fbpx
Wikipedia

Icelandic Commonwealth

The Icelandic Commonwealth,[a] also known as the Icelandic Free State, was the political unit existing in Iceland between the establishment of the Althing in 930 and the pledge of fealty to the Norwegian king with the Old Covenant in 1262. With the probable exception of hermitic Irish monks known as Papar, Iceland was an uninhabited island until around 874.

Icelandic Commonwealth
Þjóðveldið Ísland (Icelandic)
c. 930–1262
Map of Iceland by Abraham Ortelius (c. 1590)
StatusCommonwealth
CapitalÞingvellir
Common languagesOld Norse (later Old Icelandic)
Religion
Demonym(s)Norse: Icelandic
Important chieftains (goðar) 
• 1199–1238
Sturla Sighvatsson
• 1208–1245
Kolbeinn ungi Arnórsson
• 1210–1256
Þórður kakali Sighvatsson
• 1208–1268
Gissur Þorvaldsson
• 1214–1284
Sturla Þórðarson
Lawspeaker 
• 985–1001
Þorgeir Ljósvetningagoði
• 1004–1030
Skapti Þóroddsson
• 1031–1033
Steinn Þorgestsson
• 1034–1053
Þorkell Tjörvason
• 1054–1062/1072–1074
Gellir Bolverksson
• 1063–1065/1075
Gunnar Þorgrímsson the Wise
• 1066–1071
Kolbeinn Flosason
• 1076–1083
Sighvatur Surtsson
• 1084–1107
Markús Skeggjason
• 1108–1116
Úlfhéðinn Gunnarsson
• 1117–1122
Bergþór Hrafnsson
• 1215–1218/1222–1231
Snorri Sturluson
• 1248–1250/1252
Ólafur Þórðarson
• 1251
Sturla Þórðarson
LegislatureLögrétta of Alþingi
Historical eraHigh Middle Ages
• Alþingi established
c. 930
• Norwegian kingship
1262
ISO 3166 codeIS
Succeeded by
Today part ofIceland

The Icelandic Commonwealth had a unique political system whereby chieftains (goðar) established a common legal code and settled judicial disputes at the Althing, a national assembly.[1] However, there was no executive body in Iceland that enforced the legal code.[1] The Icelandic Commonwealth has consequently been characterized as a stateless society.[2][3] During the 13th century, Iceland came under the control of the Norwegian Kingdom.[1]

Goðorð system edit

The medieval Icelandic state had a unique judicial structure. The first settlers of Iceland were greatly influenced by their Norwegian roots when creating their own form of government. They wanted to avoid the strong centralized authority of Harald Fairhair from which some of them had fled, but they also wanted to replicate the Norwegian tradition of laws and district legal assemblies (Þing). This created a unique structure.[4][dubious ]

The most powerful and elite leaders in Iceland were the chieftains (sing. goði, pl. goðar). The office of the goði was called the goðorð. The goðorð was not delimited by strict geographical boundaries. Thus, a free man could choose to support any of the goðar of his district. The supporters of the goðar were called Þingmenn ("assembly people"). In exchange for the goði protecting his interests, the Þingmaðr would provide armed support to his goði during feuds or conflicts. The Þingmenn were also required to attend regional and national assemblies.[5]

On a regional level, the goðar of the thirteen district assemblies convened meetings every spring to settle local disputes. The goðar also served as the leaders of the Alþingi, the national assembly of Iceland. Today, the Alþingi is the oldest parliamentary institution in existence. It began with the regional assembly at Kjalarness established by Þorsteinn Ingólfsson, son of the first settler. The leaders of the Kjalarnessþing appointed a man named Úlfljótr to study the laws in Norway. He spent three years in Norway and returned with the foundation of Úlfljótr's Law, which would form the basis for Iceland's national assembly. Sections of his law code are preserved in the Landnámabók, ("Book of Settlements"). The first Alþingi assembly convened around the year 930 at Þingvellir, ("Assembly Plains"). The Alþingi served as a public gathering at which people from all over the country met for two weeks every June. The Alþingi revolved around the Lögrétta, the legislative council of the assembly, which was responsible for reviewing and amending the nation's laws. The Lögrétta comprised the 39 goðar and their advisors. They also appointed a Lawspeaker (lögsögumaður) once every three years. The Lawspeaker recited and clarified laws at Lögberg ("Law Rock"), located at the center of Þingvellir.[6] The descendants of Ingólfr Arnarson, the first settler of Iceland, held the ceremonial position of allsherjargoði and had the role of sanctifying the Alþingi each year.

Court system edit

Iceland was divided into four administrative regions called fjörðungar (farthings). Each of these was ruled by nine goðar. The Alþingi was made up of the four Quarter Courts (fjórðungsdómur). This judicial body of Iceland consisted of 36 judges, each appointed by one of the goðar. These courts tried individual cases and served as a higher judicial authority to the regional courts. The rulings of the quarter judges had to be agreed upon by a strong majority: if only six of the judges disagreed, then the case was deadlocked and dismissed. In 1005, this problem was solved by the creation of a Fifth Court, an appeals court based on a simple majority. Once a court decided a party was guilty, however, it had no executive authority to carry out a sentence. Instead, enforcement of a verdict became the responsibility of the injured party or his family.

