fbpx
Wikipedia

Aid effectiveness

Aid effectiveness and Impact

Aid effectiveness is the degree of success or failure of international aid (development aid or humanitarian aid). Concern with aid effectiveness might be at a high level of generality (whether aid on average fulfils the main functions that aid is supposed to have), or it might be more detailed (considering relative degrees of success between different types of aid in differing circumstances).

Questions of aid effectiveness have been highly contested by academics, commentators and practitioners: there is a large literature on the subject. Econometric studies in the late 20th century often found the average effectiveness of aid to be minimal or even negative. Such studies have appeared on the whole to yield more affirmative results in the early 21st century, but the picture is complex and far from clear in many respects.

Many prescriptions have been made about how to improve aid effectiveness. In 2003–2011 there existed a global movement in the name of aid effectiveness, around four high level forums on aid effectiveness. These elaborated a set of good practices concerning aid administration co-ordination and relations between donors and recipient countries. From 2011 this movement was subsumed in one concerned more broadly with effective development co-operation, largely embodied by the Global Partnership for Effective Development Co-operation.

The concept of aid effectiveness edit

Any discussion of "effectiveness" must rely on understandings or assumptions about aims.[1] In public discussions of aid effectiveness, the general aim is usually assumed to be boosting the development of recipient countries and, hence, the well-being of people living in them. But "development" and "well-being" are complex and slippery concepts. The most popular summary indicator for a country's development is probably average national income per head in its population, but this indicator does not capture inequalities of wealth and power, or the structural characteristics of the country's institutions and economy.[2] Since the 1990s the prime purpose of aid has widely been seen as poverty reduction, but this, too, can be interpreted in a variety of ways (How soon? How sustainable? What level?).[3] Such ambiguities should be clarified or at least borne in mind when considering aid effectiveness.[3]

Under the main international definition of aid – Official Development Assistance – any self-seeking motives of aid donors are supposed to be strictly subordinate to the objective of promoting the economic development and welfare of developing countries.[4] Such motives – which may involve strategic alliances, diplomatic trade-offs, commercial advantages and other political benefits[5] – are nowadays usually discussed as obstacles to aid effectiveness rather than alternative aims.

In the first decade of the 20th century, "aid effectiveness" was the declared focus of a movement joined by major donor and recipient countries and aid-related organisations, involving a series of high level forums on aid effectiveness. The agenda of this movement was largely about good practices in donor-recipient relationships, and in some cases these good practices became seen as proxies for aid effectiveness.[6]

History edit

The historical themes of aid effectiveness are rather different for humanitarian aid and developmental aid, so these have been treated in different sections below.

Development aid effectiveness (historical perspective) edit

1945 – early 1970s: Post-war boom edit

Although US aid is widely credited with having hastened the reconstruction of western Europe after World War II, there have been doubts about the effectiveness of this aid. G. A. Duncan in 1950 deplored the governmental character of Marshall Aid, arguing that private loans could have achieved the economic purposes more efficiently. He acknowledged that the provision of official aid also had other – political – purposes.[7]

When US economic aid shifted from Europe to poorer countries – as initially signalled by President Truman in Point Four of his 1949 inauguration speech – the strategic framework was one of building a "free world" in the face of communist threat. In the 1950s, official US development assistance was mobilized alongside military aid within the Mutual Security Program.[8] A 1957 Senate Special Committee report admitted it was impossible to prove how effective US aid since World War II had been, but considered that, without it, several countries might have been lost to the Soviet Union's sphere of influence.[9] For greater clarity in future, the committee attempted to distill the purposes of US aid into four:

  • The defense need: aid could persuade and enable other nations to be military allies (important for maintaining air bases in distant parts of the world).
  • The economic need: aid could bring more nations into a global system of commerce that would benefit the US.
  • The political need: aid could be one factor (among many others needed) for helping countries to make "long-range political progress toward freedom" rather than totalitarianism.
  • The humanitarian motive, which was seen in responding to "natural disasters or other unexpected conditions".[10]

The first of these aid drivers could be seen, during the Cold War, as part of a competition with the Soviet Union to win influence.[11] But aid was often observed to fail in this respect; for instance, in the 1950s and 1960s Egypt and Afghanistan took aid from both sides without making a decisive commitment either way, and large Russian support to China and Indonesia did not prevent those countries' leaders turning against their former patron.[11]

A more detailed theory about the kinds of effect and the causal paths through which aid could be effective was developed by Max Millikan and Walt Rostow in the mid- to late-1950s, expressed in "A Proposal" of 1956. This propounded that aid in the form of investment funds could promote the "take-off" of economies into self-reliant growth. It further suggested that this economic transformation, channeled properly, could produce a free and democratic type of society by providing: a constructive outlet for nationalism; a social solvent by interesting the urban elites in a dynamic agricultural sector; a stimulus for the emergence of authentic leaders; incentives for the attitudes of political responsibility needed to support democratisation; and feelings of international solidarity.[12] Rostow later elaborated the "take-off" theory of development in his more famous work, "The Stages of Economic Growth", in which he stated that greatly increased economic aid was needed in order to outrace the effects of population growth.[13]

In 1966, Hollis Chenery and Alan Strout published a still more sophisticated and influential macro-economic model of the way aid could boost development.[14] It involved identifying for each country whether the bottlenecks to economic growth lay in the availability of skills, domestic savings, or export earnings. In this way, an appropriate mix of technical assistance, grants or loans could be decided. The focus was on achieving a target level of GNP growth, which helped consolidate this as the prime indicator of aid effectiveness. At this time Chenery and Strout pointed to the Philippines, Taiwan, Greece and Israel as examples of countries that seemed to have achieved self-sustaining growth rates with the help of aid.[14]

Early 1970s – mid-1990s: The rise of neoliberalism edit

The end of the post-war boom – marked particularly by the oil crisis of 1973 – was a watershed in attitudes to aid effectiveness, as it forced a reappraisal of the existing models.[15]

In the 1980s and 1990s NGOs played a greater part in international aid.[16]

After the end of the Cold War, the declared focus of official aid began to move further towards the alleviation of poverty and the promotion of development. The countries that were in the most need and poverty became more of a priority. Once the Cold War ended, Western donors were able to enforce aid conditionality better because they no longer had geopolitical interests in recipient countries. This allowed donors to condition aid on the basis that recipient governments make economic changes as well as democratic changes.[17] It is against this background that the international aid effectiveness movement began taking shape in the late 1990s as donor governments and aid agencies began working together to improve effectiveness.

Late 1990s onward: Millennial partnerships edit

The global "effectiveness" movement edit

Aid effectiveness became more strongly recognized as a global multilateral objective in 2002 at the International Conference on Financing for Development in Monterrey, Mexico, which established the Monterrey Consensus.[18] There, the international community agreed to increase its funding for development—but acknowledged that more money alone was not enough. Donors and developing countries alike wanted to know that aid would be used as effectively as possible. They wanted it to play its optimum role in helping poor countries achieve the Millennium Development Goals, the set of targets agreed by 192 countries in 2000 which aimed to halve world poverty by 2015. Over the following nine years, a process punctuated by four high level forums on aid effectiveness (Rome 2003, Paris 2005, Accra 2008 and Busan 2011) consolidated a set of recognised good practices in aid effectiveness, and a framework for monitoring them.

In 2011 the dominant global agenda on "aid effectiveness" was subsumed in a broader movement for "effective development cooperation". This was embodied in the Global Partnership for Effective Development Co-operation (GPEDC) mandated at the Fourth High-Level Forum on Aid Effectiveness in Busan in 2011. GPEDC endorsed the prior "aid effectiveness" principles and commitments, and added others more widely concerned with development cooperation.

Another global partnership that follows the "effective development cooperation" approach is UHC2030 (the International Health Partnership for Universal Health Care 2030), formerly known simply as the International Health Partnership (or IHP+).[19][20]

See below for more details of the aid effectiveness principles and practices advocated by this movement and its component partnerships.

Humanitarian aid effectiveness (historical perspective) edit

Widespread famine in Biafra during the Nigerian Civil War (1967–1970) led to greater NGO involvement in events like the Biafran airlift being attempted for the first time.[21] The way in which aid was allocated during the 1983–1985 famine in Ethiopia forever changed the way in which governments and NGOs respond to international emergencies taking place within conflict situations and raised disturbing questions about the relationship between humanitarian agencies and host governments.[22]

Findings and critiques on aid effectiveness edit

There is wide agreement that aid alone is not enough to lift developing countries out of poverty and that it is not the most powerful potential instrument for promoting this end. The debates on aid effectiveness are over the degree of significance of aid's effects, the extent of its unfavourable effects, and the relative effectiveness of different kinds of aid.

Major critiques edit

P. T. Bauer edit

British economist P. T. Bauer argued that aid did more harm than good, notably in his books "Dissent on Development" (1972)[23] and "Reality and Rhetoric" (1984).[24] The main harmful effect was that aid channelled resources through governments, enabling inefficient state planning and producing a general "politicization of life" in which the population shifted its activities to the political sphere rather than the economic one.[25] On the other side, Bauer saw aid's benefits as being limited to the avoidance of commercial loan costs, which he did not consider to be a significant factor in countries' development (pp. 47-49). He believed that the choices of aid projects were usually controlled by recipient governments less interested in alleviating poverty than enriching the elite (pp.49-52).

Dambisa Moyo edit

Noted Zambian economist Dambisa Moyo has been a fierce opponent to development aid, and calls it “the single worst decision of modern developmental politics”. Her 2009 book, Dead Aid describes how aid has encouraged kleptocracies, corruption, aid-dependency and a series of detrimental economic effects and vicious downward spirals of development in Africa. She argues that foreign aid provides a windfall to governments which can encourage extreme forms of rent-seeking and through providing a positive shock of revenue, lead to Dutch Disease. Furthermore, this easy money offers governments an exit from the contract between them and their electorate: the contract that states that they must provide public goods in exchange for taxes. In short, it "allows the state to abdicate its responsibilities toward its people".[26] It is important to note that Moyo alludes specifically to government bilateral and multilateral aid and not small-holder charity, humanitarian or emergency aid. Her prescriptions call for increased trade and foreign direct investment, emphasizing China's burgeoning role in Africa.[27] Moyo also makes a case for micro-financing schemes, as popularized by the widespread success of Grameen Bank, to spark entrepreneurship within the continent on the ground level, thus building from the bottom-up as opposed to the top-down approach aid takes.

Econometric Studies edit

Many econometric studies have attempted to establish broad conclusions about aid, using regression analysis on a panel of recipient countries (seeing if their differing amounts and timings of aid received could be correlated with development indicators). These have created a mixed picture on the average effectiveness of aid, but one in which pessimism in the late 20th century has seemed to yield to qualified optimism in the early 21st century.[28] See the table in the sub-section on "Major econometric studies and their findings", below.

