fbpx
Wikipedia

Bid rigging

Bid rigging is a fraudulent scheme in a procurement action which enables companies to submit non-competitive bids. It can be performed by corrupt officials, by firms in an orchestrated act of collusion, or by officials and firms acting together. This form of collusion is illegal in most countries. It is a form of price fixing and market allocation, often practiced where contracts are determined by a call for bids, for example in the case of government construction contracts. The typical objective of bid rigging is to enable the "winning" party to obtain contracts at uncompetitive prices (i.e., at higher prices if they are sellers, or lower prices if they are buyers). The other parties are compensated in various ways, for example, by cash payments, or by being designated to be the "winning" bidder on other contracts, or by an arrangement where some parts of the successful bidder's contract will be subcontracted to them. In this way, they "share the spoils" among themselves. Bid rigging almost always results in economic harm to the agency which is seeking the bids, and to the public, who ultimately bear the costs as taxpayers or consumers.

Forms edit

As acts of corruption edit

  • Change order abuse occurs when a contractor colludes with project officials, wins a low bid, and asks to change the contract afterwards. That is approved by officials, resulting in a much higher bid being retroactively approved.[1]
  • Bidder exclusion allows project officials to essentially choose their bid. There are multiple methods to achieve that like the following:
    • Instituting unreasonable qualification parameters, excluding non-preferred firms, or effectuating the same by shortening the time of acceptance periods for new bids following a request.
    • Advertising projects to select bidders or bidding markets, thereby reducing publicity of bid procurement.
    • Bundling of contracts to exclude bidders.
    • Coercion and intimidation can also be used, as well as the simple rejection of individual bids over trivial matters.[2]
  • Purchase splitting to reduce the minimum bid amount. That functions as contracts are split up to reduce the actual procurement amount and keep it under a threshold value. That reduces competitive bidding and enables less oversight at the project level as bid prices drop and kickbacks can be allotted.[3]
  • Leaking of bid information, which requires a relationship of some degree between the project and a bidder as the bidder is handed information to gain an unfair advantage.[4]
  • Bid manipulation is another method for officials to choose the bidder of their choice but occurs after receipt of bids. The methods for this would include either changing bid parameters, evaluation processes, or other activity to effectively select the bidder of choice.[5]
  • Rigged Specifications allow more bidder exclusion by officials by either tailoring requests to individual bidders or creating a vague criterion to reasonably choose a preferred bidder.[6]
  • Unbalanced bidding involves high bid prices for commencing phases of development and low prices for later stages. That effectively increases the flow of funds for the bidding firm. This occurs when bidders cite high prices for items, intending to raise the number of units and purchase them at a competitive rate while simultaneously skimming profits from the artificially high bid price. Additionally, bidders may give low quotes for non-necessary items (knowledge gained through collusion or experience) to disadvantage other firms as their bid amount is more competitive. This also serves to increase the cost of entry for new firms.[7]
  • Unjustified sole source awards are bids chosen on criteria unrelated to their competitiveness. That can be performed blatantly, by falsifying bids, or by price splitting.[8]

Within a cartel edit

  • Bid suppression collusion occurs when some of the conspirators agree not to submit bids to allow another conspirator to win the contract.
  • Complementary bidding, also known as cover bidding or courtesy bidding, occurs when some of the bidders agree to submit bids that are intended to be unsuccessful so that another conspirator can win the contract. For example, the cover bids might contain prices that are uncompetitive in relation to the prices submitted by the conspirator, who is designated to win the contract, or the cover bids might contain conditions that the conspirators know to be unacceptable to the agency calling for the bids.
  • Bid rotation occurs when bidders take turns being the designated successful bidder. For example, each conspirator is designated to be the successful bidder on a certain contract, with conspirators designated to win other contracts. That is a form of market allocation in which the conspirators allocate or apportion markets, products, customers or geographic territories among themselves. This is then divided up such that each will get a "fair share" of the total business, without truly having to compete with the others for that business.
  • Bid delegation can be a factor fostering the presence of bid rigging; for instance, it is the case of marketing agencies that bid for the same ad space on behalf of different and competing agents.[9]).

As an auctioneer or official edit

  • Phantom Bids are false bids taken by an auctioneer to trick a legitimate bidder into bidding more would have otherwise been the case. The auctioneer hires confederates to call out the phantom bids. If the phantom bid is the winner, the lot is hidden and comes back around for a second auction, or the second-highest legitimate bidder is informed that the first bidder was unable to make payment.
  • Buy-back is the strategy in which the auctioneer or seller bids on a lot and buys it back to protect it from being sold to the highest bidder for an insufficient price. That is fraud if the auction is advertised as an "absolute auction", meaning there are no reserve bids.
  • Phantom auctions, in the real estate industry, may occur when the bank "tentatively" auctions a foreclosed home and gives bidders an option to give "preliminary bids" for homes that are not yet authorized for auction. If the reserve bids are not met, the home is updated as "never was available for auction" even though bids were received. Some houses are auctioned at fire-sale prices, and the auctions are closed before the auction was formally announced. Investors rush to get in their preliminary bids before the house is technically up for auction. Bidders fear losing options so it results in more bids, and naturally, higher prices. If bidders fail to reach the target bids, the item was never available for auction. Banks do that because if they unloaded all of their toxic assets at once, the housing market would collapse, which causes foreclosed homes to be dribbled out with phantom auctions.[citation needed]