Penalties often included financial compensation or outlawry. However, these were considered by some to be insufficient penalties and the Alþingi was only moderately successful at stopping feuds.[7] According to Magnus Magnusson, the courts were "an uneasy substitute for vengeance." The most severe punishments were outlawry and three years' exile. Outlaws lost all property rights and could be killed without any punishment for the killers. Exiles who failed to leave Iceland became outlaws.[8]

Historian Birgir Solvason states that Icelandic society was "more peaceful and cooperative than its contemporaries".[citation needed] In England and Norway, by contrast, "the period from about 800 to 1200 is a period of continuous struggle; high in both violence and killings".[citation needed] Historian Jón Viðar Sigurðsson argues that the introduction of Christianity to Iceland illustrates how effective and significant arbitration was in Iceland.[9] At the Christianisation of Iceland in 1000, the Alþingi outlawed public celebration of pagan rituals and decreed that in order to prevent an invasion, all Icelanders must be baptized.[citation needed]

In 1117, the law code of the Icelandic Commonwealth was put into writing, becoming known as the Gray Goose Laws.

Life within the system edit

Knowledge of the system of government in medieval Iceland stems mainly from two main primary sources: the written law code, and Íslendingabók,[10] or the Book of the Icelanders by Ari the Learned. The impact of the legislative and judicial systems on Icelandic settlers is a common theme in many of the other Icelandic sagas. Works such as Njáls saga and the Laxdæla saga give many details, but their accuracy has been disputed. Eyrbyggja saga details the transition from paganism to Christianity within Icelandic settlement under the direction of Snorri Goði, or "Snorri the Priest." The emphasis on justice and the conviction in their system of governance is reflected within the saga: "They say we shall suffer setbacks in court; we must plead for support from powerful chieftains: but Arnkel will argue an eloquent case, he will sway judge and jury – I have faith in justice."[11]

Chieftains were highly reliant on the support of farmers in their domain in the 11th and 12th centuries, and did thus not have princely powers or subjects in the districts that they represented.[12] Around 1190, the number of chieftaincies declined and power started to centralize in individual chieftains controlling larger regions of the country.[13] By ca 1220, the country was a loose federation of 10–12 regional powers.[14]

According to historian Jón Viðar Sigurðsson, "a chieftain based his power on his personal qualities, his wealth, friends, assembly men, kinsmen and in-laws. The cleverest, the most helpful, the wealthiest and the most generous became the most powerful ones."[15] Historian Árni Daniel Júliusson further notes that the food production of the peasantry was the "basis of political and military power".[16]

Peasant rebellions, traditionally defined, never occurred in Iceland, even though peasant unrest was fairly common.[16]

Slavery was practiced in Iceland from settlement to the early 12th century. Icelandic law allowed individuals guilty of theft or failure to pay debts to be enslaved. Slaves were allowed to marry and have children, which meant that a class of slaves could self-perpetuate. Slavery likely declined in the second half of the 12th century and was extremely rare by the 15th century.[17]

Warfare edit

The followers of the goðar owed them military service. They were organized into platoons or companies based on their social status and equipment, and these formed expeditionary armies or leiðangrs. Icelandic military tradition of the time closely followed developments in Norway. No organized cavalry formations or formations of troops equipped with projectile weapons are recorded: instead the bulk of the forces were formed in units of light, medium and heavy infantry, with bowmen or slingers distributed among the infantry units, operating as light support skirmishers. Before the end of the Commonwealth, at least 21 fortresses and castles had been built in Iceland.[18] During the Age of the Sturlungs, the average battle involved fewer than 1000 men, with an average casualty rate of only 15%. This relatively low casualty rate might be attributed to the blood-feud mentality which permeated Icelandic society, which meant that the defeated army could not honourably be slaughtered to a man.[19]

Religion edit

The first Bishop of Skalholt was Ísleifur Gissurarson, who was elected by the Althing in 1056. After his son Gissur was installed as bishop, the power and wealth of the church quickly grew due to the introduction of tithing, the first tax introduced in Iceland. The church became the second unifying institution in the country after the Althing. Continuing similar patterns from the pre-Christian era, church estates could be owned by goðar who would then get a portion of the tithe.[20]

Decline and fall edit

In the early 13th century, the Age of the Sturlungs, the Commonwealth began to suffer from chaos and division resulting from internal disputes. Originally, the goðar (chieftains) functioned more as a contractual relationship than a fixed geographic chieftaincy. However, by 1220 this form of communal leadership was replaced by dominant regional individuals who battled with one another for more control. One historian argues the chaos and violence of this period stem from an imbalance of power and changes in the nature of Icelandic warfare. Whereas the number of goðar had been at least 39 early in the Icelandic Commonwealth, a few powerful families had consolidated control over most of the goðorð in the late 12th century.[21]