Challenges for measurement edit

It must be borne in mind that such econometric studies face many problems. One challenge for assessing the effectiveness of aid is that aid is intended to serve a variety of purposes: some of it is aimed primarily at poverty alleviation, some at economic growth, and some at other objectives such as better governance or reduction of social inequalities. Often it is not very clear what objectives are foremost, making it hard to measure results against intentions.[29] Roodman (2007), for instance, discovered that the results of seven previous econometric studies – including the very influential one by Burnside and Dollar (1997, 2000) – could not survive defining key terms in other plausible ways.[30] Moreover, different objectives have different implications for the time-scale in which results should be sought.[31] Varying sectors and modalities of aid have different effects, as do the contextual factors in recipient countries.[32] However, increasingly sophisticated analyses have made progress in accounting for these complicated effects.[31][32]

Econometric studies frequently show more pessimistic results than might be expected from the accumulation of successes reported by donor and implementing agencies in their projects and programs. Paul Mosley termed this the micro-macro paradox and offered three potential explanations: inaccurate measurement, fungibility, and "backwash" or negative side-effects of component aid projects.[33] The micro-macro paradox has also been attributed to inadequate assessment practices. For example, conventional assessment techniques often over-emphasize inputs and outputs without taking sufficient account of societal impacts. The shortcomings of prevalent assessment practices have led to a gradual international trend towards more rigorous methods of impact assessment.[34]

Major econometric studies and their findings edit

The main findings of major econometric studies are summarized in the following table.

Table of econometric studies on aid effectiveness
Author/year[35] Period Findings on aid effectiveness;
Mosley 1987[36] 1960-1980 Aid had no significant effect on economic growth. The reason seemed to be fungibility: aid likely released other resources for unproductive uses.
Boone 1996[37][38] 1971-1990 Aid had no clear effect on rates of infant mortality and primary education.
Burnside and Dollar 1997,[39] 2000[40] 1970-1993 Aid had a positive impact on growth in developing countries with good policies. But the overall effect of aid was unclear because donors did not especially target such countries.
Svensson 1999[41] 1980s, 1990s Aid had a positive impact on growth in more democratic countries. But aid on average was not channeled to more democratic countries.
Arvin and Borillas 2002[42] 1975-1998 Aid had no clear effect on GNP per capita.
Kosack 2003[43] 1974-1985 Aid had no clear effect on average, but improved the quality of life when combined with democracy.
Dunning 2004 [44] 1975-1997 In the first few years after the Cold War foreign aid produced a small positive effect on democracy in sub-Saharan African countries, unlike in the previous 15 years.
Easterly et al. 2004[45] 1970-1997 The finding of Burnside and Dollar (2000, see above) is not robust to different definitions of aid and good policy.
Mosley et al. 2004[46] 1980-2000 Aid increased pro-poor public spending in low-income countries.
Rajan and Subramanian 2005 [47] 1960-2000 There was on average no robust positive relationship between aid and growth.
Yontcheva and Masud 2005[48] 1990-2001 Aid by NGOs co-financed by the European Commission reduced infant mortality but bilateral aid generally did not.
Calderon et al. 2006[49][50] 1971–2002 Aid had no clear effect on poverty, inequality, economic growth or democratic institutions.
Mosley and Suleiman 2007[51] 1980-2002 Aid most effectively reduced poverty when it supported public expenditures on agriculture, education and infrastructure.
Bahmani-Oskooee and Oyolola 2009[52] 1981-2002 Aid was on average effective in reducing poverty.
Clemens et al. 2011[53] 1970-2000 Aid had a modest positive effect on economic growth.[54]
Alvi and Senbeta 2012[55] 1981-2004 Aid--especially multilateral aid--significantly reduced poverty.
Kaya et al. 2013[56] 1980-2003 Aid to agriculture significantly reduced poverty.
Hirano and Otsubo 2014[57] 1990s, 2000s Social aid directly benefitted the poorest in society, while economic aid increased the income of the poor through growth.
Nunn and Qian 2014[58] 1971-2006 U.S. food aid increased the incidence and duration of civil conflicts, but had no robust effect on inter-state conflicts or the onset of civil conflicts.[59]
Arndt et al 2015[60] 1970-2007 Aid moderately stimulated growth, promoted structural change, improved social indicators, and reduced poverty.
Petrikova 2015 1994-2011 Aid had a small positive effect on food security
Janjua et al. 2018[61] 1995-2009 Project aid had a significant effect on economic growth. Programme aid had a significant effect on social development.
Abellán and Alonso 2022[62] 1990-2015 Aid had a positive effect on access to safe drinking water, this effect being especially important when consistent long-term investments are put into place.

Analyses of factors limiting aid effectiveness edit

Aid fragmentation edit

Aid flows significantly increased in the first decade of the 21st century, but at the same time aid has become increasingly fragmented. There was an explosion in the number of donors, and while the number of projects multiplied, their average size dropped. Small projects being often limited in size, scope and duration, they resulted in little lasting benefit beyond the immediate effect.[63] With more players, aid became less predictable, less transparent and more volatile.[64]

Fragmentation means an increase in costs for recipient countries, as government offices are forced to divert administrative resources to cope with requests and meetings with donors[65] Decades of development have shown that if countries are to become less dependent on aid, they must follow a bottom-up approach, where they determine their own priorities and rely on their own systems to deliver that aid.[66]

Volatility/unpredictability of aid edit

Information, at the donors' as well at the recipients' level, is often poor, incomplete and difficult to compare with other data, and beneficiaries' feedback and formal project evaluations are rare. Aid is predictable when partner countries can be confident about the amount and the timing of aid disbursement. Not being predictable has a cost: one study assessed the deadweight loss associated with volatility at an average of 10% to 20% of a developing country's programmable aid from the European Union in recent years.[67]

Reducing the accountability of governments edit

Revenue generation is one of the essential pillars for developing state capacity. Effective taxation methods allow a state to provide public goods and services, from ensuring justice to providing education.[68] Taxation simultaneously serves as a government accountability mechanism, building state-citizen relationships, as citizens can now expect such service provisions upon their consent to taxation. For developing and fragile states that lack such revenue capabilities, while aid can be a seemingly necessary alternative, it has the potential to undermine institutional development. States that rely on higher percentages of aid for government revenue are less accountable to their citizens by avoiding the state-citizen relationships that taxation builds and face fewer incentives to develop public institutions.[69] The limited government capacity resulting from subpar institutional presence and effectiveness leads to: “ubiquitous corruption of state officials, large gaps between the law and actual practice in business regulation, workers who do not even show up, doctors that do not doctor, teachers who do not teach.”[70]

In the view of James Shikwati, aid in Africa sustains political elites who implement a colonial or neo-colonial agenda of subsidy and distortion of markets which holds African countries back.[71]

The tying of aid edit

Tied aid is defined as project aid contracted by source to private firms in the donor country. It refers to aid tied to goods and services supplied exclusively by donor country businesses or agencies. Tied aid increases the cost of assistance and has the tendency of making donors to focus more on the commercial advancement of their countries than what developing countries need. There are many ways aid can be designed to pursue the commercial objectives of donors. One of such pervasive means is by insisting on donor country products.

Others have argued that tying aid to donor-country products is common sense; it is a strategic use of aid to promote donor country's business or exports. It is further argued that tied aid - if well designed and effectively managed - would not necessarily compromise the quality as well as the effectiveness of aid.[72] However, this argument would hold particularly for programme aid, where aid is tied to a specific projects or policies and where there is little or no commercial interest. It must be emphasized, however, that commercial interest and aid effectiveness are two different things, and it would be difficult to pursue commercial interest without compromising aid effectiveness. Thus, the idea of maximizing development should be separated from the notion of pursuing commercial interest. Tied aid improves donors export performance, creates business for local companies and jobs. It also helps to expose firms, which have not had any international experience on the global market to do so.[73]

Fungibility of aid edit

Aid is often fungible,[74] meaning that aided activities which appear to be successful may be filling a role that would have been covered anyway by local resources; the effect of the aid is thus only to release those local resources for other purposes, which may not be so desirable.

Ways to improve aid effectiveness edit

Targeting aid more precisely edit

Using the private sector edit

According to Laurie Garrett, for health aid to be maximized efficiently and most optimally, donations need to be directed to areas such as local industries, franchises, or profit centers in developing countries. By doing so, these actions can sustain health related spending and result in growth in the long run.[75]

Paul Collier, in The Bottom Billion, suggests a model he calls “Independent Service Authorities”. These are organizations, independent from the government, that co-opt civil society to manage aid and public money and incorporate the scrutiny of public opinion and NGOs to determine how to maximize output from the expenditure of this money.[76]

William Easterly tells a story in The White Man’s Burden, where he says that helping the approximate three million people infected with Malaria each year may not be as simple as sending nets over to Africa. A lot of the time, these nets are diverted to the black market and used for more entrepreneurial pursuits, for example, making fishing nets out of them. Easterly does go on to report however that when schemes are introduced where mosquito nets are available on the market for an affordable price, the usage of them increases drastically.[77] He advocates the use of localized, tailored schemes like this to help the world's poor and discounts ambitious overarching schemes that claim to be a complete panacea for poverty.

Sensitivity to recipient country institutions edit

Since the effectiveness of aid usually depends on the good-functioning of institutions in the recipient country, and since potential recipients are very varied in this respect, Charles Kenny (2006) argues that aid strategies must be tailored to the state of institutions in each case. Where institutions are strong, it is appropriate to provide programmatic aid. Where they are weak, there may be a role for aid in analysis, consensus-building and technical assistance to improve them, and meanwhile other "insulated" projects might go ahead if they do not harm the prospects for developing sound governmental institutions.[78]

Reform of state institutions edit

Noted Peruvian economist, Hernando de Soto, in his book, The Mystery of Capital[79] also firmly asserts that Africa already has the resource wealth it needs to pull itself out of poverty, it just lacks the institutions that allow for the creation of wealth from these riches. Poor documentation of assets and the lack of property rights means that people cannot collateralize their assets, for example, if a farmer inhabits a tract of land that has been in his family for generations, in his view, for all intents and purposes, he owns the land. However he does not possess a title deed to the land that clearly demarcates the borders of his ownership, this means that he cannot put up this land as collateral to secure a loan. This simplistic example can help to explain why investment (and therefore growth) is inhibited, the spirit of entrepreneurship may be present, the tools to engage in it, however, are not. The answer, therefore, seems simple: create such institutions that provide transparent documentation of assets and allow them to be converted to liquidity with ease. In practice, however, this may not be so simple and would involve major overhauls in the bureaucratic fabric of a state. How aid can help to foster better institutions then, becomes the main question.

