primal problem into the dual below see Duality i 1 N x i s 1 s l i 1 N p i x i M displaystyle nabla sum i 1 N x i frac sigma 1 sigma lambda sum i 1 N p i x i M nbsp Taking first order conditions of two goods xi and xj we have x i s 1 s x i 1 s l p i 0 displaystyle nabla x i frac sigma 1 sigma x i frac 1 sigma lambda p i 0 nbsp x j s 1 s x j 1 s l p j 0 displaystyle nabla x j frac sigma 1 sigma x j frac 1 sigma lambda p j 0 nbsp dividing through x i x j 1 s p i p j displaystyle frac x i x j frac 1 sigma frac p i p j nbsp thus p j x j p i s x i p j 1 s displaystyle p j x j p i sigma x i p j 1 sigma nbsp summing left and right hand sides over j and using the fact that j 1 N p j x j M displaystyle sum j 1 N p j x j M nbsp we haveM p i s x i P 1 s displaystyle M p i sigma x i P 1 sigma nbsp where P is a price index represented as P j 1 N p j 1 s 1 1 s displaystyle P sum j 1 N p j 1 sigma frac 1 1 sigma nbsp Therefore the Marshallian demand function is x i M P p i P s displaystyle x i frac M P frac p i P sigma nbsp Under monopolistic competition where goods are almost perfect substitutes prices are likely to be relatively close Hence assuming p i p displaystyle p i p nbsp we have x i m p M M N p displaystyle x i m mathbf p M frac M Np nbsp From this we can see that the indirect utility function will have the formv p x i m i 1 N M N p s 1 s s s 1 displaystyle v mathbf p x i m left sum i 1 N left frac M Np right frac sigma 1 sigma right frac sigma sigma 1 nbsp hence v p x i m M p N 1 s 1 displaystyle v mathbf p x i m frac M p N frac 1 sigma 1 nbsp as s gt 1 we find that utility is strictly increasing in N implying that consumers are strictly better off as variety i e how many products are on offer increases The derivation can also be done with a continuum of varieties with no major difference in the approach 2 References edit Dixit Avinash K Stiglitz Joseph E June 1977 Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity The American Economic Review American Economic Association via JSTOR 67 3 297 308 JSTOR 1831401 I Dingel Jonathan 9 June 2009 The basics of Dixit Stiglitz lite PDF Further reading editBrakman Steven Heijdra Ben J eds 2001 The Monopolistic Competition Revolution in Retrospect Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 81991 1 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Dixit Stiglitz model amp oldid 1186257917, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.