There are several factors that may have resulted in the consolidation of goðorð. The separation of secular and ecclesiastical power led some families and regional networks to become stronger at the expense of others, leading to an imbalance of power.[22] The introduction of tithe may have increased the wealth of chieftains that controlled the churches.[21] The introduction of pitched battles and harassment of farmers on a regional basis raised the stakes and dangers, which may have incentivized consolidation.[22] An increase in population along with a resource shortage may have made commoners more dependent on chieftains.[21]

The King of Norway began to exert pressure on his Icelandic vassals to bring the country under his rule. He commissioned Icelandic chieftains to become part of his body of retainers and to pursue his interests in Iceland.[21] The King's role in Icelandic affairs started in 1220, and had become strong by 1240 (Icelanders were starting to accept the King's choice of chieftains).[23][24] Over the period 1240–1260, the King consolidated power in Iceland.[23] A combination of discontent with domestic hostilities and pressure from the King of Norway led the Icelandic chieftains to accept Norway's Haakon IV as king by the signing of the Gamli sáttmáli ("Old Covenant") in 1262. According to historian Sverrir Jakobsson, three Icelanders played a central role in bringing Iceland under the King of Norway: Gissur Þorvaldsson (for getting farmers to agree to pay taxes to the King), Hrafn Oddsson (for pressuring Gissur into supporting the King, and getting farmers in the Westfjords to submit to the King) and bishop Brandur Jónsson (for getting his relatives in the East Fjords to submit to the King).[25]

By 1264, all Icelandic chieftains had sworn allegiance to the King of Norway.[26] The end of the Icelandic Commonwealth is typically dated to the Old Covenant (1262–1264) or to the adoption of Jónsbók in 1281.[1]

Contemporary libertarian perspectives edit

According to the libertarian theorist David D. Friedman, "Medieval Icelandic institutions have several peculiar and interesting characteristics; they might almost have been invented by a mad economist to test the lengths to which market systems could supplant government in its most fundamental functions."[27] While not directly labeling it anarcho-capitalist, he argues that the legal system came close to being a real-world anarcho-capitalist legal system.[28] Although noting that there was a single legal system, Friedman argues that enforcement of the law was entirely private and highly capitalist, providing some evidence of how such a society would function. "Even where the Icelandic legal system recognized an essentially 'public' offense, it dealt with it by giving some individual (in some cases chosen by lot from those affected) the right to pursue the case and collect the resulting fine, thus fitting it into an essentially private system."[27] Commenting on its political structure, libertarian scholar Roderick Long remarks:

The legal system's administration, insofar as it had one, lay in the hands of a parliament of about 40 officers whom historians call, however inadequately, "chieftains". This parliament had no budget and no employees; it met only two weeks per year. In addition to their parliamentary role, chieftains were empowered in their own local districts to appoint judges and to keep the peace; this latter job was handled on an essentially fee-for-service basis. The enforcement of judicial decisions was largely a matter of self-help (hence Iceland's reputation as a land of constant private feuding), but those who lacked the might to enforce their rights could sell their court-decreed claims for compensation to someone more powerful, usually a chieftain; hence even the poor and friendless could not be victimized with impunity. The basis of a chieftain's power within the political order was the power he already possessed outside it, in civil society. The office of chieftaincy was private property, and could be bought or sold; hence chieftaincies tended to track private wealth. But wealth alone was not enough. As economic historian Birgir Solvason notes in his masterful study of the period, "just buying the chieftainship was no guarantee of power"; the mere office by itself was "almost worthless" unless the chieftain could "convince some free-farmers to follow him". Chieftains did not hold authority over territorially-defined districts, but competed for clients with other chieftains from the same geographical area.[29]

Summarizing his research, Friedman concludes in part:[30]

It is difficult to draw any conclusion from the Icelandic experience concerning the viability of systems of private enforcement in the twentieth century. Even if Icelandic institutions worked well then, they might not work in a larger and more interdependent society. And whether the Icelandic institutions did work well is a matter of controversy; the sagas are perceived by many as portraying an essentially violent and unjust society, tormented by constant feuding. It is difficult to tell whether such judgments are correct."[27]

A 2021 study by economists Vincent Geloso and Peter T. Leeson concluded that:

The data available for comparing living standards in Iceland and other territories in medieval Europe—data on human height, wages, and population growth—are sparse, crude, and therefore challenging to interpret. But a basic picture is apparent nonetheless and suggests a negative conclusion if not a positive one. Living standards in state-governed medieval Europe do not seem to have been higher than they were in Iceland. Anarcho-capitalists, it seems, are not insane.[30]

Friedman and Bruce L. Benson argued that the Icelandic Commonwealth saw significant economic and social progress in the absence of systems of criminal law, an executive, or bureaucracy.[31]

See also edit

Citations edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ Icelandic: Þjóðveldið Ísland, [ˈθjouːðˌvɛltɪθ]; Old Norse: Íslands þjóðveldi