Best practices according to the High Level Forums on Aid Effectiveness edit

The Paris Declaration and other results of the High Level Forums on Aid Effectiveness (2003-2011) embodied a broad consensus on what needed to be done to produce better development results.[80] Its principles lay open the possible ways to undertake, which can be interpreted also as the major objectives of good aid: fostering recipient countries' ownership of development policies and strategies, maximizing donors' coordination and harmonization, improving aid transparency and mutual accountability of donors and recipients, just to name a few.[81]

The forums were supported by work done by the OECD, which had explored—through peer reviews and other work by the Development Assistance Committee (DAC)—the reasons why aid has and has not worked. This has resulted in a body of best practices and principles that can be applied globally to make aid work better.

Improving aid transparency and mutual accountability of donors and recipients edit

Some believe that the way to improvement is through better monitoring and evaluation, increased transparency, accountability and learning. For instance, Stefan Schmitz, a former senior aid official in the German government and the OECD, has argued that reporting duties, results-orientated action and ongoing performance assessments are essential for the sake of aid effectiveness, but political will must be already there for this to happen.[82]

The Accra Agenda for Action states that transparency and accountability are essential elements for development results, as well as drivers of progress.[83] Mutual accountability and transparency is one of the five partnership commitments of the Paris Declaration.[84] Through 'transparency', donors and recipients can be held accountable for what they spend and aid can be made more effective by knowing the three Ws of transparency:

  • Who gives money to which recipient?
  • What project is being funded and for what purpose? and
  • Where?[85]

Transparency offers a valuable answer to insecurity, making aid "predictable" and "reliable". Transparency has been shown to improve service delivery and to reduce opportunities for diversion and therefore corruption.[86]

Transparency can be defined as a basic expression of mutual accountability.[87] Mutual accountability can only work if there is a global culture of transparency that demands provision of information through a set of rules and behavioral norms, which are difficult to enforce in the case of official development cooperation. In particular for emerging economy donors and private development assistance, these norms are only at a nascent stage. Kharas[88] suggest to adopt the "regulation through information" approach,[89] which has been developed and has proven its effectiveness in the case of the European integration. In fact, at the international level, when the enforcement of mandatory rules is difficult, the solution could be to provide and make available transparent, relevant, accurate and reliable information, which can be used to reward or sanction individual aid agencies according to their performances. This means establishing a strong culture of accountability within aid, which rewards aid successes but penalizes failures.

To achieve this, literature on the topic[90] suggest that donors should agree on adopting a standardized format for providing information on volume, allocation and results, such as the International Aid Transparency Initiative (IATI), or other similar standards, and commit to improve recipient countries' databases with technical, financial and informational support. The format should be easily downloadable and with sufficient disaggregation to enable comparison with other data. Making aid data public and comparable among donors, would be likely to encourage a process of positive emulation towards a better usage of public funds. After all, official development assistance (ODA) is a voluntary transfer that depends on the support of donor country taxpayers. Donors should therefore consider improving the transparency and traceability of aid funds also as a way of increasing engagement and support toward aid inside their own country. Moreover, a generalized adoption of IATI would ensure the publication of aid information in a timely way, the compatibility with developing countries' budgets and the reliability of future projections, which would have a strong and positive effect on the predictability of aid.[91]