Those forms of bid rigging can occur together, and two or more of the practices could occur at the same time. For example, if one member of the bidding ring is designated to win a particular contract, that bidder's conspirators could avoid winning by not bidding ("bid suppression") or by submitting a high bid ("cover bidding").

Economic costs edit

Many of the issues presented by bid rigging are the result of cartel involvement. Inefficient firms are not pushed out, as they would have been in a competitive market, and firms experience more profit, despite an inefficient allocation of resources. Cartels behave more like monopolies and so their behaviors, such as bid rigging, create market inefficiencies as contracts are fulfilled at elevated values.[10] Furthermore, bid prices increase with more repeated collusion.[11] Ultimately, the cost is typically borne by the taxpayer as government-sponsored contracts are artificially above market value. Additionally, it can be thought of as raising prices for the taxpayer (or consumer) as firms rent seek. One study found that bid rigging significantly raised prices over market value in the seafood industry in Philadelphia in a bidding scheme involving Defense Personnel Support Center, a purchaser for the Department of Defense.[12] The high price of entry and fewer entrants in many industries results in lessened incentives for firms to behave competitively.[13]

Detection edit

In the UK, the Competition and Markets Authority published an open letter in 2016 aiming to promote good practice among procurement and supply staff, and detailing indications they should watch out for.[14][15]

Remediation edit

Bid rigging is an illegal practice under the criminal or competition laws of most developed countries. Depending on the jurisdiction, it is punishable by fines, imprisonment or both.

At a very basic level, there would likely be more competitive bidding if there were more firms present in a market, outside of a cartel, as evidence shows that bids lessen in value as the number of firms rises. Furthermore, collusion becomes less frequent with better market competitiveness, a result of reduced ability to compromise.[11]

The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), in its work on bid-rigging and cartels in public procurement, makes the following suggestions for better tenders:

  • Developing expertise and awareness of the market for which a tender is being designed.
  • Maximizing the number of bids and potential contractors for enhanced competition among proposals.
  • Striving for clarity in requirements and details.
  • Reducing potential for communication between bidders and procurement officials and adhering to a strict criterion and process of evaluation.[16]

Suggestions for ameliorating procurement auctions have also been put forth. Lengstein and Wolfstetter suggest that when a particular bidder is preferred, disregarding cost, possible reforms include a sealed Vickrey auction, or if there is reason to believe that officials and bidders are in contact, an open auction is preferred to sidestep potential bribery. When officials are engaged in more competitive procurement processes with regard to price but are suspected of kickbacks, a potential solution is the open auction to prevent clandestine arrangements such as change order abuse. If a closed or sealed auction process is preferred, the use of electronic bidding and investment in tamper-resistant systems is suggested.[17]

Notable examples by region edit

South America edit

Brazil edit

Brazil's Operation Car Wash is an ongoing investigation into the Brazilian semi-public multinational Petrobras. Petrobras is suspected of having overcharged bids as much as 3% of the total cost on contracts with an alleged $2.1 billion being misappropriated in kickbacks. Operation Car Wash is part of a larger investigation into Brazil's government as well and has contributed to the conviction and imprisonment of former president Luiz Inácio Lula da Silva.[18] In early January 2018, Petrobras settled a United States class action case for $2.95 billion, though JP Morgan and BTG Pactual had expected a settlement between $5 and $10 billion.[19]

The Petrobras scandal extends beyond bid rigging in the oil sector as the investigation has also implicated Brazilian construction firms as bid rigging was discovered to be rampant in the preparations for the 2016 Summer Olympics. This would not be the first instance of bid rigging by construction firms in recent Brazilian history as Andrade Gutierrez Engenharia SA, the nation's second largest construction firm, admitted to bid rigging during contract procurement for stadiums to host the 2014 FIFA World Cup. This revelation implicates an additional five domestic construction firms and was revealed by the Conselho Administrativo de Defesa Econômica(CADE).[20]

Colombia edit

From 2002 until 2013, the Colombian government opened 121 investigations into bid rigging, which lead to sixty-nine entities paying fines amounting to nearly $23.5 million, with an additional nine entities receiving sanctions. Colombia was found to generally comply with the OECD's recommendations regarding competitive procurement.[21]

North America edit

United States edit

In the United States, bid rigging is a federal felony criminal offense under Section 1 of the Sherman Act. Even so, bid rigging is still rampant in the construction industry, auto sale auctions, and foreclosed home auctions.

