fbpx
Wikipedia

Location model (economics)

In economics, a location model or spatial model refers to any monopolistic competition model that demonstrates consumer preference for particular brands of goods and their locations. Examples of location models include Hotelling's Location Model, Salop's Circle Model, and hybrid variations.

Traditional vs. location models edit

In traditional economic models, consumers display preference given the constraints of a product characteristic space. Consumers perceive certain brands with common characteristics to be close substitutes, and differentiate these products from their unique characteristics. For example, there are many brands of chocolate with nuts and others without them. Hence, the chocolate with nuts is a constraint of its product characteristic space.

On the other hand, consumers in location models display preference for both the utility gained from a particular brand's characteristics as well as its geographic location; these two factors form an enhanced “product characteristic space.” Consumers are now willing to sacrifice pleasure from products for a closer geographic location, and vice versa. For example, consumers realize high costs for products that are located far from their spatial point (e.g. transportation costs, time, etc.) and also for products that deviate from their ideal features. Firms have greater market power when they satisfy the consumer's demand for products at closer distance or preferred products.

Hotelling's Location Model edit

In 1929, Hotelling developed a location model that demonstrates the relationship between location and pricing behavior of firms.[1] He represented this notion through a line of fixed length. Assuming all consumers are identical (except for location) and consumers are evenly dispersed along the line, both the firms and consumer respond to changes in demand and the economic environment.

In Hotelling's Location Model, firms do not exercise variations in product characteristics; firms compete and price their products in only one dimension, geographic location. Therefore, traditional usage of this model should be used for consumers who perceive products to be perfect substitutes or as a foundation for modern location models.

An example of fixed firms edit

Assumptions edit

Assume that the line in Hotelling's location model is actually a street with fixed length.

All consumers are identical, except they are uniformly located at two equal quadrants   and  , which is divided in the center by point  . Consumers face a transportation/time cost for reaching a firm, denoted by  ; they have no preferences for the firms.

There are two firms in this scenario, Firm x and Firm y; each one is located at a different end of the street, is fixed in location and sells an identical product.

Advanced analysis edit

Given the assumptions of the Hotelling model, consumers will choose either firm as long as the combined price   and transportation cost   of the product is less than the competitive firm.

For example, if both firms sell the product at the same price  , consumers in quadrants   and   will pick the firm closest to them. The price realized by the consumer is

 , where   is the price of the product including the cost of transportation.

As long as   for Firm x is greater than Firm y, consumers will travel to Firm y to purchase their product; this minimizes  . Only the consumers who live at point  , the halfway point between the two firms, will be indifferent between the two product locations.

An example of firm relocation edit

Assumptions edit

Assume that the line in Hotelling's location model is actually a street with fixed length.

All consumers are identical, except they are uniformly located in four quadrants  ,  ,  , and  ; the halfway point between the endpoints is point  . Consumers face an equal transportation/time cost for reaching a firm, denoted by  ; they have no preferences for the firms.

There are two firms in this scenario, Firm x and Firm y; each one is located at a different end of the street, is able to relocate at no cost, and sells an identical product.

Analysis edit

In this example, Firm x and Firm y will maximize their profit by increasing their consumer pool. Firm x will move slightly toward Firm y, in order to gain Firm y's customers. In response, Firm y will move slightly toward Firm x to re-establish its loss, and increase the pool from its competitor. The cycle repeats until both firms are at point  , the halfway point of the street where each firm has the same number of customers. This result is known as Hotelling's law, however it was invalidated in 1979 by d'Aspremont, J. Jaskold Gabszewicz and J.-F. Thisse.[2] Consider that quick (short run) price adjustment and slow (long run) location adjustment is modelled as a repeated two-stage game, where in the first stage firms will make an incremental relocation and in the second period, having observed each other's new locations, they will simultaneously choose prices. d'Aspremont et al. (1979) prove that when firms are sufficiently close together (but not located in the same place) no Nash equilibrium price pair (in pure strategies) exists for the second stage subgame (because there is an incentive to undercut the rival firm's price and gain the entire market). For example, when firms are equidistant from the centre of the street, no equilibrium price pair exists for locations 1/4 or closer than 1/4 of the length of the street from the centre. The non-existence of a Cournot equilibrium precludes the ending of the game, and so it is not repeated. Thus, although both firms at the halfway point itself is an equilibrium, there is no tendency for firms to agglomerate here.

