fbpx
Wikipedia

Wickard v. Filburn

Wickard v. Filburn, 317 U.S. 111 (1942), is a United States Supreme Court decision that dramatically increased the regulatory power of the federal government. It remains as one of the most important and far-reaching cases concerning the New Deal, and it set a precedent for an expansive reading of the U.S. Constitution's Commerce Clause for decades to come. The goal of the legal challenge was to end the entire federal crop support program by declaring it unconstitutional.[1]

Wickard v. Filburn
Argued May 4, 1942
Reargued October 12, 1942
Decided November 9, 1942
Full case nameClaude R. Wickard, Secretary of Agriculture, et al. v. Roscoe C. Filburn
Citations317 U.S. 111 (more)
63 S. Ct. 82; 87 L. Ed. 122; 1942 U.S. LEXIS 1046
Case history
PriorInjunction granted to plaintiff, Filburn v. Helke, 43 F. Supp. 1017 (S.D. Ohio 1942); probable jurisdiction noted, 62 S. Ct. 919 (1942).
Holding
Production quotas under the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938 were constitutionally applied to agricultural production that was consumed purely intrastate because its effect upon interstate commerce placed it within the power of Congress to regulate under the Commerce Clause.
Court membership
Chief Justice
Harlan F. Stone
Associate Justices
Owen Roberts · Hugo Black
Stanley F. Reed · Felix Frankfurter
William O. Douglas · Frank Murphy
Robert H. Jackson
Case opinion
MajorityJackson, joined by unanimous
Laws applied
U.S. Const. amends. I, V; 7 U.S.C. § 1281, et. seq. (1941) (Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938)

An Ohio farmer, Roscoe Filburn, was growing wheat to feed animals on his own farm. The U.S. government had established limits on wheat production, based on the acreage owned by a farmer, to stabilize wheat prices and supplies. Filburn grew more than was permitted and so was ordered to pay a penalty. In response, he said that because his wheat was not sold, it could not be regulated as commerce, let alone "interstate" commerce (described in the Constitution as "Commerce ... among the several states"). The Supreme Court disagreed: "Whether the subject of the regulation in question was 'production', 'consumption', or 'marketing' is, therefore, not material for purposes of deciding the question of federal power before us. ... But even if appellee's activity be local and though it may not be regarded as commerce, it may still, whatever its nature, be reached by Congress if it exerts a substantial economic effect on interstate commerce and this irrespective of whether such effect is what might at some earlier time have been defined as 'direct' or 'indirect'."[2]

The Supreme Court interpreted the Constitution's Commerce Clause, in Article I, Section 8, of the Constitution, which permits the U.S. Congress "to regulate Commerce with foreign Nations, and among the several States, and with the Indian Tribes". The Court decided that Filburn's wheat-growing activities reduced the amount of wheat he would buy for animal feed on the open market, which is traded nationally, is thus interstate, and is therefore within the scope of the Commerce Clause. Although Filburn's relatively small amount of production of more wheat than he was allotted would not affect interstate commerce itself, the cumulative actions of thousands of other farmers like Filburn would become substantial. Therefore the Court decided that the federal government could regulate Filburn's production.[3]

Background edit

The Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938 limited the area that farmers could devote to wheat production. Its stated purpose was to stabilize the price of wheat in the national market by controlling the amount of wheat produced. It was motivated by a belief by Congress that great international fluctuations in the supply and the demand for wheat were leading to wide swings in the price of wheat, which were deemed to be harmful to the U.S. agricultural economy.

The Supreme Court's decision states that the parties had stipulated as to the economic conditions leading to passage of the legislation:

The parties have stipulated a summary of the economics of the wheat industry. ... The wheat industry has been a problem industry for some years. Largely as a result of increased foreign production and import restrictions, annual exports of wheat and flour from the United States during the ten-year period ending in 1940 averaged less than 10 percent of total production, while, during the 1920s, they averaged more than 25 percent. The decline in the export trade has left a large surplus in production which, in connection with an abnormally large supply of wheat and other grains in recent years, caused congestion in a number of markets; tied up railroad cars, and caused elevators in some instances to turn away grains, and railroads to institute embargoes to prevent further congestion. Many countries, both importing and exporting, have sought to modify the impact of the world market conditions on their own economy. Importing countries have taken measures to stimulate production and self-sufficiency. The four large exporting countries of Argentina, Australia, Canada, and the United States have all undertaken various programs for the relief of growers. Such measures have been designed, in part at least, to protect the domestic price received by producers. Such plans have generally evolved towards control by the central government. In the absence of regulation, the price of wheat in the United States would be much affected by world conditions. During 1941, producers who cooperated with the Agricultural Adjustment program received an average price on the farm of about $1.16 a bushel, as compared with the world market price of 40 cents a bushel.