Canada edit

In Canada, bid rigging is an indictable criminal offence under Section 47 of the Competition Act.

Europe edit

Bid rigging is illegal in the European Union (EU) under Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU). The annual cost to the EU in economic waste as a direct result of bid rigging among cartels was estimated to be between €13 billion and €37 billion in 2008.[22] Bid rigging seems to be on the rise across Europe, raising concerns particularly over excessive expenditures and single-bid tenders. These single-bid tenders represented 17% of tenders in 2006, but 30% nine years later. RAND estimated that the overall annual cost posed to the EU by bid cost increases was $5 billion.[23]

Slovakia edit

Bid rigging is illegal in Slovakia under the Act on the Protection of Competition and by EU membership, also Article 101 of TFEU. The first charges to be brought to court in Slovakia in 2006 by the Antimonopoly Office involved six construction companies who submitted bids with suspiciously consistent unit quotes. The fines from this bid rigging scheme amounted to €45 million following an initial court decision, an over-ruling, and a reinstatement of the initial verdict.[24] In 2007, a Slovakian government ministry participated in bidder exclusion by posting a request for proposals regarding consulting on a bulletin board in an official building, though not open to the public. This resulted in a consulting firm winning a €120 million contract.[23][25] The word for receiving kickbacks after participating in bid rigging is known as "tunelovanie" in Slovak.[25]

Switzerland edit

Bid rigging occurs frequently in the construction industry in Switzerland. In 2007, seventeen different firms were involved in a bid rigging scheme but there was no prosecution as the ring had disbanded before colluding.[26][1] In 2009, a ring of seven electricity firms from Bern were charged with bid rigging and fined two million Swiss francs. In Aargau, in 2011, a bid rigging scheme was discovered wherein seventeen firms were fined eight million Swiss francs though the appeals are ongoing. Multiple other cases are still ongoing.

United Kingdom edit

In the United Kingdom, individuals can be prosecuted criminally under the Enterprise Act 2002.

Asia edit

Japan edit

Although both a violation of Japanese criminal law and the Japan Anti-Monopoly Law, bid rigging is still a habitual practice of the Japanese construction industry. It has been shown by a number of academic studies both in Japan and in the US to be a system which considerably inflates the cost of construction projects, and in the Japanese public sector, considerably wasteful of annual tax money amounting to billions of Japanese yen.

Dango refers to collusion in Japanese, or more precisely, "conference", and is an extremely prevalent system in Japan. Dango can be understood as a mutually beneficial system of bureaucracy and government and the private construction industry wherein bid rigging is incredibly common, benefiting colluding firms and officials alike in the form of kickbacks. The system of dango is often supported though as allowing small firms to continue to compete, though detractors are quick to point to the economic inefficiencies presented by a non-competitive market.[10] The US Government, specifically the United States Trade Representative Office and Department of Commerce, made fierce efforts[27][28] in the late 1980s and early 1990s to urge the Japanese government to reform dango as a de facto non-tariff barrier to foreign firms in the Japanese construction market. Despite years of negotiations, including promises by the Japanese government in the Structural Impediment Initiative (SII) trade talks,[29] the practice was never fully stamped out and continued to flourish.

In 2006, Tadahiro Ando, the then governor of Miyazaki Prefecture, resigned over a series of bid rigging allegations and was subsequently sentenced to over three years in jail.[30]

As of 2008, thirteen lawsuits were still pending over 1990s' bid rigging for local government contracts to supply incinerator plants.[31]

Korea edit

In a three and half year period from 1995 to 1998 there was an estimated $4.13 billion surcharge attributed to bid rigging in Korea's construction industry, representing 15.5% of the total spent. It was also found that firms already present in an area enjoyed a significant degree of incumbency, meaning that they were more likely to continue to win additional contracts in areas they were already developing. This was discovered to be a result of complementary bidding. Some legal action has been undertaken against these bid rigging schemes with nine contracting companies and several officials being charged and fined $5 billion in 1999.[32]

See also edit

Further reading edit

  • Choi, Jin-Wook (2007). "Governance Structure and Administrative Corruption in Japan: An Organizational Network Approach". Public Administration Review. Wiley. 67 (5): 930–942. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6210.2007.00779.x. ISSN 0033-3352.
  • LaCasse, Chantale (1995). "Bid Rigging and the Threat of Government Prosecution". The RAND Journal of Economics. Wiley. 26 (3): 398–417. doi:10.2307/2555995. ISSN 0741-6261. JSTOR 2555995.
  • Porter, Robert; Zona, J. Douglas (1992). "Detection of Bid Rigging in Procurement Auctions". Journal of Political Economy. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. 101: 518–538. doi:10.3386/w4013.
  • Woodall, Brian (1993). "The Logic of Collusive Action: The Political Roots of Japan's Dango System". Comparative Politics. JSTOR. 25 (3): 297–312. doi:10.2307/422247. ISSN 0010-4159. JSTOR 422247.