References edit

  1. ^ a b c d Jakobsson, Sverrir (2021). "All the King's men. The incorporation of Iceland into the Norwegian Realm". Scandinavian Journal of History. 46 (5): 571–592. doi:10.1080/03468755.2021.1961856. ISSN 0346-8755. S2CID 238770622. from the original on 20 August 2023. Retrieved 8 August 2021.
  2. ^ Jakobsson, Sverrir (2010). "Heaven is a Place on Earth: Church and Sacred Space in Thirteenth-Century Iceland". Scandinavian Studies. 82 (1): 1–20. doi:10.2307/40920892. ISSN 0036-5637. JSTOR 40920892. S2CID 159404976. from the original on 9 January 2022. Retrieved 9 January 2022.
  3. ^ Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990). Economic Behavior and Institutions: Principles of Neoinstitutional Economics. Cambridge University Press. p. 305. ISBN 978-0-521-34891-1. from the original on 20 August 2023. Retrieved 9 January 2022.
  4. ^ Jon A. Hjaltalin (1 January 1868). "the Civilisation of the First Icelandic Colonists, with a short account of some of their manners and customs". JSTOR 3014256. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  5. ^ Short, William Rhuel. Icelanders in the Viking Age: The People of the Sagas. Jefferson, NC: McFarland &, 2010. Print.
  6. ^ Guðmundur, Hálfdanarson. Historical Dictionary of Iceland. Lanham, MD: Scarecrow, 2008. Print.
  7. ^ Karlsson, Gunnar. The History of Iceland. Minneapolis Minn.: Univ. of Minneapolis, 2000. Print.
  8. ^ Sigurðsson, Jón Viðar (1999). Chieftains and Power in the Icelandic Commonwealth. p. 168.
  9. ^ Sigurðsson, Jón Viðar (1999). Chieftains and Power in the Icelandic Commonwealth. p. 170.
  10. ^ GRØNLIE, SIÂN (2006). "ÍSLENDINGABÓK — KRISTNI SAGA: THE BOOK OF THE ICELANDERS — THE STORY OF THE CONVERSION" (PDF). (PDF) from the original on 12 April 2013. Retrieved 13 February 2015. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  11. ^ Palsson, Herman, and Paul Edwards. Eyrbyggja Saga. Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1989. Print.
  12. ^ Jakobsson, Sverrir (2016). Auðnaróðal. Sögufélag. p. 13.
  13. ^ Jakobsson, Sverrir (2016). Auðnaróðal. Sögufélag. p. 145.
  14. ^ "Hvers vegna féll þjóðveldið?". Vísindavefurinn. from the original on 29 January 2017. Retrieved 2 January 2017.
  15. ^ Sigurðsson, Jón Viðar (1999). Chieftains and Power in the Icelandic Commonwealth. p. 211.
  16. ^ a b Júliusson, Árni Daniel. "Peasant Unrest in Iceland". www.academia.edu. Retrieved 12 February 2016.
  17. ^ Jakobsson, Sverrir. "Frá þrælahaldi til landeigendavalds: Íslenskt miðaldasamfélag, 1100–1400". from the original on 20 August 2023. Retrieved 3 January 2017. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  18. ^ Birgir Loftsson (2006), Hernaðarsaga Íslands : 1170–1581, Pjaxi. Reykjavík; pg. 76
  19. ^ Birgir Loftsson op.cit.
  20. ^ Fridrikson, Fridrik (August 1982). "The Rise and Decline of the Icelandic Commonwealth" (PDF). (PDF) from the original on 14 October 2020. Retrieved 5 October 2020.
  21. ^ a b c d Bagge, Sverre (2014). Cross and Scepter: The Rise of the Scandinavian Kingdoms from the Vikings to the Reformation. Princeton University Press. p. 45. ISBN 978-1-4008-5010-5. from the original on 23 April 2023. Retrieved 2 January 2022.
  22. ^ a b Jakobsson, Sverrir (2001). "The Process of State-Formation in Medieval Iceland". www.academia.edu. from the original on 20 August 2023. Retrieved 18 January 2016.
  23. ^ a b Sigurðsson, Jón Viðar (1999). Chieftains and Power in the Icelandic Commonwealth. pp. 208–216.
  24. ^ Sigurdsson, Jon Vidar (2017). Viking Friendship: The Social Bond in Iceland and Norway, c. 900–1300. Cornell University Press. p. 71. ISBN 978-1-5017-0848-0. from the original on 2 May 2023. Retrieved 3 January 2022.
  25. ^ Jakobsson, Sverrir (2016). Auðnaróðal. Sögufélag. p. 255.
  26. ^ Karlsson, Gunnar (2000). The History of Iceland. pp. 82–83.
  27. ^ a b c Friedman, David (1979). "Private Creation and Enforcement of Law: A Historical Case". The Journal of Legal Studies. 8 (2): 399–415. doi:10.1086/467615. ISSN 0047-2530. S2CID 59062557. from the original on 18 April 2021. Retrieved 30 December 2016.
  28. ^ Friedman, David D. (28 February 2015). "Private Law Enforcement, Medieval Iceland, and Libertarianism". The Machinery of Freedom (3rd ed.). pp. 203–204. ISBN 978-1507785607.
  29. ^ "The Vikings Were Libertarians". Lew Rockwell. from the original on 8 December 2015. Retrieved 14 September 2015.
  30. ^ a b Geloso, Vincent; Leeson, Peter T. (2021). "Are Anarcho-Capitalists Insane? Medieval Icelandic Conflict Institutions in Comparative Perspective" (PDF). Revue d'économie politique. 130 (6): 957–974. doi:10.3917/redp.306.0115. ISSN 0373-2630. S2CID 235008718. (PDF) from the original on 19 April 2021. Retrieved 12 April 2023.
  31. ^ Costa, Daniel (21 October 2022). "Anarcho-capitalism". Encyclopædia Britannica. from the original on 25 October 2022. Retrieved 25 October 2022.