Finally, to improve accountability while building evaluation capabilities in aid recipient countries and systematically collecting beneficiaries’ feedback, different mechanisms to evaluate and monitor transparency should be considered, such as independent third-party reviews, peer reviews or mutual reviews.[92]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Kenny, Charles (September 2006). What is effective aid? How would donors allocate it? (PDF) (Report). World Bank. p. 2-3. Retrieved 2021-03-05.
  2. ^ Mahbub ul Haq; et al. (1990). Human Development Report 1990 (PDF). UNDP. Retrieved 2021-03-01.
  3. ^ a b Barder, Owen (2009). "What Is Poverty Reduction?" (PDF). Centre for Global Development. (PDF) from the original on 2020-12-23.
  4. ^ "Official Development Assistance (ODA)". OECD. from the original on 2019-04-22. Retrieved 2021-03-01.
  5. ^ Kenny, Charles (2006). "What Is Effective Aid? How Would Donors Allocate It?" (PDF). The World Bank. (PDF) from the original on 2021-11-01. Retrieved 2021-03-01.
  6. ^ Mitchell, Ian; McKee, Caitlin (15 November 2018). "How Do You Measure Aid Quality and Who Ranks Highest?". Center for Global Development. from the original on 2019-05-10. Retrieved 2021-03-01.
  7. ^ Duncan, G. A. (1950). "Marshall Aid". Journal of the Statistical and Social Inquiry Society of Ireland. 18: 293.
  8. ^ Haviland, H. Field (1958). "Foreign Aid and the Policy Process: 1957". American Political Science Review. 52 (3): 689–724. doi:10.2307/1951900. ISSN 1537-5943. JSTOR 1951900. S2CID 144564474.
  9. ^ US Senate Special Committee (1957). Report of the special committee to study the foreign aid program. United States Government Printing Office. pp. 7–8.
  10. ^ US Senate Special Committee (1957). Report of the special committee to study the foreign aid program. United States Government Printing Office. pp. 8–10.
  11. ^ a b Morgner, Aurelius (1967). "The American Foreign Aid Program: Costs, Accomplishments, Alternatives?". The Review of Politics. 29 (1): 72–73. doi:10.1017/S0034670500023731. ISSN 0034-6705. JSTOR 1405813. S2CID 145492668.
  12. ^ Millikan, Max F (1957). A proposal: Key to an effective foreign policy. New York: Harper & Brothers.
  13. ^ Rostow, W. W. (1962). The Stages of Economic Growth. Cambridge University Press. p. 143.
  14. ^ a b Chenery, Hollis B.; Strout, Alan M. (1966). "Foreign Assistance and Economic Development". The American Economic Review. 56 (4): 679–733. ISSN 0002-8282. JSTOR 1813524.
  15. ^ Riddell, Roger (1987). Foreign aid reconsidered. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. pp. 92–95. ISBN 0-8018-3546-1. OCLC 15630613.
  16. ^ Lewis D. (2010) "Nongovernmental Organizations, Definition and History" (PDF). In: Anheier H.K., Toepler S. (eds) International Encyclopedia of Civil Society. Springer, New York, NY.
  17. ^ Dunning, Thad. "Conditioning the Effects of Aid: Cold War Politics, Donor Credibility, and Democracy in Africa." International Organization 58.02 (2004)
  18. ^ "International Conference on Financing for Development". Un.org. Retrieved 2012-12-26.
  19. ^ "uhc2030: History". UHC2030. from the original on 2017-10-01. Retrieved 2021-02-27.
  20. ^ "IHP+ Strategic Directions 2016-17" (PDF). uhc2030. Retrieved 2021-02-27.
  21. ^ Omaka, Arua Oko (1 June 2016). "Humanitarian Action: The Joint Church Aid and Health Care Intervention in the Nigeria-Biafra War, 1967–1970". Canadian Journal of History. 49 (3): 423–227. doi:10.3138/cjh.49.3.423.
  22. ^ Waal, Alexander De (1991). Evil Days: Thirty Years of War and Famine in Ethiopia. Human Rights Watch. p. 2. ISBN 9781564320384.
  23. ^ Bauer, P. T. (1976). Dissent on development. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. ISBN 0-674-21282-7. OCLC 2666082.
  24. ^ Bauer, P. T. (1984). Reality and rhetoric : studies in the economics of development. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. ISBN 0-674-74946-4. OCLC 9894295.
  25. ^ Bauer, P. T. (1984). Reality and rhetoric : studies in the economics of development. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. pp. 27–28, 46. ISBN 0-674-74946-4. OCLC 9894295.
  26. ^ Moyo, Dambisa (2009). Aid: Why Aid Is Not Working and How There Is a Better Way for Africa. Douglas & Mcintyre. ISBN 978-1-55365-542-8.
  27. ^ Moyo, Dambisa (2009). Dead Aid: Why Aid Is Not Working and How There Is a Better Way for Africa. Douglas & Mcintyre. p. 124.
  28. ^ Mahembe, Edmore; Odhiambo, Nicholas M. (2019-01-01). Read, Robert (ed.). "Foreign aid and poverty reduction: A review of international literature". Cogent Social Sciences. 5 (1): 1625741. doi:10.1080/23311886.2019.1625741. ISSN 2331-1886.
  29. ^ Barder, Owen (2009-04-21). "What is Poverty Reduction?". CGD Working Papers. Retrieved 2010-06-02.
  30. ^ Roodman, David (2007). "The Anarchy of Numbers: Aid, Development and Cross-Country Empirics". The World Bank Economic Review. 21 (2): 255–277. doi:10.1093/wber/lhm004. hdl:10.1093/wber/lhm004. S2CID 14359188.
  31. ^ a b Clemens MA; et al. (2011). "Counting Chickens when they Hatch: Timing and the Effects of Aid on Growth". The Economic Journal. 122 (561): 590–617. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2011.02482.x.
  32. ^ a b Petrikova, Ivica (2015). "Aid for food security: does it work?" (PDF). International Journal of Development Issues. 14: 41–59. doi:10.1108/IJDI-07-2014-0058.
  33. ^ Mosley, Paul (1987). Foreign Aid: Its Defense and Reform. University Press of Kentucky. ISBN 978-0-8131-1608-2. Retrieved December 7, 2009. Paul Mosley.
  34. ^ Faust, Jörg (2009). . Development and Cooperation. 36 (1): 14–17. Archived from the original on 2010-02-27.
  35. ^ Bibliographic reference to be given in a note
  36. ^ Mosley, Paul (1987). Foreign aid, its defense and reform. Lexington, Ky.: University Press of Kentucky. ISBN 0-8131-1608-2. OCLC 14240724.
  37. ^ Boone, Peter (1995). Politics and the effectiveness of foreign aid (PDF) (Report). National Bureau of Economic Research. Retrieved 2021-02-19.
  38. ^ A similar version was published as Boone, Peter (1996). "Politics and the effectiveness of foreign aid" (PDF). European Economic Review. 40 (2): 289–329. doi:10.1016/0014-2921(95)00127-1. S2CID 154155908 – via Science Direct.
  39. ^ Burnside, Craig; Dollar, David (1997). Aid, policies and growth (PDF) (Report). World Bank. Retrieved 2021-02-20.
  40. ^ Burnside, Craig; Dollar, David (September 2000). "Aid, Policies, and Growth". American Economic Review. 90 (4): 847–868. doi:10.1257/aer.90.4.847. ISSN 0002-8282. S2CID 14261087.
  41. ^ Svensson, J. (1999). "Aid, Growth and Democracy". Economics & Politics. 11 (3): 275–297. doi:10.1111/1468-0343.00062. ISSN 1468-0343.
  42. ^ Arvin, B. Mak; Barillas, Francisco (2002-11-01). "Foreign aid, poverty reduction, and democracy". Applied Economics. 34 (17): 2151–2156. doi:10.1080/00036840210136718. ISSN 0003-6846. S2CID 154546476.
  43. ^ Kosack, Stephen (2003-01-01). "Effective Aid: How Democracy Allows Development Aid to Improve the Quality of Life". World Development. 31 (1): 1–22. doi:10.1016/S0305-750X(02)00177-8. ISSN 0305-750X.
  44. ^ Dunning, Thad (2004). "Conditioning the Effects of Aid: Cold War Politics, Donor Credibility, and Democracy in Africa". International Organization. 58 (2): 409–423. doi:10.1017/S0020818304582073. ISSN 1531-5088. S2CID 154368924.
  45. ^ Easterly, William; Levine, Ross; Roodman, David (2004-05-01). "Aid, Policies, and Growth: Comment". American Economic Review. 94 (3): 774–780. doi:10.1257/0002828041464560. ISSN 0002-8282.
  46. ^ Mosley, Paul; Hudson, John; Verschoor, Arjan (2004-06-01). "Aid, Poverty Reduction and the 'New Conditionality'". The Economic Journal. 114 (496): F217–F243. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2004.00220.x. ISSN 0013-0133. S2CID 55919902.
  47. ^ Rajan, Raghuram G.; Subramanian, Arvind (2005). Aid and growth: What does the cross-country evidence really show? (PDF) (Report). National Bureau of Economic Research. Retrieved 2021-02-23.
  48. ^ Yontcheva, Boriana; Masud, Nadia (2005). Does Foreign Aid Reduce Poverty? Empirical Evidence from Nongovernmental and Bilateral Aid (Report). IMF. Retrieved 2021-02-19.
  49. ^ Calderon, Mark; Chong, Alberto; Gradstein (2006). Foreign aid, income inequality, and poverty (PDF) (Report). Inter-American Development Bank. Retrieved 2021-02-20.
  50. ^ A similar version was published as Chong, Alberto; Gradstein, Mark; Calderon, Cecilia (2009-07-01). "Can foreign aid reduce income inequality and poverty?". Public Choice. 140 (1): 59–84. doi:10.1007/s11127-009-9412-4. ISSN 1573-7101. S2CID 154071767.
  51. ^ Mosley, Paul; Suleiman, Abrar (2007). "Aid, Agriculture and Poverty in Developing Countries". Review of Development Economics. 11 (1): 139–158. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9361.2006.00354.x. ISSN 1467-9361. S2CID 154905396.
  52. ^ Bahmani‐Oskooee, Mohsen; Oyolola, Maharouf (2009-01-01). "Poverty reduction and aid: cross‐country evidence". International Journal of Sociology and Social Policy. 29 (5/6): 264–273. doi:10.1108/01443330910965796. ISSN 0144-333X.
  53. ^ Clemens, Michael A.; Radelet, Steven; Bhavnani, Rikhil R.; Bazzi, Samuel (2012-06-01). "Counting Chickens when they Hatch: Timing and the Effects of Aid on Growth". The Economic Journal. 122 (561): 590–617. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2011.02482.x. ISSN 0013-0133.
  54. ^ The study re-analyzed data from Boone (1996), Burnside and Dollar (2000), and Rajan and Subramanian (2008), treating time-lags differently.
  55. ^ Alvi, Eskander; Senbeta, Aberra (2012). "Does Foreign Aid Reduce Poverty?". Journal of International Development. 24 (8): 955–976. doi:10.1002/jid.1790. ISSN 1099-1328.
  56. ^ Kaya, Ozgur; Kaya, Ilker; Gunter, Lewell (2013). "Foreign Aid and the Quest for Poverty Reduction: Is Aid to Agriculture Effective?". Journal of Agricultural Economics. 64 (3): 583–596. doi:10.1111/1477-9552.12023. ISSN 1477-9552.
  57. ^ Hirano, Yumeka; Otsubo, Shigero (2014). Aid Is Good for the Poor (Report). World Bank. Retrieved 2021-02-20.
  58. ^ Nunn, Nathan; Qian, Nancy (2014-06-01). "US Food Aid and Civil Conflict". American Economic Review. 104 (6): 1630–1666. doi:10.1257/aer.104.6.1630. ISSN 0002-8282. S2CID 12935268.
  59. ^ Nunn and Qian acknowledged that such aid might also have other, possibly beneficial, effects
  60. ^ Arndt, Channing; Jones, Sam; Tarp, Finn (2015-05-01). "Assessing Foreign Aid's Long-Run Contribution to Growth and Development". World Development. 69: 6–18. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.12.016. ISSN 0305-750X.
  61. ^ Janjua, Pervez Zamurrad; Muhammad, Malik; Usman, Muhammad (2018-06-01). "Impact of Project and Programme Aid on Economic Growth: A Cross Country Analysis". The Pakistan Development Review. 57 (2): 145–174. doi:10.30541/v57i2pp.145-174. ISSN 0030-9729.
  62. ^ Abellán, Javier; Alonso, José Antonio (2022). "Promoting global access to water and sanitation: A supply and demand perspective". Water Resources and Economics. 38: 100194. doi:10.1016/j.wre.2022.100194. S2CID 246261266.
  63. ^ Fengler, M.G and Kharas, H. Delivering Aid Differently: Lesson from the Field. Brookings Institution, Washington D.C. 2010.
  64. ^ Kharas, H., Makino, K., Jung, W. Catalizing Development. Brookings Institution Press, Washington D.C. 2011
  65. ^ As an example, in 2005, government authorities in Vietnam received 791 missions from donors, which means more than two a day, including weekends and holidays. See, for example, OECD, DAC, "The Challenge of Capacity Development: Working Towards Good Practice", Paris, 2006.
  66. ^ Deutscher, E., and Fyson, S., "Improving the Effectiveness of Aid", Finance and Development, Vol. 25, n. 3, The International Monetary Fund, September 2008.
  67. ^ Kharas, H. "Measuring the Cost of Aid Volatility". Wolfensohn Centre for Development, Working Parper 3, Brookings Institution, Washington D.C. 2008
  68. ^ Bräutigam, Deborah (2002). "Building Leviathan: Revenue, State Capacity and Governance" (PDF). IDS Bulletin. 33 (3): 1–17. doi:10.1111/j.1759-5436.2002.tb00034.x.
  69. ^ "An Aid-Institutions Paradox? A Review Essay on Aid Dependency and State Building in Sub-Saharan Africa- Working Paper 74". Center For Global Development. Retrieved 2017-05-17.
  70. ^ Pritchett, Lant; Woolcock, Michael; Andrews, Matt (2013-01-01). "Looking Like a State: Techniques of Persistent Failure in State Capability for Implementation" (PDF). The Journal of Development Studies. 49 (1): 1–18. doi:10.1080/00220388.2012.709614. ISSN 0022-0388. S2CID 14363040.
  71. ^ Shikwati, James (2006). . Inter Region Economic Network: 6. Archived from the original on 2013-06-17.
  72. ^ Aryeetey, 1995; Sowa 1997.
  73. ^ Tied Aid and Multi-Donor Budgetary Support, Journal of International Development, Vol 17. Issue 8
  74. ^ Kenny, Charles (September 2006). What is effective aid? How would donors allocate it? (PDF) (Report). World Bank. p. 9. Retrieved 2021-03-05.
  75. ^ Garrett, Laurie. 2007. The Challenge of Global Health. Foreign Affairs 86 (1):14-38]
  76. ^ Collier, Paul (2007). The Bottom Billion: Why the Poorest Countries Are failing and What Can Be Done about It. Oxford.
  77. ^ Easterly, William (2006). The White Man's Burden: Why the West's Efforts to Aid the Rest Have Done so Much Ill and so Little Good. New york: Penguin Press.
  78. ^ Kenny, Charles (September 2006). What is effective aid? How would donors allocate it? (PDF) (Report). World Bank. Retrieved 2021-03-05.
  79. ^ Soto, Hernando de (2003). The mystery of capital: why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else (1. paperback ed.). New York: BasicBooks. ISBN 978-0-465-01615-0.
  80. ^ "Effective development co-operation - OECD". www.oecd.org. Retrieved 2019-07-04.
  81. ^ See OECD, "The Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness". March 2, 2005.
  82. ^ . Archived from the original on 2010-07-06. Retrieved 2010-03-11.
  83. ^ OECD, "The Accra Agenda For Action", 3rd High Level Forum on Aid Effectiveness, September 4, 2008.
  84. ^ OECD, "The Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness". March 2, 2005.
  85. ^ Kharas, H., "Transparency: Changing the Accountability Engagement, and Effectiveness of Aid", in: Kharas, H., Makino, K., Jung, W., "Catalyzing Development", Brookings Institution Press, Washington, D.C. 2011.
  86. ^ Bjorkman, M., Svensson, J., "Power to the People: Evidence from a Randomized Field Experience on Community-Based Monitoring in Uganda", Quarterly Journal of Economics 124, no. 2: 735-69, 2009.
  87. ^ Mary Robinson’s definition, in the OECD Survey on Monitoring The Paris Declaration, 2008.
  88. ^ See Kharas, H., "Transparency: Changing the Accountability Engagement, and Effectiveness of Aid", in: Kharas, H., Makino, K., Jung, W., "Catalyzing Development", Brookings Institution Press, Washington, D.C. 2011.
  89. ^ Majone, G. "The new European Agencies: regulation by information", Journal of European Public Policy 4, no. 2: 262-75, 1997.
  90. ^ See, for example, Pranay, S., and Hubbard, M., "A Future for Aid Data: Research towards a South-South Cooperation Data Categorization to complement on-going IATI Categorizations’", ongoing research, DFID Future of Aid and Beyond Research Competition 2010-11, 2011.
  91. ^ Kharas, H., Makino, K., Jung, W., "Catalyzing Development", Brookings Institution Press, Washington, D.C. 2011.
  92. ^ See Droop, J., Isenman, P., and Mlalazi, B., "Mutual accountability in Aid Effectiveness: International-Level Mechanisms", Briefing Note, n.3, Oxford Policy Management, 2008.