References edit

  1. ^ "Potential Scheme: Change Order Abuse". guide.iacrc.org. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  2. ^ "Potential Scheme: Excluding Qualified Bidders". guide.iacrc.org. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  3. ^ "Potential Scheme: Split Purchases". guide.iacrc.org. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  4. ^ "Potential Scheme: Leaking of Bid Information". guide.iacrc.org. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  5. ^ "Potential Scheme: Manipulation of Bids". guide.iacrc.org. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  6. ^ "Potential Scheme: Rigged Specifications". guide.iacrc.org. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  7. ^ "Potential Scheme: Unbalanced Bidding". guide.iacrc.org. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  8. ^ "Potential Scheme: Unjustified Sole Source Awards". guide.iacrc.org. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  9. ^ Decarolis, Francesco; Goldmanis, Maris; Penta, Antonio (2017). "Marketing agencies and collusive bidding in online ad auctions". National Bureau of Economic Research, No. W23962. doi:10.3386/w23962. S2CID 44056837.
  10. ^ a b Black, William K. (October 2004). "The Dango Tango: Why Corruption Blocks Real Reform in Japan". Business Ethics Quarterly. 14 (4): 603–623. doi:10.5840/beq200414442. ISSN 1052-150X. S2CID 146369439.
  11. ^ a b Gupta, Srabana (2001). "The Effect of Bid Rigging on Prices: A Study of the Highway Construction Industry". Review of Industrial Organization. 19 (4): 451–465. doi:10.1023/a:1012568509136. ISSN 0889-938X. S2CID 153988096.
  12. ^ Froeb, Luke M.; Koyak, Robert A.; Werden, Gregory J. (January 1993). "What is the effect of bid-rigging on prices?". Economics Letters. 42 (4): 419–423. doi:10.1016/0165-1765(93)90095-t. ISSN 0165-1765.
  13. ^ https://www.oecd.org/governance/procurement/toolbox/search/checklist-design-tender-methods-reduce-bid-rigging.pdf
  14. ^ Cave, B., CMA publishes guidance to help detect bid-rigging, Lexology, accessed 18 January 2024
  15. ^ Competition and Markets Authority, Detecting and deterring bid-rigging, published 20 June 2016, archived by The National Archives on 24 June 2016, accessed 18 January 2024
  16. ^ "Guidelines for Fighting Bid Rigging in Public Procurement - OECD". www.oecd.org. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  17. ^ Lengwiler, Yvan; Wolfstetter, Elmar G. (2006). "Corruption in Procurement Auctions". SSRN Working Paper Series. doi:10.2139/ssrn.874705. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 167452901.
  18. ^ "Petrobras scandal | Summary, Explanation, & Operation Car Wash". Encyclopedia Britannica. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  19. ^ Pierson, Brendan. "Petrobras to pay $2.95 billion to settle U.S. corruption lawsuit". U.S. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  20. ^ Mano, Ana. "Brazil builder admits to World Cup stadium cartel in deal with..." U.S. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  21. ^ "Fighting Bid Rigging in Public Procurement in Colombia - 2014 - OECD". www.oecd.org. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  22. ^ Maci, Marsela (April 2012). "Private Enforcement in Bid-Rigging Cases in the European Union". European Competition Journal. 8 (1): 211–227. doi:10.5235/174410512800369973. ISSN 1744-1056. S2CID 154382209.
  23. ^ a b "Rigging the bids". The Economist. Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  24. ^ Blaao, Ondrej; Sramelova, Silvia (2015). (PDF). SSRN Working Paper Series. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2741673. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 159767037. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2020-01-01.
  25. ^ a b Castle, Stephen. "E.U. Cash Tunnel Ends in Slovakia". Retrieved 2018-09-11.
  26. ^ Huschelrath, K. (2012-12-17). "Economic Approaches to Fight Bid Rigging". Journal of European Competition Law & Practice. 4 (2): 185–191. doi:10.1093/jeclap/lps071. ISSN 2041-7764.
  27. ^ "US Department of Justice report". Usdoj.gov. 1994-09-16. Retrieved 2011-12-17.
  28. ^ "New York Times report from 1995". The New York Times. 1995-03-09. Retrieved 2011-12-17.
  29. ^ "Britanica Article". Britannica.com. Retrieved 2011-12-17.
  30. ^ "Japan Times report". Search.japantimes.co.jp. 2009-03-28. Retrieved 2011-12-17.
  31. ^ "Builders settle damages suit over bid-rigging | The Japan Times Online". Search.japantimes.co.jp. 2009-04-04. Retrieved 2011-12-17.
  32. ^ Lee, In Kwon; Hahn, Kyungdong (2002). "Bid-Rigging in Auctions for Korean Public-Works Contracts and Potential Damage". Review of Industrial Organization. 21 (1): 73–88. doi:10.1023/a:1016018505021. ISSN 0889-938X. S2CID 153429133.