If only Firm x can relocate without costs and Firm y is fixed, Firm x will move to the side of Firm y where the consumer pool is maximized. Consequently, the profits for Firm X significantly increase, while the profits for Firm Y significantly decrease.

Salop's Circle Model edit

One of the most famous variations of Hotelling's location model is Salop's circle model.[3] Similar to the previous spatial representations, the circle model examines consumer preference with regards to geographic location. However, Salop introduces two significant factors: 1) firms are located around a circle with no end-points, and 2) it allows the consumer to choose a second, heterogeneous good.

An example of a second good edit

Assumptions edit

Assume that the consumers are equidistant from one another around the circle. The model will occur for one time period, in which only one product is purchased. The consumer will have a choice of purchasing variations of Product A (a differentiated product) or Product B (an outside good; undifferentiated product).

There are two firms also located equidistant around the circle. Each firm offers a variation of Product A, and an outside firm offers a good, Product B.

Analysis edit

In this example, the consumer wants to purchase their ideal variation of Product A. They are willing to purchase the product, given that it is within the constraint of their utility, transportation/distance costs, and price.

The utility   for a particular product at distance   is represented in the following equation:

 

Where   is the utility from a superior brand,   denotes the rate at which an inferior brand lowers the utility from the superior brand,   is the location of the superior brand, and   is the location of the consumer. The distance between the brand and the consumer is thereby given in  .

The consumer's primary goal is to maximize consumer surplus, i.e. purchase the product that best satisfies any combination of price and quality. Although the consumer may receive more pleasure from their superior brand, the inferior brand may maximize the surplus   which is given by:

 , where the difference is between the utility of a product at location   and the price  .

Now suppose the consumer also has the option to purchase an outside, undifferentiated Product B. The consumer surplus gained from Product B is denoted by  .

Therefore, for a given amount of money, the consumer will purchase the superior variation of Product A over Product B as long as

 , where the consumer surplus from the superior variation of Product A is greater than the consumer surplus gained from Product B.

Alternatively, the consumer only purchases the superior variation of product A as long as

 , where the difference between the surplus of the superior variation of Product A and the surplus gained from Product B is positive.

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Hotelling, Harold (1929), "Stability in Competition", Economic Journal, 39 (153): 41–57, doi:10.2307/2224214, JSTOR 2224214
  2. ^ d'Aspremont, C.; Gabszewicz, J. Jaskold; Thisse, J.-F. (1979). "On Hotelling's "Stability in Competition"". Econometrica. 47 (5): 1145–1150. doi:10.2307/1911955. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 1911955.
  3. ^ Salop, Steven C. (1979), "Monopolistic competition with outside goods", The Bell Journal of Economics, 10 (1): 141–156, doi:10.2307/3003323, JSTOR 3003323