External links edit

  • Medieval Iceland: Society, Sagas, and Power by Jesse L. Byock


65°N 18°W / 65°N 18°W / 65; -18

icelandic, commonwealth, also, known, icelandic, free, state, political, unit, existing, iceland, between, establishment, althing, pledge, fealty, norwegian, king, with, covenant, 1262, with, probable, exception, hermitic, irish, monks, known, papar, iceland, . The Icelandic Commonwealth a also known as the Icelandic Free State was the political unit existing in Iceland between the establishment of the Althing in 930 and the pledge of fealty to the Norwegian king with the Old Covenant in 1262 With the probable exception of hermitic Irish monks known as Papar Iceland was an uninhabited island until around 874 Icelandic CommonwealthTHjodveldid Island Icelandic c 930 1262Map of Iceland by Abraham Ortelius c 1590 StatusCommonwealthCapitalTHingvellirCommon languagesOld Norse later Old Icelandic ReligionOld Norse religion state before 1000 Roman Catholicism state after 1000 godlauss lack of faith in any deity Demonym s Norse IcelandicImportant chieftains godar 1199 1238Sturla Sighvatsson 1208 1245Kolbeinn ungi Arnorsson 1210 1256THordur kakali Sighvatsson 1208 1268Gissur THorvaldsson 1214 1284Sturla THordarsonLawspeaker 985 1001THorgeir Ljosvetningagodi 1004 1030Skapti THoroddsson 1031 1033Steinn THorgestsson 1034 1053THorkell Tjorvason 1054 1062 1072 1074Gellir Bolverksson 1063 1065 1075Gunnar THorgrimsson the Wise 1066 1071Kolbeinn Flosason 1076 1083Sighvatur Surtsson 1084 1107Markus Skeggjason 1108 1116Ulfhedinn Gunnarsson 1117 1122Bergthor Hrafnsson 1215 1218 1222 1231Snorri Sturluson 1248 1250 1252olafur THordarson 1251Sturla THordarsonLegislatureLogretta of AlthingiHistorical eraHigh Middle Ages Althingi establishedc 930 Norwegian kingship1262ISO 3166 codeISSucceeded byKingdom of NorwayToday part ofIcelandThe Icelandic Commonwealth had a unique political system whereby chieftains godar established a common legal code and settled judicial disputes at the Althing a national assembly 1 However there was no executive body in Iceland that enforced the legal code 1 The Icelandic Commonwealth has consequently been characterized as a stateless society 2 3 During the 13th century Iceland came under the control of the Norwegian Kingdom 1 Contents 1 Godord system 2 Court system 2 1 Life within the system 3 Warfare 4 Religion 5 Decline and fall 6 Contemporary libertarian perspectives 7 See also 8 Citations 8 1 Notes 8 2 References 9 External linksGodord system editMain article Godi The medieval Icelandic state had a unique judicial structure The first settlers of Iceland were greatly influenced by their Norwegian roots when creating their own form of government They wanted to avoid the strong centralized authority of Harald Fairhair from which some of them had fled but they also wanted to replicate the Norwegian tradition of laws and district legal assemblies THing This created a unique structure 4 dubious discuss The most powerful and elite leaders in Iceland were the chieftains sing godi pl godar The office of the godi was called the godord The godord was not delimited by strict geographical boundaries Thus a free man could choose to support any of the godar of his district The supporters of the godar were called THingmenn assembly people In exchange for the godi protecting his interests the THingmadr would provide armed support to his godi during feuds or conflicts The THingmenn were also required to attend regional and national assemblies 5 On a regional level the godar of the thirteen district assemblies convened meetings every spring to settle local disputes The godar also served as the leaders of the Althingi the national assembly of Iceland Today the Althingi is the oldest parliamentary institution in existence It began with the regional assembly at Kjalarness established by THorsteinn Ingolfsson son of the first settler The leaders of the Kjalarnessthing appointed a man named Ulfljotr to study the laws in Norway He spent three years in Norway and returned with the foundation of Ulfljotr s Law which would form the basis for Iceland s national assembly Sections of his law code are preserved in the Landnamabok Book of Settlements The first Althingi assembly convened around the year 930 at THingvellir Assembly Plains The Althingi served as a public gathering at which people from all over the country met for two weeks every June The Althingi revolved around the Logretta the legislative council of the assembly which was responsible for reviewing and amending the nation s laws The Logretta comprised the 39 godar and their advisors They also appointed a Lawspeaker logsogumadur once every three years The Lawspeaker recited and clarified laws at Logberg Law Rock located at the center of THingvellir 6 The descendants of Ingolfr Arnarson the first settler of Iceland held the ceremonial position of allsherjargodi and had the role of sanctifying the Althingi each year Court system editIceland was divided into four administrative regions called fjordungar farthings Each of these was ruled by nine godar The Althingi was made up of the four Quarter Courts fjordungsdomur This judicial body of Iceland consisted of 36 judges each appointed by one of the godar These courts tried individual cases and served as a higher judicial authority to the regional courts The rulings of the quarter judges had to be agreed upon by a strong majority if only six of the judges disagreed then the case was deadlocked and dismissed In 1005 this problem was solved by the creation of a