rigging, fraudulent, scheme, procurement, action, which, enables, companies, submit, competitive, bids, performed, corrupt, officials, firms, orchestrated, collusion, officials, firms, acting, together, this, form, collusion, illegal, most, countries, form, pr. Bid rigging is a fraudulent scheme in a procurement action which enables companies to submit non competitive bids It can be performed by corrupt officials by firms in an orchestrated act of collusion or by officials and firms acting together This form of collusion is illegal in most countries It is a form of price fixing and market allocation often practiced where contracts are determined by a call for bids for example in the case of government construction contracts The typical objective of bid rigging is to enable the winning party to obtain contracts at uncompetitive prices i e at higher prices if they are sellers or lower prices if they are buyers The other parties are compensated in various ways for example by cash payments or by being designated to be the winning bidder on other contracts or by an arrangement where some parts of the successful bidder s contract will be subcontracted to them In this way they share the spoils among themselves Bid rigging almost always results in economic harm to the agency which is seeking the bids and to the public who ultimately bear the costs as taxpayers or consumers Contents 1 Forms 1 1 As acts of corruption 1 2 Within a cartel 1 3 As an auctioneer or official 2 Economic costs 3 Detection 4 Remediation 5 Notable examples by region 5 1 South America 5 1 1 Brazil 5 1 2 Colombia 5 2 North America 5 2 1 United States 5 2 2 Canada 5 3 Europe 5 3 1 Slovakia 5 3 2 Switzerland 5 3 3 United Kingdom 5 4 Asia 5 4 1 Japan 5 4 2 Korea 6 See also 7 Further reading 8 ReferencesForms editAs acts of corruption edit Change order abuse occurs when a contractor colludes with project officials wins a low bid and asks to change the contract afterwards That is approved by officials resulting in a much higher bid being retroactively approved 1 Bidder exclusion allows project officials to essentially choose their bid There are multiple methods to achieve that like the following Instituting unreasonable qualification parameters excluding non preferred firms or effectuating the same by shortening the time of acceptance periods for new bids following a request Advertising projects to select bidders or bidding markets thereby reducing publicity of bid procurement Bundling of contracts to exclude bidders Coercion and intimidation can also be used as well as the simple rejection of individual bids over trivial matters 2 Purchase splitting to reduce the minimum bid amount That functions as contracts are split up to reduce the actual procurement amount and keep it under a threshold value That reduces competitive bidding and enables less oversight at the project level as bid prices drop and kickbacks can be allotted 3 Leaking of bid information which requires a relationship of some degree between the project and a bidder as the bidder is handed information to gain an unfair advantage 4 Bid manipulation is another method for officials to choose the bidder of their choice but occurs after receipt of bids The methods for this would include either changing bid parameters evaluation processes or other activity to effectively select the bidder of choice 5 Rigged Specifications allow more bidder exclusion by officials by either tailoring requests to individual bidders or creating a vague criterion to reasonably choose a preferred bidder 6 Unbalanced bidding involves high bid prices for commencing phases of development and low prices for later stages That effectively increases the flow of funds for the bidding firm This occurs when bidders cite high prices for items intending to raise the number of units and purchase them at a competitive rate while simultaneously skimming profits from the artificially high bid price Additionally bidders may give low quotes for non necessary items knowledge gained through collusion or experience to disadvantage other firms as their bid amount is more competitive This also serves to increase the cost of entry for new firms 7 Unjustified sole source awards are bids chosen on criteria unrelated to their competitiveness That can be performed blatantly by falsifying bids or by price splitting 8 Within a cartel edit Bid suppression collusion occurs when some of the conspirators agree not to submit bids to allow another conspirator to win the contract Complementary bidding also known as cover bidding or courtesy bidding occurs when some of the bidders agree to submit bids that are intended to be unsuccessful so that another conspirator can win the contract For example the cover bids might contain prices that are uncompetitive in relation to the prices submitted by the conspirator who is designated to win the contract or the cover bids might contain conditions that the conspirators know to be unacceptable to the agency calling for the bids Bid rotation occurs when bidders take turns being the designated successful bidder For example each conspirator is designated to be the successful bidder on a certain contract with conspirators designated to win other contracts That is a form of market allocation in which the conspirators allocate or apportion markets products customers or geographic territories among themselves This is then divided up such that each will get a fair share of the total business without truly having to compete with the others for that business