Roscoe Filburn was a farmer in what is now suburban Dayton, Ohio.[4] He admitted producing wheat in excess of the amount permitted. He maintained, however, that the excess wheat was produced for his private consumption on his own farm. Since it never entered commerce at all, much less interstate commerce, he argued that it was not a proper subject of federal regulation under the Commerce Clause.

In July 1940, pursuant to the Agricultural Adjustment Act (AAA) of 1938, Filburn's 1941 allotment was established at 11.1 acres (4.5 ha) and a normal yield of 20.1 bushels of wheat per acre (1.4 metric tons per hectare). Filburn was given notice of the allotment in July 1940, before the fall planting of his 1941 crop of wheat, and again in July 1941, before it was harvested. Despite the notices, Filburn planted 23 acres (9.3 ha) and harvested 239 more bushels (6,500 kg) than was allowed from his 11.9 acres (4.8 ha) of excess area.[3][5]

The Federal District Court ruled in favor of Filburn. The Act required an affirmative vote of farmers by plebiscite to implement the quota. Much of the District Court decision related to the way in which the U.S. Secretary of Agriculture had campaigned for passage: the District Court had held that the Secretary's comments were improper. The government then appealed to the Supreme Court, which called the District Court's holding (against the campaign methods that led to passage of the quota by farmers) a "manifest error". The Court then went on to uphold the Act under the Interstate Commerce Clause.

By the time that the case reached the high court, eight out of the nine justices had been appointed by President Franklin Roosevelt, the architect of the New Deal legislation. In addition, the case was heard during wartime, shortly after the attack on Pearl Harbor galvanized the United States to enter the Second World War.[6][7] The decision supported the President by holding that the Constitution allowed the federal government to regulate economic activity that was only indirectly related to interstate commerce.

Decision edit

The Act's intended rationale was to stabilize the price of wheat on the national market. The federal government has the power to regulate interstate commerce by the Commerce Clause of the Constitution. In this decision, the Court unanimously reasoned that the power to regulate the price at which commerce occurs was inherent in the power to regulate commerce.

Filburn argued that since the excess wheat that he produced was intended solely for home consumption, his wheat production could not be regulated through the Interstate Commerce Clause. The Supreme Court rejected the argument and reasoned that if Filburn had not produced his own wheat, he would have bought wheat on the open market.

That effect on interstate commerce, the Court reasoned, may not be substantial from the actions of Filburn alone, but the cumulative actions of thousands of other farmers just like Filburn would certainly make the effect become substantial.

Therefore, Congress could regulate wholly intrastate, non-commercial activity if such activity, viewed in the aggregate, would have a substantial effect on interstate commerce, even if the individual effects are trivial.

Some of the parties' argument had focused on prior decisions, especially those relating to the Dormant Commerce Clause, in which the Court had tried to focus on whether a commercial activity was local or not. Justice Robert H. Jackson's decision rejected that approach as too formulaic:

The Government's concern lest the Act be held to be a regulation of production or consumption rather than of marketing is attributable to a few dicta and decisions of this Court which might be understood to lay it down that activities such as "production", "manufacturing", and "mining" are strictly "local" and, except in special circumstances which are not present here, cannot be regulated under the commerce power because their effects upon interstate commerce are, as matter of law, only "indirect". Even today, when this power has been held to have great latitude, there is no decision of this Court that such activities may be regulated where no part of the product is intended for interstate commerce or intermingled with the subjects thereof. We believe that a review of the course of decision under the Commerce Clause will make plain, however, that questions of the power of Congress are not to be decided by reference to any formula which would give controlling force to nomenclature such as "production" and "indirect" and foreclose consideration of the actual effects of the activity in question upon interstate commerce.[8]