Fifth Court an appeals court based on a simple majority Once a court decided a party was guilty however it had no executive authority to carry out a sentence Instead enforcement of a verdict became the responsibility of the injured party or his family Penalties often included financial compensation or outlawry However these were considered by some to be insufficient penalties and the Althingi was only moderately successful at stopping feuds 7 According to Magnus Magnusson the courts were an uneasy substitute for vengeance The most severe punishments were outlawry and three years exile Outlaws lost all property rights and could be killed without any punishment for the killers Exiles who failed to leave Iceland became outlaws 8 Historian Birgir Solvason states that Icelandic society was more peaceful and cooperative than its contemporaries citation needed In England and Norway by contrast the period from about 800 to 1200 is a period of continuous struggle high in both violence and killings citation needed Historian Jon Vidar Sigurdsson argues that the introduction of Christianity to Iceland illustrates how effective and significant arbitration was in Iceland 9 At the Christianisation of Iceland in 1000 the Althingi outlawed public celebration of pagan rituals and decreed that in order to prevent an invasion all Icelanders must be baptized citation needed In 1117 the law code of the Icelandic Commonwealth was put into writing becoming known as the Gray Goose Laws Life within the system edit Knowledge of the system of government in medieval Iceland stems mainly from two main primary sources the written law code and Islendingabok 10 or the Book of the Icelanders by Ari the Learned The impact of the legislative and judicial systems on Icelandic settlers is a common theme in many of the other Icelandic sagas Works such as Njals saga and the Laxdaela saga give many details but their accuracy has been disputed Eyrbyggja saga details the transition from paganism to Christianity within Icelandic settlement under the direction of Snorri Godi or Snorri the Priest The emphasis on justice and the conviction in their system of governance is reflected within the saga They say we shall suffer setbacks in court we must plead for support from powerful chieftains but Arnkel will argue an eloquent case he will sway judge and jury I have faith in justice 11 Chieftains were highly reliant on the support of farmers in their domain in the 11th and 12th centuries and did thus not have princely powers or subjects in the districts that they represented 12 Around 1190 the number of chieftaincies declined and power started to centralize in individual chieftains controlling larger regions of the country 13 By ca 1220 the country was a loose federation of 10 12 regional powers 14 According to historian Jon Vidar Sigurdsson a chieftain based his power on his personal qualities his wealth friends assembly men kinsmen and in laws The cleverest the most helpful the wealthiest and the most generous became the most powerful ones 15 Historian Arni Daniel Juliusson further notes that the food production of the peasantry was the basis of political and military power 16 Peasant rebellions traditionally defined never occurred in Iceland even though peasant unrest was fairly common 16 Slavery was practiced in Iceland from settlement to the early 12th century Icelandic law allowed individuals guilty of theft or failure to pay debts to be enslaved Slaves were allowed to marry and have children which meant that a class of slaves could self perpetuate Slavery likely declined in the second half of the 12th century and was extremely rare by the 15th century 17 Warfare editSee also Military history of Iceland The followers of the godar owed them military service They were organized into platoons or companies based on their social status and equipment and these formed expeditionary armies or leidangrs Icelandic military tradition of the time closely followed developments in Norway No organized cavalry formations or formations of troops equipped with projectile weapons are recorded instead the bulk of the forces were formed in units of light medium and heavy infantry with bowmen or slingers distributed among the infantry units operating as light support skirmishers Before the end of the Commonwealth at least 21 fortresses and castles had been built in Iceland 18 During the Age of the Sturlungs the average battle involved fewer than 1000 men with an average casualty rate of only 15 This relatively low casualty rate might be attributed to the blood feud mentality which permeated Icelandic society which meant that the defeated army could not honourably be slaughtered to a man 19 Religion editMain article Christianization of Iceland The first Bishop of Skalholt was Isleifur Gissurarson who was elected by the Althing in 1056 After his son Gissur was installed as bishop the power and wealth of the church quickly grew due to the introduction of tithing the first tax introduced in Iceland The church became the second unifying institution in the country after the Althing Continuing similar patterns from the pre Christian era church estates could be owned by godar who would then get a portion of the tithe 20 Decline and fall editIn the early 13th century the Age of the Sturlungs the Commonwealth began to suffer from chaos and division resulting from internal disputes Originally the godar chieftains functioned more as a contractual relationship than a fixed geographic chieftaincy However by 1220 this form of communal leadership