External links edit

  • Eurodad: The European Network on Debt and Development
  • Center for Global Development: Aid Effectiveness
  • The International Health Partnership (IHP+) A group of partners committed to putting international principles for effective aid and development cooperation into practice in the health sector
  • Millions Saved 2008-10-11 at the Wayback Machine A compilation of case studies of effective foreign assistance by the Center for Global Development.
  • Aideffectiveness.org
  • PubHealth.org - Ugandan effort to develop tools for harmonization
  • Initial article arguing for funding of projects confirmed as effective in randomized trials, followed by replies.
  • The Crisis in African Agriculture: A more effective use for EC aid? A Practical Action and Pelum 'African Voices' Report
  • European Network on Debt and Development reports, news and links on aid effectiveness
  • Euforic 2007-09-28 at the Wayback Machine pages on aid evaluation and effectiveness
  • From Paris to Accra: building the global governance of aid
  • - articles, reports, blogs, and jobs related to aid effectiveness
  • Three-Cs.net 2022-10-06 at the Wayback Machine Six joint-evaluations to explore and assess the role played by the Maastricht Treaty precepts of coordination, complementarity and coherence (3Cs) in the EU's development co-operation policies and operations
  • The OECD DAC's site on the Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness
  • Governance and Social Development Resource Centre's Topic Guide: Aid instruments and aid effectiveness 2008-03-15 at the Wayback Machine
  • ODI Briefing Paper: Aid effectiveness after Accra[permanent dead link]
  • EADI Online Dossier on Aid Effectiveness 2012-03-10 at the Wayback Machine
  • Masterclass on Aid Effectiveness
  • CSOs on the road from Accra to Busan
  • Aid for Trade in Asia and the Pacific: 12 Things to Know Asian Development Bank