External links edit

  • The Hotelling-Downs Model of Spatial/Political Competition

location, model, economics, location, model, redirects, here, confused, with, location, model, statistics, this, article, needs, additional, citations, verification, please, help, improve, this, article, adding, citations, reliable, sources, unsourced, materia. Location model redirects here Not to be confused with Location model statistics This article needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Location model economics news newspapers books scholar JSTOR January 2021 Learn how and when to remove this template message In economics a location model or spatial model refers to any monopolistic competition model that demonstrates consumer preference for particular brands of goods and their locations Examples of location models include Hotelling s Location Model Salop s Circle Model and hybrid variations Contents 1 Traditional vs location models 2 Hotelling s Location Model 2 1 An example of fixed firms 2 1 1 Assumptions 2 1 2 Advanced analysis 2 2 An example of firm relocation 2 2 1 Assumptions 2 2 2 Analysis 3 Salop s Circle Model 3 1 An example of a second good 3 1 1 Assumptions 3 1 2 Analysis 4 See also 5 References 6 External linksTraditional vs location models editIn traditional economic models consumers display preference given the constraints of a product characteristic space Consumers perceive certain brands with common characteristics to be close substitutes and differentiate these products from their unique characteristics For example there are many brands of chocolate with nuts and others without them Hence the chocolate with nuts is a constraint of its product characteristic space On the other hand consumers in location models display preference for both the utility gained from a particular brand s characteristics as well as its geographic location these two factors form an enhanced product characteristic space Consumers are now willing to sacrifice pleasure from products for a closer geographic location and vice versa For example consumers realize high costs for products that are located far from their spatial point e g transportation costs time etc and also for products that deviate from their ideal features Firms have greater market power when they satisfy the consumer s demand for products at closer distance or preferred products Hotelling s Location Model editIn 1929 Hotelling developed a location model that demonstrates the relationship between location and pricing behavior of firms 1 He represented this notion through a line of fixed length Assuming all consumers are identical except for location and consumers are evenly dispersed along the line both the firms and consumer respond to changes in demand and the economic environment In Hotelling s Location Model firms do not exercise variations in product characteristics firms compete and price their products in only one dimension geographic location Therefore traditional usage of this model should be used for consumers who perceive products to be perfect substitutes or as a foundation for modern location models An example of fixed firms edit Assumptions edit Assume that the line in Hotelling s location model is actually a street with fixed length All consumers are identical except they are uniformly located at two equal quadrants a displaystyle a nbsp and b displaystyle b nbsp which is divided in the center by point o displaystyle o nbsp Consumers face a transportation time cost for reaching a firm denoted by c displaystyle c nbsp they have no preferences for the firms There are two firms in this scenario Firm x and Firm y each one is located at a different end of the street is fixed in location and sells an identical product Advanced analysis edit Given the assumptions of the Hotelling model consumers will choose either firm as long as the combined price P displaystyle P nbsp and transportation cost c displaystyle c nbsp of the product is less than the competitive firm For example if both firms sell the product at the same price P displaystyle P nbsp consumers in quadrants a displaystyle a nbsp and b displaystyle b nbsp will pick the firm closest to them The price realized by the consumer isP c P 1 displaystyle P c P1 nbsp where P 1 displaystyle P1 nbsp is the price of the product including the cost of transportation As long as c displaystyle c nbsp for Firm x is greater than Firm y consumers will travel to Firm y to purchase their product this minimizes P 1 displaystyle P1 nbsp Only the consumers who live at point o displaystyle o nbsp the halfway point between the two firms will be indifferent between the two product locations An example of firm relocation edit Assumptions edit Assume that the line in Hotelling s location model is actually a street with fixed length All consumers are identical except they are uniformly located in four quadrants a displaystyle a nbsp b displaystyle b nbsp c displaystyle c nbsp and d displaystyle d nbsp the halfway point between the endpoints is point o displaystyle o nbsp Consumers face an equal transportation time cost for reaching a firm denoted by c displaystyle c nbsp they have no preferences for the firms There are two firms in this scenario Firm x and Firm y each one is located at a different end of the street is able to relocate at no cost and sells an identical product Analysis edit In this example Firm x and Firm y will maximize their profit by increasing their consumer pool Firm x will