was replaced by dominant regional individuals who battled with one another for more control One historian argues the chaos and violence of this period stem from an imbalance of power and changes in the nature of Icelandic warfare Whereas the number of godar had been at least 39 early in the Icelandic Commonwealth a few powerful families had consolidated control over most of the godord in the late 12th century 21 There are several factors that may have resulted in the consolidation of godord The separation of secular and ecclesiastical power led some families and regional networks to become stronger at the expense of others leading to an imbalance of power 22 The introduction of tithe may have increased the wealth of chieftains that controlled the churches 21 The introduction of pitched battles and harassment of farmers on a regional basis raised the stakes and dangers which may have incentivized consolidation 22 An increase in population along with a resource shortage may have made commoners more dependent on chieftains 21 The King of Norway began to exert pressure on his Icelandic vassals to bring the country under his rule He commissioned Icelandic chieftains to become part of his body of retainers and to pursue his interests in Iceland 21 The King s role in Icelandic affairs started in 1220 and had become strong by 1240 Icelanders were starting to accept the King s choice of chieftains 23 24 Over the period 1240 1260 the King consolidated power in Iceland 23 A combination of discontent with domestic hostilities and pressure from the King of Norway led the Icelandic chieftains to accept Norway s Haakon IV as king by the signing of the Gamli sattmali Old Covenant in 1262 According to historian Sverrir Jakobsson three Icelanders played a central role in bringing Iceland under the King of Norway Gissur THorvaldsson for getting farmers to agree to pay taxes to the King Hrafn Oddsson for pressuring Gissur into supporting the King and getting farmers in the Westfjords to submit to the King and bishop Brandur Jonsson for getting his relatives in the East Fjords to submit to the King 25 By 1264 all Icelandic chieftains had sworn allegiance to the King of Norway 26 The end of the Icelandic Commonwealth is typically dated to the Old Covenant 1262 1264 or to the adoption of Jonsbok in 1281 1 Contemporary libertarian perspectives editAccording to the libertarian theorist David D Friedman Medieval Icelandic institutions have several peculiar and interesting characteristics they might almost have been invented by a mad economist to test the lengths to which market systems could supplant government in its most fundamental functions 27 While not directly labeling it anarcho capitalist he argues that the legal system came close to being a real world anarcho capitalist legal system 28 Although noting that there was a single legal system Friedman argues that enforcement of the law was entirely private and highly capitalist providing some evidence of how such a society would function Even where the Icelandic legal system recognized an essentially public offense it dealt with it by giving some individual in some cases chosen by lot from those affected the right to pursue the case and collect the resulting fine thus fitting it into an essentially private system 27 Commenting on its political structure libertarian scholar Roderick Long remarks The legal system s administration insofar as it had one lay in the hands of a parliament of about 40 officers whom historians call however inadequately chieftains This parliament had no budget and no employees it met only two weeks per year In addition to their parliamentary role chieftains were empowered in their own local districts to appoint judges and to keep the peace this latter job was handled on an essentially fee for service basis The enforcement of judicial decisions was largely a matter of self help hence Iceland s reputation as a land of constant private feuding but those who lacked the might to enforce their rights could sell their court decreed claims for compensation to someone more powerful usually a chieftain hence even the poor and friendless could not be victimized with impunity The basis of a chieftain s power within the political order was the power he already possessed outside it in civil society The office of chieftaincy was private property and could be bought or sold hence chieftaincies tended to track private wealth But wealth alone was not enough As economic historian Birgir Solvason notes in his masterful study of the period just buying the chieftainship was no guarantee of power the mere office by itself was almost worthless unless the chieftain could convince some free farmers to follow him Chieftains did not hold authority over territorially defined districts but competed for clients with other chieftains from the same geographical area 29 Summarizing his research Friedman concludes in part 30 It is difficult to draw any conclusion from the Icelandic experience concerning the viability of systems of private enforcement in the twentieth century Even if Icelandic institutions worked well then they might not work in a larger and more interdependent society And whether the Icelandic institutions did work well is a matter of controversy the sagas are perceived by many as portraying an essentially violent and unjust society tormented by constant feuding It is difficult to tell whether such judgments are correct 27 A 2021 study by economists Vincent Geloso and Peter T Leeson concluded that The data available for