effectiveness, impact, source, source, degree, success, failure, international, development, humanitarian, concern, with, effectiveness, might, high, level, generality, whether, average, fulfils, main, functions, that, supposed, have, might, more, detailed, co. Aid effectiveness and Impact source source Aid effectiveness is the degree of success or failure of international aid development aid or humanitarian aid Concern with aid effectiveness might be at a high level of generality whether aid on average fulfils the main functions that aid is supposed to have or it might be more detailed considering relative degrees of success between different types of aid in differing circumstances Questions of aid effectiveness have been highly contested by academics commentators and practitioners there is a large literature on the subject Econometric studies in the late 20th century often found the average effectiveness of aid to be minimal or even negative Such studies have appeared on the whole to yield more affirmative results in the early 21st century but the picture is complex and far from clear in many respects Many prescriptions have been made about how to improve aid effectiveness In 2003 2011 there existed a global movement in the name of aid effectiveness around four high level forums on aid effectiveness These elaborated a set of good practices concerning aid administration co ordination and relations between donors and recipient countries From 2011 this movement was subsumed in one concerned more broadly with effective development co operation largely embodied by the Global Partnership for Effective Development Co operation Contents 1 The concept of aid effectiveness 2 History 2 1 Development aid effectiveness historical perspective 2 1 1 1945 early 1970s Post war boom 2 1 2 Early 1970s mid 1990s The rise of neoliberalism 2 1 3 Late 1990s onward Millennial partnerships 2 1 3 1 The global effectiveness movement 2 2 Humanitarian aid effectiveness historical perspective 3 Findings and critiques on aid effectiveness 3 1 Major critiques 3 1 1 P T Bauer 3 1 2 Dambisa Moyo 3 2 Econometric Studies 3 2 1 Challenges for measurement 3 2 2 Major econometric studies and their findings 3 3 Analyses of factors limiting aid effectiveness 3 3 1 Aid fragmentation 3 3 2 Volatility unpredictability of aid 3 3 3 Reducing the accountability of governments 3 3 4 The tying of aid 3 3 5 Fungibility of aid 4 Ways to improve aid effectiveness 4 1 Targeting aid more precisely 4 1 1 Using the private sector 4 1 2 Sensitivity to recipient country institutions 4 1 3 Reform of state institutions 4 2 Best practices according to the High Level Forums on Aid Effectiveness 4 2 1 Improving aid transparency and mutual accountability of donors and recipients 5 See also 6 References 7 External linksThe concept of aid effectiveness editAny discussion of effectiveness must rely on understandings or assumptions about aims 1 In public discussions of aid effectiveness the general aim is usually assumed to be boosting the development of recipient countries and hence the well being of people living in them But development and well being are complex and slippery concepts The most popular summary indicator for a country s development is probably average national income per head in its population but this indicator does not capture inequalities of wealth and power or the structural characteristics of the country s institutions and economy 2 Since the 1990s the prime purpose of aid has widely been seen as poverty reduction but this too can be interpreted in a variety of ways How soon How sustainable What level 3 Such ambiguities should be clarified or at least borne in mind when considering aid effectiveness 3 Under the main international definition of aid Official Development Assistance any self seeking motives of aid donors are supposed to be strictly subordinate to the objective of promoting the economic development and welfare of developing countries 4 Such motives which may involve strategic alliances diplomatic trade offs commercial advantages and other political benefits 5 are nowadays usually discussed as obstacles to aid effectiveness rather than alternative aims In the first decade of the 20th century aid effectiveness was the declared focus of a movement joined by major donor and recipient countries and aid related organisations involving a series of high level forums on aid effectiveness The agenda of this movement was largely about good practices in donor recipient relationships and in some cases these good practices became seen as proxies for aid effectiveness 6 History editThe historical themes of aid effectiveness are rather different for humanitarian aid and developmental aid so these have been treated in different sections below Development aid effectiveness historical perspective edit 1945 early 1970s Post war boom edit Although US aid is widely credited with having hastened the reconstruction of western Europe after World War II there have been doubts about the effectiveness of this aid G A Duncan in 1950 deplored the governmental character of Marshall Aid arguing that private loans could have achieved the economic purposes more efficiently He acknowledged that the provision of official aid also had other political purposes 7 When US economic aid shifted from Europe to poorer countries as initially signalled by President Truman in Point Four of his 1949 inauguration speech the strategic framework was one of building a free world in the face of communist threat In the 1950s official US development assistance was mobilized alongside military aid within the Mutual Security Program 8 A 1957 Senate Special Committee report admitted it was impossible to prove how effective US aid since World War II had been but considered that without it several countries might have been lost to the Soviet Union s sphere of influence 9 For greater clarity in future the committee attempted to distill the purposes of US aid into four The defense need aid could persuade and enable other nations to be military allies important for maintaining air bases in distant parts of the world The economic need aid could bring more nations into a global system of commerce that would benefit the US The political need aid could be one factor among many others needed for helping countries to make long range political progress toward freedom rather than totalitarianism The humanitarian motive which was seen in responding to natural disasters or other unexpected conditions 10 The first of these aid drivers could be seen during the Cold War as part of a competition with the Soviet Union to win influence 11 But aid was often observed to fail in this respect for instance in the 1950s and 1960s Egypt and Afghanistan took aid from both sides without making a decisive commitment either way and large Russian support to China and Indonesia did not prevent those countries leaders turning against their former patron 11 A more detailed theory about the kinds of effect and the causal paths through which aid could be effective was developed by Max Millikan and Walt Rostow in the mid to late 1950s expressed in A Proposal of 1956 This propounded that aid in the form of investment funds could promote the take off of economies into self reliant growth It further suggested that this economic transformation channeled properly could produce a free and democratic type of society by providing a constructive outlet for nationalism a social solvent by interesting the urban elites in a dynamic agricultural sector a stimulus for the emergence of authentic leaders incentives for the attitudes of political responsibility needed to support democratisation and feelings of international solidarity 12 Rostow later elaborated the take off theory of development in his more famous work The Stages of Economic Growth in which he stated that greatly increased economic aid was needed in order to outrace the effects of population growth 13 In 1966 Hollis Chenery and Alan Strout published a still more sophisticated and influential macro economic model of the way aid could boost development 14 It involved identifying for each country whether the bottlenecks to economic growth lay in the availability of skills domestic savings or export earnings In this way an appropriate mix of technical assistance grants or loans could be decided The focus was on achieving a target level of GNP growth which helped consolidate this as the prime indicator of aid effectiveness At this time Chenery and Strout pointed to the Philippines Taiwan Greece and Israel as examples of countries that seemed to have achieved self sustaining growth rates with the help of aid 14 Early 1970s mid 1990s The rise of neoliberalism edit The end of the post war boom marked particularly by the oil crisis of 1973 was a watershed in attitudes to aid effectiveness as it forced a reappraisal of the existing models 15 In the 1980s and 1990s NGOs played a greater part in international aid 16 After the end of the Cold War the declared focus of official aid began to move further towards the alleviation of poverty and the promotion of development The countries that were in the most need and poverty became more of a priority Once the Cold War ended Western donors were able to enforce aid conditionality better because they no longer had geopolitical interests in recipient countries This allowed donors to condition aid on the basis that recipient governments make economic changes as well as democratic changes 17 It is against this background that the international aid effectiveness movement began taking shape in the late 1990s as donor governments and aid agencies began working together to improve effectiveness Late 1990s onward Millennial partnerships edit The global effectiveness movement edit Main articles High level forums on aid effectiveness and Global Partnership for Effective Development Co operation Aid effectiveness became more strongly recognized as a global multilateral objective in 2002 at the International Conference on Financing for Development in Monterrey Mexico which established the Monterrey Consensus 18 There the international community agreed to increase its funding for development but acknowledged that more money alone was not enough Donors and developing countries alike wanted to know that aid would be used as effectively as possible They wanted it to play its optimum role in helping poor countries achieve the Millennium Development Goals the set of targets agreed by 192 countries in 2000 which aimed to halve world poverty by 2015 Over the following nine years a process punctuated by four high level forums on aid effectiveness Rome 2003 Paris 2005 Accra 2008 and Busan 2011 consolidated a set of recognised good practices in aid effectiveness and a framework for monitoring them In 2011 the dominant global agenda on aid effectiveness was subsumed in a broader movement for effective development cooperation This was embodied in the Global Partnership for Effective Development Co operation GPEDC mandated at the Fourth High Level Forum on Aid Effectiveness in Busan in 2011 GPEDC endorsed the prior aid effectiveness principles and commitments and added others more widely concerned with development cooperation Another global partnership that follows the effective development cooperation approach is UHC2030 the International Health Partnership for Universal Health Care 2030 formerly known simply as the International Health Partnership or IHP 19 20 See below for more details of the aid effectiveness principles and practices advocated by this movement and its component partnerships Humanitarian aid effectiveness historical perspective edit Widespread famine in Biafra during the Nigerian Civil War 1967 1970 led to greater NGO involvement in events like the Biafran airlift being attempted for the first time 21 The way in which aid was allocated during the 1983 1985 famine in Ethiopia forever changed the way in which governments and NGOs respond to international emergencies taking place within conflict situations and raised disturbing questions about the relationship between humanitarian agencies and host governments 22 Findings and critiques on aid effectiveness editSee also Aid CriticismThere is wide agreement that aid alone is not enough to lift developing countries out of poverty and that it is not the most powerful potential instrument for promoting this end The debates on aid effectiveness are over the degree of significance of aid s effects the extent of its unfavourable effects and the relative effectiveness of different kinds of aid Major critiques edit P T Bauer edit British economist P T Bauer argued that aid did more harm than good notably in his books Dissent on Development 1972 23 and Reality and Rhetoric 1984 24 The main harmful effect was that aid channelled resources through governments enabling inefficient state planning and producing a general politicization of life in which the population shifted its activities to the political sphere rather than the economic one 25 On the other side Bauer saw aid s benefits as being limited to the avoidance of commercial loan costs which he did not consider to be a significant factor in countries development pp 47 49 He believed that the choices of aid projects were usually controlled by recipient governments less interested in alleviating poverty than enriching the elite pp 49 52 Dambisa Moyo edit Noted Zambian economist Dambisa Moyo has been a fierce opponent to development aid and calls it the single worst decision of modern developmental politics Her 2009 book Dead Aid describes how aid has encouraged kleptocracies corruption aid dependency and a series of detrimental economic effects and vicious downward spirals of development in Africa She argues that foreign aid provides a windfall to governments which can encourage extreme forms of rent seeking and through providing a positive shock of revenue lead to Dutch Disease Furthermore this easy money offers governments an exit from the contract between them and their electorate the contract that states that they must provide public goods in exchange for taxes In short it allows the state to abdicate its responsibilities toward its people 26 It is important to note that Moyo alludes specifically to government bilateral and multilateral aid and not small holder charity humanitarian or emergency aid Her prescriptions call for increased trade and foreign direct investment emphasizing China s burgeoning role in Africa 27 Moyo also makes a case for micro financing schemes as popularized by the widespread success of Grameen Bank to spark entrepreneurship within the continent on the ground level thus building from the bottom up as opposed to the top down approach aid takes Econometric Studies edit Many econometric studies have attempted to establish broad conclusions about aid using regression analysis on a panel of recipient countries seeing if their differing amounts and timings of aid received could be correlated with development indicators These have created a mixed picture on the average effectiveness of aid but one in which pessimism in the late 20th century has seemed to yield to qualified optimism in the early 21st century 28 See the table in the sub section on Major econometric studies and their findings below Challenges for measurement edit It must be borne in mind that such econometric studies face many problems One challenge for assessing the effectiveness of aid is that aid is intended to serve a variety of purposes some of it is aimed primarily at poverty alleviation some at economic growth and some at other objectives such as better governance or reduction of social inequalities Often it is not very clear what objectives are foremost making it hard to measure results against intentions 29 Roodman 2007 for instance discovered that the results of seven previous econometric studies including the very influential one by Burnside and Dollar 1997 2000 could not survive defining key terms in other plausible ways 30 Moreover different objectives have different implications for the time scale in which results should be sought 31 Varying sectors and modalities of aid have different effects as do the contextual factors in recipient countries 32 However increasingly sophisticated analyses have made progress in accounting for these complicated effects 31 32 Econometric studies frequently