Bid delegation can be a factor fostering the presence of bid rigging for instance it is the case of marketing agencies that bid for the same ad space on behalf of different and competing agents 9 As an auctioneer or official edit Phantom Bids are false bids taken by an auctioneer to trick a legitimate bidder into bidding more would have otherwise been the case The auctioneer hires confederates to call out the phantom bids If the phantom bid is the winner the lot is hidden and comes back around for a second auction or the second highest legitimate bidder is informed that the first bidder was unable to make payment Buy back is the strategy in which the auctioneer or seller bids on a lot and buys it back to protect it from being sold to the highest bidder for an insufficient price That is fraud if the auction is advertised as an absolute auction meaning there are no reserve bids Phantom auctions in the real estate industry may occur when the bank tentatively auctions a foreclosed home and gives bidders an option to give preliminary bids for homes that are not yet authorized for auction If the reserve bids are not met the home is updated as never was available for auction even though bids were received Some houses are auctioned at fire sale prices and the auctions are closed before the auction was formally announced Investors rush to get in their preliminary bids before the house is technically up for auction Bidders fear losing options so it results in more bids and naturally higher prices If bidders fail to reach the target bids the item was never available for auction Banks do that because if they unloaded all of their toxic assets at once the housing market would collapse which causes foreclosed homes to be dribbled out with phantom auctions citation needed Those forms of bid rigging can occur together and two or more of the practices could occur at the same time For example if one member of the bidding ring is designated to win a particular contract that bidder s conspirators could avoid winning by not bidding bid suppression or by submitting a high bid cover bidding Economic costs editMany of the issues presented by bid rigging are the result of cartel involvement Inefficient firms are not pushed out as they would have been in a competitive market and firms experience more profit despite an inefficient allocation of resources Cartels behave more like monopolies and so their behaviors such as bid rigging create market inefficiencies as contracts are fulfilled at elevated values 10 Furthermore bid prices increase with more repeated collusion 11 Ultimately the cost is typically borne by the taxpayer as government sponsored contracts are artificially above market value Additionally it can be thought of as raising prices for the taxpayer or consumer as firms rent seek One study found that bid rigging significantly raised prices over market value in the seafood industry in Philadelphia in a bidding scheme involving Defense Personnel Support Center a purchaser for the Department of Defense 12 The high price of entry and fewer entrants in many industries results in lessened incentives for firms to behave competitively 13 Detection editIn the UK the Competition and Markets Authority published an open letter in 2016 aiming to promote good practice among procurement and supply staff and detailing indications they should watch out for 14 15 Remediation editBid rigging is an illegal practice under the criminal or competition laws of most developed countries Depending on the jurisdiction it is punishable by fines imprisonment or both At a very basic level there would likely be more competitive bidding if there were more firms present in a market outside of a cartel as evidence shows that bids lessen in value as the number of firms rises Furthermore collusion becomes less frequent with better market competitiveness a result of reduced ability to compromise 11 The Organisation for Economic Co operation and Development OECD in its work on bid rigging and cartels in public procurement makes the following suggestions for better tenders Developing expertise and awareness of the market for which a tender is being designed Maximizing the number of bids and potential contractors for enhanced competition among proposals Striving for clarity in requirements and details Reducing potential for communication between bidders and procurement officials and adhering to a strict criterion and process of evaluation 16 Suggestions for ameliorating procurement auctions have also been put forth Lengstein and Wolfstetter suggest that when a particular bidder is preferred disregarding cost possible reforms include a sealed Vickrey auction or if there is reason to believe that officials and bidders are in contact an open auction is preferred to sidestep potential bribery When officials are engaged in more competitive procurement processes with regard to price but are suspected of kickbacks a potential solution is the open auction to prevent clandestine arrangements such as change order abuse If a closed or sealed auction process is preferred the use of electronic bidding and investment in tamper resistant systems is suggested 17 Notable examples by region editSouth America edit Brazil edit Brazil s Operation Car Wash is an ongoing investigation into the Brazilian semi public multinational Petrobras Petrobras is suspected of having overcharged bids as much as 3 of the total cost on contracts with an alleged 2 1 billion being misappropriated in kickbacks Operation Car Wash is part