The issue was not how one characterized the activity as local. Rather, it was whether the activity "exerts a substantial economic effect on interstate commerce":

Whether the subject of the regulation in question was "production", "consumption", or "marketing" is, therefore, not material for purposes of deciding the question of federal power before us. That an activity is of local character may help in a doubtful case to determine whether Congress intended to reach it. ... But even if appellee's activity be local and though it may not be regarded as commerce, it may still, whatever its nature, be reached by Congress if it exerts a substantial economic effect on interstate commerce and this irrespective of whether such effect is what might at some earlier time have been defined as "direct" or "indirect".[9]

The regulation of local production of wheat was rationally related to Congress's goal: to stabilize prices by limiting the total supply of wheat produced and consumed. It was clear, the Court held,

that a factor of such volume and variability as home-consumed wheat would have a substantial influence on price and market conditions. ... Home-grown wheat in this sense competes with wheat in commerce. The stimulation of commerce is a use of the regulatory function quite as definitely as prohibitions or restrictions thereon. This record leaves us in no doubt that Congress may properly have considered that wheat consumed on the farm where grown, if wholly outside the scheme of regulation, would have a substantial effect in defeating and obstructing its purpose to stimulate trade therein at increased prices.[10]

Aftermath edit

Wickard marked the beginning of the Supreme Court's total deference to the claims of the U.S. Congress to Commerce Clause powers until the 1990s. The Court's own decision, however, emphasizes the role of the democratic electoral process in confining the abuse of the power of Congress: "At the beginning Chief Justice Marshall described the Federal commerce power with a breadth never yet exceeded. He made emphatic the embracing and penetrating nature of this power by warning that effective restraints on its exercise must proceed from political rather than from judicial processes."

Critics have noted that under Wickard there is "no distinction between 'interstate' and 'intrastate' commerce to place any limits on Congress' authority under the Commerce Clause",[11][12] and that it allows regulation of activity that is generally not considered commerce.[13][14]

According to Earl M. Maltz, Wickard and other New Deal decisions gave Congress "the authority to regulate private economic activity in a manner near limitless in its purview."[15]

That remained the case until United States v. Lopez (1995), which was the first decision in six decades to invalidate a federal statute on the grounds that it exceeded the power of the Congress under the Commerce Clause. The opinion described Wickard as "perhaps the most far reaching example of Commerce Clause authority over intrastate commerce" and judged that it "greatly expanded the authority of Congress beyond what is defined in the Constitution under that Clause."

In Lopez, the Court held that while Congress had broad lawmaking authority under the Commerce Clause, the power was limited and did not extend so far from "commerce" as to authorize the regulation of the carrying of handguns, especially when there was no evidence that carrying them affected the economy on a massive scale. (In a later case, United States v. Morrison, the Court ruled in 2000 that Congress could not make such laws even when there was evidence of aggregate effect.)

The Supreme Court has since relied heavily on Wickard in upholding the power of the federal government to prosecute individuals who grow their own medicinal marijuana pursuant to state law. The Supreme Court would hold in Gonzales v. Raich (2005) that like with the home-grown wheat at issue in Wickard, home-grown marijuana is a legitimate subject of federal regulation because it competes with marijuana that moves in interstate commerce:

Wickard thus establishes that Congress can regulate purely intrastate activity that is not itself "commercial", in that it is not produced for sale, if it concludes that failure to regulate that class of activity would undercut the regulation of the interstate market in that commodity.