show more pessimistic results than might be expected from the accumulation of successes reported by donor and implementing agencies in their projects and programs Paul Mosley termed this the micro macro paradox and offered three potential explanations inaccurate measurement fungibility and backwash or negative side effects of component aid projects 33 The micro macro paradox has also been attributed to inadequate assessment practices For example conventional assessment techniques often over emphasize inputs and outputs without taking sufficient account of societal impacts The shortcomings of prevalent assessment practices have led to a gradual international trend towards more rigorous methods of impact assessment 34 Major econometric studies and their findings edit The main findings of major econometric studies are summarized in the following table Table of econometric studies on aid effectiveness Author year 35 Period Findings on aid effectiveness Mosley 1987 36 1960 1980 Aid had no significant effect on economic growth The reason seemed to be fungibility aid likely released other resources for unproductive uses Boone 1996 37 38 1971 1990 Aid had no clear effect on rates of infant mortality and primary education Burnside and Dollar 1997 39 2000 40 1970 1993 Aid had a positive impact on growth in developing countries with good policies But the overall effect of aid was unclear because donors did not especially target such countries Svensson 1999 41 1980s 1990s Aid had a positive impact on growth in more democratic countries But aid on average was not channeled to more democratic countries Arvin and Borillas 2002 42 1975 1998 Aid had no clear effect on GNP per capita Kosack 2003 43 1974 1985 Aid had no clear effect on average but improved the quality of life when combined with democracy Dunning 2004 44 1975 1997 In the first few years after the Cold War foreign aid produced a small positive effect on democracy in sub Saharan African countries unlike in the previous 15 years Easterly et al 2004 45 1970 1997 The finding of Burnside and Dollar 2000 see above is not robust to different definitions of aid and good policy Mosley et al 2004 46 1980 2000 Aid increased pro poor public spending in low income countries Rajan and Subramanian 2005 47 1960 2000 There was on average no robust positive relationship between aid and growth Yontcheva and Masud 2005 48 1990 2001 Aid by NGOs co financed by the European Commission reduced infant mortality but bilateral aid generally did not Calderon et al 2006 49 50 1971 2002 Aid had no clear effect on poverty inequality economic growth or democratic institutions Mosley and Suleiman 2007 51 1980 2002 Aid most effectively reduced poverty when it supported public expenditures on agriculture education and infrastructure Bahmani Oskooee and Oyolola 2009 52 1981 2002 Aid was on average effective in reducing poverty Clemens et al 2011 53 1970 2000 Aid had a modest positive effect on economic growth 54 Alvi and Senbeta 2012 55 1981 2004 Aid especially multilateral aid significantly reduced poverty Kaya et al 2013 56 1980 2003 Aid to agriculture significantly reduced poverty Hirano and Otsubo 2014 57 1990s 2000s Social aid directly benefitted the poorest in society while economic aid increased the income of the poor through growth Nunn and Qian 2014 58 1971 2006 U S food aid increased the incidence and duration of civil conflicts but had no robust effect on inter state conflicts or the onset of civil conflicts 59 Arndt et al 2015 60 1970 2007 Aid moderately stimulated growth promoted structural change improved social indicators and reduced poverty Petrikova 2015 1994 2011 Aid had a small positive effect on food securityJanjua et al 2018 61 1995 2009 Project aid had a significant effect on economic growth Programme aid had a significant effect on social development Abellan and Alonso 2022 62 1990 2015 Aid had a positive effect on access to safe drinking water this effect being especially important when consistent long term investments are put into place Analyses of factors limiting aid effectiveness edit Aid fragmentation edit Aid flows significantly increased in the first decade of the 21st century but at the same time aid has become increasingly fragmented There was an explosion in the number of donors and while the number of projects multiplied their average size dropped Small projects being often limited in size scope and duration they resulted in little lasting benefit beyond the immediate effect 63 With more players aid became less predictable less transparent and more volatile 64 Fragmentation means an increase in costs for recipient countries as government offices are forced to divert administrative resources to cope with requests and meetings with donors 65 Decades of development have shown that if countries are to become less dependent on aid they must follow a bottom up approach where they determine their own priorities and rely on their own systems to deliver that aid 66 Volatility unpredictability of aid edit Information at the donors as well at the recipients level is often poor incomplete and difficult to compare with other data and beneficiaries feedback and formal project evaluations are rare Aid is predictable when partner countries can be confident about the amount and the timing of aid disbursement Not being predictable has a cost one study assessed the deadweight loss associated with volatility at an average of 10 to 20 of a developing country s programmable aid from the European Union in recent years 67 Reducing the accountability of governments edit Revenue generation is one of the essential pillars for developing state capacity Effective taxation methods allow a state to provide public goods and services from ensuring justice to providing education 68 Taxation simultaneously serves as a government accountability mechanism building state citizen relationships as citizens can now expect such service provisions upon their consent to taxation For developing and fragile states that lack such revenue capabilities while aid can be a seemingly necessary alternative it has the potential to undermine institutional development States that rely on higher percentages of aid for government revenue are less accountable to their citizens by avoiding the state citizen relationships that taxation builds and face fewer incentives to develop public institutions 69 The limited government capacity resulting from subpar institutional presence and effectiveness leads to ubiquitous corruption of state officials large gaps between the law and actual practice in business regulation workers who do not even show up doctors that do not doctor teachers who do not teach 70 In the view of James Shikwati aid in Africa sustains political elites who implement a colonial or neo colonial agenda of subsidy and distortion of markets which holds African countries back 71 The tying of aid edit Tied aid is defined as project aid contracted by source to private firms in the donor country It refers to aid tied to goods and services supplied exclusively by donor country businesses or agencies Tied aid increases the cost of assistance and has the tendency of making donors to focus more on the commercial advancement of their countries than what developing countries need There are many ways aid can be designed to pursue the commercial objectives of donors One of such pervasive means is by insisting on donor country products Others have argued that tying aid to donor country products is common sense it is a strategic use of aid to promote donor country s business or exports It is further argued that tied aid if well designed and effectively managed would not necessarily compromise the quality as well as the effectiveness of aid 72 However this argument would hold particularly for programme aid where aid is tied to a specific projects or policies and where there is little or no commercial interest It must be emphasized however that commercial interest and aid effectiveness are two different things and it would be difficult to pursue commercial interest without compromising aid effectiveness Thus the idea of maximizing development should be separated from the notion of pursuing commercial interest Tied aid improves donors export performance creates business for local companies and jobs It also helps to expose firms which have not had any international experience on the global market to do so 73 Fungibility of aid edit Aid is often fungible 74 meaning that aided activities which appear to be successful may be filling a role that would have been covered anyway by local resources the effect of the aid is thus only to release those local resources for other purposes which may not be so desirable Ways to improve aid effectiveness editTargeting aid more precisely edit Using the private sector edit According to Laurie Garrett for health aid to be maximized efficiently and most optimally donations need to be directed to areas such as local industries franchises or profit centers in developing countries By doing so these actions can sustain health related spending and result in growth in the long run 75 Paul Collier in The Bottom Billion suggests a model he calls Independent Service Authorities These are organizations independent from the government that co opt civil society to manage aid and public money and incorporate the scrutiny of public opinion and NGOs to determine how to maximize output from the expenditure of this money 76 William Easterly tells a story in The White Man s Burden where he says that helping the approximate three million people infected with Malaria each year may not be as simple as sending nets over to Africa A lot of the time these nets are diverted to the black market and used for more entrepreneurial pursuits for example making fishing nets out of them Easterly does go on to report however that when schemes are introduced where mosquito nets are available on the market for an affordable price the usage of them increases drastically 77 He advocates the use of localized tailored schemes like this to help the world s poor and discounts ambitious overarching schemes that claim to be a complete panacea for poverty Sensitivity to recipient country institutions edit Since the effectiveness of aid usually depends on the good functioning of institutions in the recipient country and since potential recipients are very varied in this respect Charles Kenny 2006 argues that aid strategies must be tailored to the state of institutions in each case Where institutions are strong it is appropriate to provide programmatic aid Where they are weak there may be a role for aid in analysis consensus building and technical assistance to improve them and meanwhile other insulated projects might go ahead if they do not harm the prospects for developing sound governmental institutions 78 Reform of state institutions edit Noted Peruvian economist Hernando de Soto in his book The Mystery of Capital 79 also firmly asserts that Africa already has the resource wealth it needs to pull itself out of poverty it just lacks the institutions that allow for the creation of wealth from these riches Poor documentation of assets and the lack of property rights means that people cannot collateralize their assets for example if a farmer inhabits a tract of land that has been in his family for generations in his view for all intents and purposes he owns the land However he does not possess a title deed to the land that clearly demarcates the borders of his ownership this means that he cannot put up this land as collateral to secure a loan This simplistic example can help to explain why investment and therefore growth is inhibited the spirit of entrepreneurship may be present the tools to engage in it however are not The answer therefore seems simple create such institutions that provide transparent documentation of assets and allow them to be converted to liquidity with ease In practice however this may not be so simple and would involve major overhauls in the bureaucratic fabric of a state How aid can help to foster better institutions then becomes the main question Best practices according to the High Level Forums on Aid Effectiveness edit The Paris Declaration and other results of the High Level Forums on Aid Effectiveness 2003 2011 embodied a broad consensus on what needed to be done to produce better development results 80 Its principles lay open the possible ways to undertake which can be interpreted also as the major objectives of good aid fostering recipient countries ownership of development policies and strategies maximizing donors coordination and harmonization improving aid transparency and mutual accountability of donors and recipients just to name a few 81 The forums were supported by work done by the OECD which had explored through peer reviews and other work by the Development Assistance Committee DAC the reasons why aid has and has not worked This has resulted in a body of best practices and principles that can be applied globally to make aid work better Improving aid transparency and mutual accountability of donors and recipients edit Some believe that the way to improvement is through better monitoring and evaluation increased transparency accountability and learning For instance Stefan Schmitz a former senior aid official in the German government and the OECD has argued that reporting duties results orientated action and ongoing performance assessments are essential for the sake of aid effectiveness but political will must be already there for this to happen 82 The Accra Agenda for Action states that transparency and accountability are essential elements for development results as well as drivers of progress 83 Mutual accountability and transparency is one of the five partnership commitments of the Paris Declaration 84 Through transparency donors and recipients can be held accountable for what they spend and aid can be made more effective by knowing the three Ws of transparency Who gives money to which recipient What project is being funded and for what purpose and Where 85 Transparency offers a valuable answer to insecurity making aid predictable and reliable Transparency has been shown to improve service delivery and to reduce opportunities for diversion and therefore corruption 86 Transparency can be defined as a basic expression of mutual accountability 87 Mutual accountability can only work if there is a global culture of transparency that demands provision of information through a set of rules and behavioral norms which are difficult to enforce in the case of official development cooperation In particular for emerging economy donors and private development assistance these norms are only at a nascent stage Kharas 88 suggest to adopt the regulation through information approach 89 which has been developed and has proven its effectiveness in the case of the European integration In fact at the international level when the enforcement of mandatory rules is difficult the solution could be to provide and make available transparent relevant accurate and reliable information which can be used to reward or sanction individual aid agencies according to their performances This means establishing a strong culture of accountability within aid which rewards aid successes but penalizes failures To achieve this literature on the topic 90 suggest that donors should agree on adopting a standardized format for providing information on volume allocation and results such as the International Aid Transparency Initiative IATI or other similar standards and commit to improve recipient countries databases with technical financial and informational support The format should be easily downloadable and with sufficient disaggregation to enable comparison with other data Making aid data public and comparable among donors would be likely to encourage a process of positive emulation towards a better usage of public funds After all official development assistance ODA is a voluntary transfer that depends on the support of donor country taxpayers Donors should therefore consider improving the transparency and traceability of aid funds also as a way of increasing engagement and support toward aid inside their own country Moreover a generalized adoption of IATI would ensure the publication of aid information in a timely way the compatibility with developing countries