of a larger investigation into Brazil s government as well and has contributed to the conviction and imprisonment of former president Luiz Inacio Lula da Silva 18 In early January 2018 Petrobras settled a United States class action case for 2 95 billion though JP Morgan and BTG Pactual had expected a settlement between 5 and 10 billion 19 The Petrobras scandal extends beyond bid rigging in the oil sector as the investigation has also implicated Brazilian construction firms as bid rigging was discovered to be rampant in the preparations for the 2016 Summer Olympics This would not be the first instance of bid rigging by construction firms in recent Brazilian history as Andrade Gutierrez Engenharia SA the nation s second largest construction firm admitted to bid rigging during contract procurement for stadiums to host the 2014 FIFA World Cup This revelation implicates an additional five domestic construction firms and was revealed by the Conselho Administrativo de Defesa Economica CADE 20 Colombia edit From 2002 until 2013 the Colombian government opened 121 investigations into bid rigging which lead to sixty nine entities paying fines amounting to nearly 23 5 million with an additional nine entities receiving sanctions Colombia was found to generally comply with the OECD s recommendations regarding competitive procurement 21 North America edit United States edit In the United States bid rigging is a federal felony criminal offense under Section 1 of the Sherman Act Even so bid rigging is still rampant in the construction industry auto sale auctions and foreclosed home auctions Canada edit In Canada bid rigging is an indictable criminal offence under Section 47 of the Competition Act Europe edit Bid rigging is illegal in the European Union EU under Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union TFEU The annual cost to the EU in economic waste as a direct result of bid rigging among cartels was estimated to be between 13 billion and 37 billion in 2008 22 Bid rigging seems to be on the rise across Europe raising concerns particularly over excessive expenditures and single bid tenders These single bid tenders represented 17 of tenders in 2006 but 30 nine years later RAND estimated that the overall annual cost posed to the EU by bid cost increases was 5 billion 23 Slovakia edit Bid rigging is illegal in Slovakia under the Act on the Protection of Competition and by EU membership also Article 101 of TFEU The first charges to be brought to court in Slovakia in 2006 by the Antimonopoly Office involved six construction companies who submitted bids with suspiciously consistent unit quotes The fines from this bid rigging scheme amounted to 45 million following an initial court decision an over ruling and a reinstatement of the initial verdict 24 In 2007 a Slovakian government ministry participated in bidder exclusion by posting a request for proposals regarding consulting on a bulletin board in an official building though not open to the public This resulted in a consulting firm winning a 120 million contract 23 25 The word for receiving kickbacks after participating in bid rigging is known as tunelovanie in Slovak 25 Switzerland edit Bid rigging occurs frequently in the construction industry in Switzerland In 2007 seventeen different firms were involved in a bid rigging scheme but there was no prosecution as the ring had disbanded before colluding 26 1 In 2009 a ring of seven electricity firms from Bern were charged with bid rigging and fined two million Swiss francs In Aargau in 2011 a bid rigging scheme was discovered wherein seventeen firms were fined eight million Swiss francs though the appeals are ongoing Multiple other cases are still ongoing United Kingdom edit In the United Kingdom individuals can be prosecuted criminally under the Enterprise Act 2002 Asia edit Japan edit Although both a violation of Japanese criminal law and the Japan Anti Monopoly Law bid rigging is still a habitual practice of the Japanese construction industry It has been shown by a number of academic studies both in Japan and in the US to be a system which considerably inflates the cost of construction projects and in the Japanese public sector considerably wasteful of annual tax money amounting to billions of Japanese yen Dango refers to collusion in Japanese or more precisely conference and is an extremely prevalent system in Japan Dango can be understood as a mutually beneficial system of bureaucracy and government and the private construction industry wherein bid rigging is incredibly common benefiting colluding firms and officials alike in the form of kickbacks The system of dango is often supported though as allowing small firms to continue to compete though detractors are quick to point to the economic inefficiencies presented by a non competitive market 10 The US Government specifically the United States Trade Representative Office and Department of Commerce made fierce efforts 27 28 in the late 1980s and early 1990s to urge the Japanese government to reform dango as a de facto non tariff barrier to foreign firms in the Japanese construction market Despite years of negotiations including promises by the Japanese government in the Structural Impediment Initiative SII trade talks 29 the practice was never fully stamped out and continued to flourish In 2006 Tadahiro Ando the then governor of Miyazaki Prefecture resigned over a series of bid rigging allegations and was subsequently sentenced to over three years in jail 30 As of 2008 thirteen lawsuits were still