comparing living standards in Iceland and other territories in medieval Europe data on human height wages and population growth are sparse crude and therefore challenging to interpret But a basic picture is apparent nonetheless and suggests a negative conclusion if not a positive one Living standards in state governed medieval Europe do not seem to have been higher than they were in Iceland Anarcho capitalists it seems are not insane 30 Friedman and Bruce L Benson argued that the Icelandic Commonwealth saw significant economic and social progress in the absence of systems of criminal law an executive or bureaucracy 31 See also edit nbsp Iceland portal nbsp Middle Ages portalHistory of Iceland History of Icelandic nationality Icelandic nobility Settlement of Iceland Sagas of IcelandersCitations editNotes edit Icelandic THjodveldid Island ˈ8jouːdˌvɛltɪ8 Old Norse Islands thjodveldi References edit a b c d Jakobsson Sverrir 2021 All the King s men The incorporation of Iceland into the Norwegian Realm Scandinavian Journal of History 46 5 571 592 doi 10 1080 03468755 2021 1961856 ISSN 0346 8755 S2CID 238770622 Archived from the original on 20 August 2023 Retrieved 8 August 2021 Jakobsson Sverrir 2010 Heaven is a Place on Earth Church and Sacred Space in Thirteenth Century Iceland Scandinavian Studies 82 1 1 20 doi 10 2307 40920892 ISSN 0036 5637 JSTOR 40920892 S2CID 159404976 Archived from the original on 9 January 2022 Retrieved 9 January 2022 Eggertsson Thrainn 1990 Economic Behavior and Institutions Principles of Neoinstitutional Economics Cambridge University Press p 305 ISBN 978 0 521 34891 1 Archived from the original on 20 August 2023 Retrieved 9 January 2022 Jon A Hjaltalin 1 January 1868 the Civilisation of the First Icelandic Colonists with a short account of some of their manners and customs JSTOR 3014256 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Short William Rhuel Icelanders in the Viking Age The People of the Sagas Jefferson NC McFarland amp 2010 Print Gudmundur Halfdanarson Historical Dictionary of Iceland Lanham MD Scarecrow 2008 Print Karlsson Gunnar The History of Iceland Minneapolis Minn Univ of Minneapolis 2000 Print Sigurdsson Jon Vidar 1999 Chieftains and Power in the Icelandic Commonwealth p 168 Sigurdsson Jon Vidar 1999 Chieftains and Power in the Icelandic Commonwealth p 170 GRONLIE SIAN 2006 ISLENDINGABoK KRISTNI SAGA THE BOOK OF THE ICELANDERS THE STORY OF THE CONVERSION PDF Archived PDF from the original on 12 April 2013 Retrieved 13 February 2015 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Palsson Herman and Paul Edwards Eyrbyggja Saga Harmondsworth Penguin 1989 Print Jakobsson Sverrir 2016 Audnarodal Sogufelag p 13 Jakobsson Sverrir 2016 Audnarodal Sogufelag p 145 Hvers vegna fell thjodveldid Visindavefurinn Archived from the original on 29 January 2017 Retrieved 2 January 2017 Sigurdsson Jon Vidar 1999 Chieftains and Power in the Icelandic Commonwealth p 211 a b Juliusson Arni Daniel Peasant Unrest in Iceland www academia edu Retrieved 12 February 2016 Jakobsson Sverrir Fra thraelahaldi til landeigendavalds Islenskt midaldasamfelag 1100 1400 Archived from the original on 20 August 2023 Retrieved 3 January 2017 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Birgir Loftsson 2006 Hernadarsaga Islands 1170 1581 Pjaxi Reykjavik pg 76 Birgir Loftsson op cit Fridrikson Fridrik August 1982 The Rise and Decline of the Icelandic Commonwealth PDF Archived PDF from the original on 14 October 2020 Retrieved 5 October 2020 a b c d Bagge Sverre 2014 Cross and Scepter The Rise of the Scandinavian Kingdoms from the Vikings to the Reformation Princeton University Press p 45 ISBN 978 1 4008 5010 5 Archived from the original on 23 April 2023 Retrieved 2 January 2022 a b Jakobsson Sverrir 2001 The Process of State Formation in Medieval Iceland www academia edu Archived from the original on 20 August 2023 Retrieved 18 January 2016 a b Sigurdsson Jon Vidar 1999 Chieftains and Power in the Icelandic Commonwealth pp 208 216 Sigurdsson Jon Vidar 2017 Viking Friendship The Social Bond in Iceland and Norway c 900 1300 Cornell University Press p 71 ISBN 978 1 5017 0848 0 Archived from the original on 2 May 2023 Retrieved 3 January 2022 Jakobsson Sverrir 2016 Audnarodal Sogufelag p 255 Karlsson Gunnar 2000 The History of Iceland pp 82 83 a b c Friedman David 1979 Private Creation and Enforcement of Law A Historical Case The Journal of Legal Studies 8 2 399 415 doi 10 1086 467615 ISSN 0047 2530 S2CID 59062557 Archived from the original on 18 April 2021 Retrieved 30 December 2016 Friedman David D 28 February 2015 Private Law Enforcement Medieval Iceland and Libertarianism The Machinery of Freedom 3rd ed pp 203 204 ISBN 978 1507785607 The Vikings Were Libertarians Lew Rockwell Archived from the original on 8 December 2015 Retrieved 14 September 2015 a b Geloso Vincent Leeson Peter T 2021 Are Anarcho Capitalists Insane Medieval Icelandic Conflict Institutions in Comparative Perspective PDF Revue d economie politique 130 6 957 974 doi 10 3917 redp 306 0115 ISSN 0373 2630 S2CID 235008718 Archived PDF from the original on 19 April 2021 Retrieved 12 April 2023 Costa Daniel 21 October 2022 Anarcho capitalism Encyclopaedia Britannica Archived from the original on 25 October 2022 Retrieved 25 October 2022 External links editMedieval Iceland Society Sagas and Power by Jesse L Byock 65 N 18 W 65 N 18 W 65 18 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Icelandic Commonwealth amp oldid 1174954580, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.