move slightly toward Firm y in order to gain Firm y s customers In response Firm y will move slightly toward Firm x to re establish its loss and increase the pool from its competitor The cycle repeats until both firms are at point o displaystyle o nbsp the halfway point of the street where each firm has the same number of customers This result is known as Hotelling s law however it was invalidated in 1979 by d Aspremont J Jaskold Gabszewicz and J F Thisse 2 Consider that quick short run price adjustment and slow long run location adjustment is modelled as a repeated two stage game where in the first stage firms will make an incremental relocation and in the second period having observed each other s new locations they will simultaneously choose prices d Aspremont et al 1979 prove that when firms are sufficiently close together but not located in the same place no Nash equilibrium price pair in pure strategies exists for the second stage subgame because there is an incentive to undercut the rival firm s price and gain the entire market For example when firms are equidistant from the centre of the street no equilibrium price pair exists for locations 1 4 or closer than 1 4 of the length of the street from the centre The non existence of a Cournot equilibrium precludes the ending of the game and so it is not repeated Thus although both firms at the halfway point itself is an equilibrium there is no tendency for firms to agglomerate here If only Firm x can relocate without costs and Firm y is fixed Firm x will move to the side of Firm y where the consumer pool is maximized Consequently the profits for Firm X significantly increase while the profits for Firm Y significantly decrease Salop s Circle Model editOne of the most famous variations of Hotelling s location model is Salop s circle model 3 Similar to the previous spatial representations the circle model examines consumer preference with regards to geographic location However Salop introduces two significant factors 1 firms are located around a circle with no end points and 2 it allows the consumer to choose a second heterogeneous good An example of a second good edit Assumptions edit Assume that the consumers are equidistant from one another around the circle The model will occur for one time period in which only one product is purchased The consumer will have a choice of purchasing variations of Product A a differentiated product or Product B an outside good undifferentiated product There are two firms also located equidistant around the circle Each firm offers a variation of Product A and an outside firm offers a good Product B Analysis edit In this example the consumer wants to purchase their ideal variation of Product A They are willing to purchase the product given that it is within the constraint of their utility transportation distance costs and price The utility u displaystyle u nbsp for a particular product at distance d displaystyle d nbsp is represented in the following equation U d d 1 u r d d 1 displaystyle U d d 1 u r d d 1 nbsp Where u displaystyle u nbsp is the utility from a superior brand r displaystyle r nbsp denotes the rate at which an inferior brand lowers the utility from the superior brand d displaystyle d nbsp is the location of the superior brand and d 1 displaystyle d 1 nbsp is the location of the consumer The distance between the brand and the consumer is thereby given in d d 1 displaystyle d d 1 nbsp The consumer s primary goal is to maximize consumer surplus i e purchase the product that best satisfies any combination of price and quality Although the consumer may receive more pleasure from their superior brand the inferior brand may maximize the surplus C S displaystyle CS nbsp which is given by U d d 1 P C S displaystyle U d d 1 P CS nbsp where the difference is between the utility of a product at location d displaystyle d nbsp and the price P displaystyle P nbsp Now suppose the consumer also has the option to purchase an outside undifferentiated Product B The consumer surplus gained from Product B is denoted by u displaystyle u nbsp Therefore for a given amount of money the consumer will purchase the superior variation of Product A over Product B as long asU d d 1 P u displaystyle U d d 1 P geq u nbsp where the consumer surplus from the superior variation of Product A is greater than the consumer surplus gained from Product B Alternatively the consumer only purchases the superior variation of product A as long asu u r d d 1 P 0 displaystyle u u r d d 1 P geq 0 nbsp where the difference between the surplus of the superior variation of Product A and the surplus gained from Product B is positive See also editEconomics Economic geography Location theory Microeconomics Industrial organization Retail geography Hyperbolic discounting Hotelling s location modelReferences edit Hotelling Harold 1929 Stability in Competition Economic Journal 39 153 41 57 doi 10 2307 2224214 JSTOR 2224214 d Aspremont C Gabszewicz J Jaskold Thisse J F 1979 On Hotelling s Stability in Competition Econometrica 47 5 1145 1150 doi 10 2307 1911955 ISSN 0012 9682 JSTOR 1911955 Salop Steven C 1979 Monopolistic competition with outside goods The Bell Journal of Economics 10 1 141 156 doi 10 2307 3003323 JSTOR 3003323External links editThe Hotelling Downs Model of Spatial Political Competition Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Location model economics amp oldid 1163579620, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.