pending over 1990s bid rigging for local government contracts to supply incinerator plants 31 Korea edit In a three and half year period from 1995 to 1998 there was an estimated 4 13 billion surcharge attributed to bid rigging in Korea s construction industry representing 15 5 of the total spent It was also found that firms already present in an area enjoyed a significant degree of incumbency meaning that they were more likely to continue to win additional contracts in areas they were already developing This was discovered to be a result of complementary bidding Some legal action has been undertaken against these bid rigging schemes with nine contracting companies and several officials being charged and fined 5 billion in 1999 32 See also editBribery Cartel Collusion Corruption Operation Car Wash Organized crime Price fixingFurther reading editChoi Jin Wook 2007 Governance Structure and Administrative Corruption in Japan An Organizational Network Approach Public Administration Review Wiley 67 5 930 942 doi 10 1111 j 1540 6210 2007 00779 x ISSN 0033 3352 LaCasse Chantale 1995 Bid Rigging and the Threat of Government Prosecution The RAND Journal of Economics Wiley 26 3 398 417 doi 10 2307 2555995 ISSN 0741 6261 JSTOR 2555995 Porter Robert Zona J Douglas 1992 Detection of Bid Rigging in Procurement Auctions Journal of Political Economy Cambridge MA National Bureau of Economic Research 101 518 538 doi 10 3386 w4013 Woodall Brian 1993 The Logic of Collusive Action The Political Roots of Japan s Dango System Comparative Politics JSTOR 25 3 297 312 doi 10 2307 422247 ISSN 0010 4159 JSTOR 422247 References edit Potential Scheme Change Order Abuse guide iacrc org Retrieved 2018 09 11 Potential Scheme Excluding Qualified Bidders guide iacrc org Retrieved 2018 09 11 Potential Scheme Split Purchases guide iacrc org Retrieved 2018 09 11 Potential Scheme Leaking of Bid Information guide iacrc org Retrieved 2018 09 11 Potential Scheme Manipulation of Bids guide iacrc org Retrieved 2018 09 11 Potential Scheme Rigged Specifications guide iacrc org Retrieved 2018 09 11 Potential Scheme Unbalanced Bidding guide iacrc org Retrieved 2018 09 11 Potential Scheme Unjustified Sole Source Awards guide iacrc org Retrieved 2018 09 11 Decarolis Francesco Goldmanis Maris Penta Antonio 2017 Marketing agencies and collusive bidding in online ad auctions National Bureau of Economic Research No W23962 doi 10 3386 w23962 S2CID 44056837 a b Black William K October 2004 The Dango Tango Why Corruption Blocks Real Reform in Japan Business Ethics Quarterly 14 4 603 623 doi 10 5840 beq200414442 ISSN 1052 150X S2CID 146369439 a b Gupta Srabana 2001 The Effect of Bid Rigging on Prices A Study of the Highway Construction Industry Review of Industrial Organization 19 4 451 465 doi 10 1023 a 1012568509136 ISSN 0889 938X S2CID 153988096 Froeb Luke M Koyak Robert A Werden Gregory J January 1993 What is the effect of bid rigging on prices Economics Letters 42 4 419 423 doi 10 1016 0165 1765 93 90095 t ISSN 0165 1765 https www oecd org governance procurement toolbox search checklist design tender methods reduce bid rigging pdf Cave B CMA publishes guidance to help detect bid rigging Lexology accessed 18 January 2024 Competition and Markets Authority Detecting and deterring bid rigging published 20 June 2016 archived by The National Archives on 24 June 2016 accessed 18 January 2024 Guidelines for Fighting Bid Rigging in Public Procurement OECD www oecd org Retrieved 2018 09 11 Lengwiler Yvan Wolfstetter Elmar G 2006 Corruption in Procurement Auctions SSRN Working Paper Series doi 10 2139 ssrn 874705 ISSN 1556 5068 S2CID 167452901 Petrobras scandal Summary Explanation amp Operation Car Wash Encyclopedia Britannica Retrieved 2018 09 11 Pierson Brendan Petrobras to pay 2 95 billion to settle U S corruption lawsuit U S Retrieved 2018 09 11 Mano Ana Brazil builder admits to World Cup stadium cartel in deal with U S Retrieved 2018 09 11 Fighting Bid Rigging in Public Procurement in Colombia 2014 OECD www oecd org Retrieved 2018 09 11 Maci Marsela April 2012 Private Enforcement in Bid Rigging Cases in the European Union European Competition Journal 8 1 211 227 doi 10 5235 174410512800369973 ISSN 1744 1056 S2CID 154382209 a b Rigging the bids The Economist Retrieved 2018 09 11 Blaao Ondrej Sramelova Silvia 2015 The First Bid Rigging Case in Slovakia after Years of Judicial Disputes PDF SSRN Working Paper Series doi 10 2139 ssrn 2741673 ISSN 1556 5068 S2CID 159767037 Archived from the original PDF on 2020 01 01 a b Castle Stephen E U Cash Tunnel Ends in Slovakia Retrieved 2018 09 11 Huschelrath K 2012 12 17 Economic Approaches to Fight Bid Rigging Journal of European Competition Law amp Practice 4 2 185 191 doi 10 1093 jeclap lps071 ISSN 2041 7764 US Department of Justice report Usdoj gov 1994 09 16 Retrieved 2011 12 17 New York Times report from 1995 The New York Times 1995 03 09 Retrieved 2011 12 17 Britanica Article Britannica com Retrieved 2011 12 17 Japan Times report Search japantimes co jp 2009 03 28 Retrieved 2011 12 17 Builders settle damages suit over bid rigging The Japan Times Online Search japantimes co jp 2009 04 04 Retrieved 2011 12 17 Lee In Kwon Hahn Kyungdong 2002 Bid Rigging in Auctions for Korean Public Works Contracts and Potential Damage Review of Industrial Organization 21 1 73 88 doi 10 1023 a 1016018505021 ISSN 0889 938X S2CID 153429133 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Bid rigging amp oldid 1206027491, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.