budgets and the reliability of future projections which would have a strong and positive effect on the predictability of aid 91 Finally to improve accountability while building evaluation capabilities in aid recipient countries and systematically collecting beneficiaries feedback different mechanisms to evaluate and monitor transparency should be considered such as independent third party reviews peer reviews or mutual reviews 92 See also editAid for Trade Development Assistance Committee Development Assistance Database Eurodad G8 5 Humanitarian Response Index International Aid Transparency Initiative International Health Partnership Monterrey ConsensusReferences edit Kenny Charles September 2006 What is effective aid How would donors allocate it PDF Report World Bank p 2 3 Retrieved 2021 03 05 Mahbub ul Haq et al 1990 Human Development Report 1990 PDF UNDP Retrieved 2021 03 01 a b Barder Owen 2009 What Is Poverty Reduction PDF Centre for Global Development Archived PDF from the original on 2020 12 23 Official Development Assistance ODA OECD Archived from the original on 2019 04 22 Retrieved 2021 03 01 Kenny Charles 2006 What Is Effective Aid How Would Donors Allocate It PDF The World Bank Archived PDF from the original on 2021 11 01 Retrieved 2021 03 01 Mitchell Ian McKee Caitlin 15 November 2018 How Do You Measure Aid Quality and Who Ranks Highest Center for Global Development Archived from the original on 2019 05 10 Retrieved 2021 03 01 Duncan G A 1950 Marshall Aid Journal of the Statistical and Social Inquiry Society of Ireland 18 293 Haviland H Field 1958 Foreign Aid and the Policy Process 1957 American Political Science Review 52 3 689 724 doi 10 2307 1951900 ISSN 1537 5943 JSTOR 1951900 S2CID 144564474 US Senate Special Committee 1957 Report of the special committee to study the foreign aid program United States Government Printing Office pp 7 8 US Senate Special Committee 1957 Report of the special committee to study the foreign aid program United States Government Printing Office pp 8 10 a b Morgner Aurelius 1967 The American Foreign Aid Program Costs Accomplishments Alternatives The Review of Politics 29 1 72 73 doi 10 1017 S0034670500023731 ISSN 0034 6705 JSTOR 1405813 S2CID 145492668 Millikan Max F 1957 A proposal Key to an effective foreign policy New York Harper amp Brothers Rostow W W 1962 The Stages of Economic Growth Cambridge University Press p 143 a b Chenery Hollis B Strout Alan M 1966 Foreign Assistance and Economic Development The American Economic Review 56 4 679 733 ISSN 0002 8282 JSTOR 1813524 Riddell Roger 1987 Foreign aid reconsidered Baltimore Johns Hopkins University Press pp 92 95 ISBN 0 8018 3546 1 OCLC 15630613 Lewis D 2010 Nongovernmental Organizations Definition and History PDF In Anheier H K Toepler S eds International Encyclopedia of Civil Society Springer New York NY Dunning Thad Conditioning the Effects of Aid Cold War Politics Donor Credibility and Democracy in Africa International Organization 58 02 2004 International Conference on Financing for Development Un org Retrieved 2012 12 26 uhc2030 History UHC2030 Archived from the original on 2017 10 01 Retrieved 2021 02 27 IHP Strategic Directions 2016 17 PDF uhc2030 Retrieved 2021 02 27 Omaka Arua Oko 1 June 2016 Humanitarian Action The Joint Church Aid and Health Care Intervention in the Nigeria Biafra War 1967 1970 Canadian Journal of History 49 3 423 227 doi 10 3138 cjh 49 3 423 Waal Alexander De 1991 Evil Days Thirty Years of War and Famine in Ethiopia Human Rights Watch p 2 ISBN 9781564320384 Bauer P T 1976 Dissent on development Cambridge Mass Harvard University Press ISBN 0 674 21282 7 OCLC 2666082 Bauer P T 1984 Reality and rhetoric studies in the economics of development Cambridge Mass Harvard University Press ISBN 0 674 74946 4 OCLC 9894295 Bauer P T 1984 Reality and rhetoric studies in the economics of development Cambridge Mass Harvard University Press pp 27 28 46 ISBN 0 674 74946 4 OCLC 9894295 Moyo Dambisa 2009 Aid Why Aid Is Not Working and How There Is a Better Way for Africa Douglas amp Mcintyre ISBN 978 1 55365 542 8 Moyo Dambisa 2009 Dead Aid Why Aid Is Not Working and How There Is a Better Way for Africa Douglas amp Mcintyre p 124 Mahembe Edmore Odhiambo Nicholas M 2019 01 01 Read Robert ed Foreign aid and poverty reduction A review of international literature Cogent Social Sciences 5 1 1625741 doi 10 1080 23311886 2019 1625741 ISSN 2331 1886 Barder Owen 2009 04 21 What is Poverty Reduction CGD Working Papers Retrieved 2010 06 02 Roodman David 2007 The Anarchy of Numbers Aid Development and Cross Country Empirics The World Bank Economic Review 21 2 255 277 doi 10 1093 wber lhm004 hdl 10 1093 wber lhm004 S2CID 14359188 a b Clemens MA et al 2011 Counting Chickens when they Hatch Timing and the Effects of Aid on Growth The Economic Journal 122 561 590 617 doi 10 1111 j 1468 0297 2011 02482 x a b Petrikova Ivica 2015 Aid for food security does it work PDF International Journal of Development Issues 14 41 59 doi 10 1108 IJDI 07 2014 0058 Mosley Paul 1987 Foreign Aid Its Defense and Reform University Press of Kentucky ISBN 978 0 8131 1608 2 Retrieved December 7 2009 Paul Mosley Faust Jorg 2009 Reliable evidence of impact Development and Cooperation 36 1 14 17 Archived from the original on 2010 02 27 Bibliographic reference to be given in a note Mosley Paul 1987 Foreign aid its defense and reform Lexington Ky University Press of Kentucky ISBN 0 8131 1608 2 OCLC 14240724 Boone Peter 1995 Politics and the effectiveness of foreign aid PDF Report National Bureau of Economic Research Retrieved 2021 02 19 A similar version was published as Boone Peter 1996 Politics and the effectiveness of foreign aid PDF European Economic Review 40 2 289 329 doi 10 1016 0014 2921 95 00127 1 S2CID 154155908 via Science Direct Burnside Craig Dollar David 1997 Aid policies and growth PDF Report World Bank Retrieved 2021 02 20 Burnside Craig Dollar David September 2000 Aid Policies and Growth American Economic Review 90 4 847 868 doi 10 1257 aer 90 4 847 ISSN 0002 8282 S2CID 14261087 Svensson J 1999 Aid Growth and Democracy Economics amp Politics 11 3 275 297 doi 10 1111 1468 0343 00062 ISSN 1468 0343 Arvin B Mak Barillas Francisco 2002 11 01 Foreign aid poverty reduction and democracy Applied Economics 34 17 2151 2156 doi 10 1080 00036840210136718 ISSN 0003 6846 S2CID 154546476 Kosack Stephen 2003 01 01 Effective Aid How Democracy Allows Development Aid to Improve the Quality of Life World Development 31 1 1 22 doi 10 1016 S0305 750X 02 00177 8 ISSN 0305 750X Dunning Thad 2004 Conditioning the Effects of Aid Cold War Politics Donor Credibility and Democracy in Africa International Organization 58 2 409 423 doi 10 1017 S0020818304582073 ISSN 1531 5088 S2CID 154368924 Easterly William Levine Ross Roodman David 2004 05 01 Aid Policies and Growth Comment American Economic Review 94 3 774 780 doi 10 1257 0002828041464560 ISSN 0002 8282 Mosley Paul Hudson John Verschoor Arjan 2004 06 01 Aid Poverty Reduction and the New Conditionality The Economic Journal 114 496 F217 F243 doi 10 1111 j 1468 0297 2004 00220 x ISSN 0013 0133 S2CID 55919902 Rajan Raghuram G Subramanian Arvind 2005 Aid and growth What does the cross country evidence really show PDF Report National Bureau of Economic Research Retrieved 2021 02 23 Yontcheva Boriana Masud Nadia 2005 Does Foreign Aid Reduce Poverty Empirical Evidence from Nongovernmental and Bilateral Aid Report IMF Retrieved 2021 02 19 Calderon Mark Chong Alberto Gradstein 2006 Foreign aid income inequality and poverty PDF Report Inter American Development Bank Retrieved 2021 02 20 A similar version was published as Chong Alberto Gradstein Mark Calderon Cecilia 2009 07 01 Can foreign aid reduce income inequality and poverty Public Choice 140 1 59 84 doi 10 1007 s11127 009 9412 4 ISSN 1573 7101 S2CID 154071767 Mosley Paul Suleiman Abrar 2007 Aid Agriculture and Poverty in Developing Countries Review of Development Economics 11 1 139 158 doi 10 1111 j 1467 9361 2006 00354 x ISSN 1467 9361 S2CID 154905396 Bahmani Oskooee Mohsen Oyolola Maharouf 2009 01 01 Poverty reduction and aid cross country evidence International Journal of Sociology and Social Policy 29 5 6 264 273 doi 10 1108 01443330910965796 ISSN 0144 333X Clemens Michael A Radelet Steven Bhavnani Rikhil R Bazzi Samuel 2012 06 01 Counting Chickens when they Hatch Timing and the Effects of Aid on Growth The Economic Journal 122 561 590 617 doi 10 1111 j 1468 0297 2011 02482 x ISSN 0013 0133 The study re analyzed data from Boone 1996 Burnside and Dollar 2000 and Rajan and Subramanian 2008 treating time lags differently Alvi Eskander Senbeta Aberra 2012 Does Foreign Aid Reduce Poverty Journal of International Development 24 8 955 976 doi 10 1002 jid 1790 ISSN 1099 1328 Kaya Ozgur Kaya Ilker Gunter Lewell 2013 Foreign Aid and the Quest for Poverty Reduction Is Aid to Agriculture Effective Journal of Agricultural Economics 64 3 583 596 doi 10 1111 1477 9552 12023 ISSN 1477 9552 Hirano Yumeka Otsubo Shigero 2014 Aid Is Good for the Poor Report World Bank Retrieved 2021 02 20 Nunn Nathan Qian Nancy 2014 06 01 US Food Aid and Civil Conflict American Economic Review 104 6 1630 1666 doi 10 1257 aer 104 6 1630 ISSN 0002 8282 S2CID 12935268 Nunn and Qian acknowledged that such aid might also have other possibly beneficial effects Arndt Channing Jones Sam Tarp Finn 2015 05 01 Assessing Foreign Aid s Long Run Contribution to Growth and Development World Development 69 6 18 doi 10 1016 j worlddev 2013 12 016 ISSN 0305 750X Janjua Pervez Zamurrad Muhammad Malik Usman Muhammad 2018 06 01 Impact of Project and Programme Aid on Economic Growth A Cross Country Analysis The Pakistan Development Review 57 2 145 174 doi 10 30541 v57i2pp 145 174 ISSN 0030 9729 Abellan Javier Alonso Jose Antonio 2022 Promoting global access to water and sanitation A supply and demand perspective Water Resources and Economics 38 100194 doi 10 1016 j wre 2022 100194 S2CID 246261266 Fengler M G and Kharas H Delivering Aid Differently Lesson from the Field Brookings Institution Washington D C 2010 Kharas H Makino K Jung W Catalizing Development Brookings Institution Press Washington D C 2011 As an example in 2005 government authorities in Vietnam received 791 missions from donors which means more than two a day including weekends and holidays See for example OECD DAC The Challenge of Capacity Development Working Towards Good Practice Paris 2006 Deutscher E and Fyson S Improving the Effectiveness of Aid Finance and Development Vol 25 n 3 The International Monetary Fund September 2008 Kharas H Measuring the Cost of Aid Volatility Wolfensohn Centre for Development Working Parper 3 Brookings Institution Washington D C 2008 Brautigam Deborah 2002 Building Leviathan Revenue State Capacity and Governance PDF IDS Bulletin 33 3 1 17 doi 10 1111 j 1759 5436 2002 tb00034 x An Aid Institutions Paradox A Review Essay on Aid Dependency and State Building in Sub Saharan Africa Working Paper 74 Center For Global Development Retrieved 2017 05 17 Pritchett Lant Woolcock Michael Andrews Matt 2013 01 01 Looking Like a State Techniques of Persistent Failure in State Capability for Implementation PDF The Journal of Development Studies 49 1 1 18 doi 10 1080 00220388 2012 709614 ISSN 0022 0388 S2CID 14363040 Shikwati James 2006 The Future of Africa in the World Inter Region Economic Network 6 Archived from the original on 2013 06 17 Aryeetey 1995 Sowa 1997 Tied Aid and Multi Donor Budgetary Support Journal of International Development Vol 17 Issue 8 Kenny Charles September 2006 What is effective aid How would donors allocate it PDF Report World Bank p 9 Retrieved 2021 03 05 Garrett Laurie 2007 The Challenge of Global Health Foreign Affairs 86 1 14 38 Collier Paul 2007 The Bottom Billion Why the Poorest Countries Are failing and What Can Be Done about It Oxford Easterly William 2006 The White Man s Burden Why the West s Efforts to Aid the Rest Have Done so Much Ill and so Little Good New york Penguin Press Kenny Charles September 2006 What is effective aid How would donors allocate it PDF Report World Bank Retrieved 2021 03 05 Soto Hernando de 2003 The mystery of capital why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else 1 paperback ed New York BasicBooks ISBN 978 0 465 01615 0 Effective development co operation OECD www oecd org Retrieved 2019 07 04 See OECD The Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness March 2 2005 Comprehensive thinking Archived from the original on 2010 07 06 Retrieved 2010 03 11 OECD The Accra Agenda For Action 3rd High Level Forum on Aid Effectiveness September 4 2008 OECD The Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness March 2 2005 Kharas H Transparency Changing the Accountability Engagement and Effectiveness of Aid in Kharas H Makino K Jung W Catalyzing Development Brookings Institution Press Washington D C 2011 Bjorkman M Svensson J Power to the People Evidence from a Randomized Field Experience on Community Based Monitoring in Uganda Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 no 2 735 69 2009 Mary Robinson s definition in the OECD Survey on Monitoring The Paris Declaration 2008 See Kharas H Transparency Changing the Accountability Engagement and Effectiveness of Aid in Kharas H Makino K Jung W Catalyzing Development Brookings Institution Press Washington D C 2011 Majone G The new European Agencies regulation by information Journal of European Public Policy 4 no 2 262 75 1997 See for example Pranay S and Hubbard M A Future for Aid Data Research towards a South South Cooperation Data Categorization to complement on going IATI Categorizations ongoing research DFID Future of Aid and Beyond Research Competition 2010 11 2011 Kharas H Makino K Jung W Catalyzing Development Brookings Institution Press Washington D C 2011 See Droop J Isenman P and Mlalazi B Mutual accountability in Aid Effectiveness International Level Mechanisms Briefing Note n 3 Oxford Policy Management 2008 External links editEurodad The European Network on Debt and Development Special Report on Aid Harmonization Addicted to Aid documentary by Sorious Samura Center for Global Development Aid Effectiveness The International Health Partnership IHP A group of partners committed to putting international principles for effective aid and development cooperation into practice in the health sector Millions Saved Archived 2008 10 11 at the Wayback Machine A compilation of case studies of effective foreign assistance by the Center for Global Development Aidharmonisation org Aideffectiveness org PubHealth org Ugandan effort to develop tools for harmonization Reading list on the future of development assistance PSD Blog aid effectiveness Boston Review Forum Making Aid Work Initial article arguing for funding of projects confirmed as effective in randomized trials followed by replies The Crisis in African Agriculture A more effective use for EC aid A Practical Action and Pelum African Voices Report European Network on Debt and Development reports news and links on aid effectiveness Euforic Archived 2007 09 28 at the Wayback Machine pages on aid evaluation and effectiveness FRIDE From Paris to Accra building the global governance of aid Zunia Aid Effectiveness Page articles reports blogs and jobs related to aid effectiveness Three Cs net Archived 2022 10 06 at the Wayback Machine Six joint evaluations to explore and assess the role played by the Maastricht Treaty precepts of coordination complementarity and coherence 3Cs in the EU s development co operation policies and operations The OECD DAC s site on the Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness Governance and Social Development Resource Centre s Topic Guide Aid instruments and aid effectiveness Archived 2008 03 15 at the Wayback Machine ODI Briefing Paper Aid effectiveness after Accra permanent dead link EADI Online Dossier on Aid Effectiveness Archived 2012 03 10 at the Wayback Machine Masterclass on Aid Effectiveness Open Forum for CSO Development Effectiveness CSOs on the road from Accra to Busan Strengthening Civil Society s Roles and Voice Reflections on CSO Engagement with the Accra Third High Level Forum on Aid Effectiveness Aid for Trade in Asia and the Pacific 12 Things to Know Asian Development Bank Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Aid effectiveness amp oldid 1188058087, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.