In 2012, Wickard was central to arguments in National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius and Florida v. United States Department of Health and Human Services on the constitutionality of the individual mandate of the Affordable Care Act, with both supporters and opponents of the mandate claiming that Wickard supported their positions.[16]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Jonathan R.T. Hughes (2014). The Governmental Habit Redux: Economic Controls from Colonial Times to the Present. Princeton University Press. p. 168.
  2. ^ Wickard v. Filburn, 317 U.S. 111, 125 (1942).
  3. ^ a b Burris, Scott; Berman, Micah L.; Penn, Matthew; Holiday, Tara Ramanathan (2018). The New Public Health Law : A Transdisciplinary Approach to Practice and Advocacy. Oxford: Alpha Press (American Public Health Association, Oxford University Press). pp. xv+306. doi:10.1093/oso/9780190681050.001.0001. ISBN 978-0-19-068108-1. OCLC 1034605089. S2CID 158545523. ISBN 9780190681050.
  4. ^ Ariane de Vogue, Long Dead Ohio Farmer, Roscoe Filburn, Plays Crucial Role in Health Care Fight, ABC News (January 30, 2012).
  5. ^ James Chen, Filburn's Legacy, 52 Emory L.J. 1719 (2003).
  6. ^ Ross Nordeen, America's Great Depression: Timeline, The Amateur Economist (June 28, 2011).
  7. ^ "In times of war, this Court has deferred to a considerable extent—and properly so—to the military and to the Executive Branch"; Nos. 03-334, 03-343, Shafiq Rasul v. George W. Bush, Fawzi Khalid Abdullah Fahad al Odah v. United States, On Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit Brief Amicus Curiae of Retired Military Officers in Support of Petitioners, Mirna Adjami James C. Schroeder, Midwest Immigrant and Counsel of Record Human Rights Center. (January 2004)
  8. ^ Wickard, 317 U.S. at 119-20.
  9. ^ Wickard, 317 U.S. at 124-25.
  10. ^ Wickard, 317 U.S. at 128–29.
  11. ^ "Wickard v. Filburn (1942)".
  12. ^ www.cato.org https://www.cato.org/blog/court-says-regulation-state-noncommercial-activity-valid-regulation-interstate-commerce. Retrieved November 2, 2023. {{cite web}}: Missing or empty |title= (help)
  13. ^ "Court precedents involving the commerce and 'necessary and proper' clauses". Washington Post. May 20, 2023. ISSN 0190-8286. Retrieved November 2, 2023.
  14. ^ DeVito, Frank (September 16, 2022). "Overturn Wickard v. Filburn". The American Conservative. Retrieved November 2, 2023.
  15. ^ Earl M. Maltz, as quoted in Chen, supra, at footnote 223.
  16. ^ Adam Liptak, At Heart of Health Law Clash, a 1942 Case of a Farmer’s Wheat, The New York Times (March 19, 2012).

Further reading edit

  • James Chen, Filburn's Legacy, 52 Emory L.J. 1719 (2003).
  • James Chen, The Story of Wickard v. Filburn: Agriculture, Aggregation, and Commerce, (2009). in Dorf, Michael C. (2009). Constitutional Law Stories. Foundation Press.
  • Epstein, Richard A. (2006). How Progressives Rewrote the Constitution. Washington: Cato Institute. ISBN 978-1-930865-87-7.
  • Kommers, D. P.; Finn, J. E.; Jacobsohn, G. J. (2004). American Constitutional Law. Vol. 2 (2nd ed.). Boston: Rowman & Littlefield. ISBN 978-0-7425-2688-4.
  • Robert Natelson, The Legal Meaning of 'Commerce' in the Commerce Clause, 80 St. John's L. Rev 789 (2006).

External links edit

  •   Works related to Wickard v. Filburn at Wikisource
  • Text of Wickard v. Filburn, 317 U.S. 111 (1942) is available from: Cornell  CourtListener  Findlaw  Google Scholar  Justia  Library of Congress 
  • Case Brief for Wickard v. Filburn at Lawnix.com
  • Long analysis of the case

wickard, filburn, 1942, united, states, supreme, court, decision, that, dramatically, increased, regulatory, power, federal, government, remains, most, important, reaching, cases, concerning, deal, precedent, expansive, reading, constitution, commerce, clause,. Wickard v Filburn 317 U S 111 1942 is a United States Supreme Court decision that dramatically increased the regulatory power of the federal government It remains as one of the most important and far reaching cases concerning the New Deal and it set a precedent for an expansive reading of the U S Constitution s Commerce Clause for decades to come The goal of the legal challenge was to end the entire federal crop support program by declaring it unconstitutional 1 Wickard v FilburnSupreme Court of the United StatesArgued May 4 1942Reargued October 12 1942Decided November 9 1942Full case nameClaude R Wickard Secretary of Agriculture et al v Roscoe C FilburnCitations317 U S 111 more 63 S Ct 82 87 L Ed 122 1942 U S LEXIS 1046Case historyPriorInjunction granted to plaintiff Filburn v Helke 43 F Supp 1017 S D Ohio 1942 probable jurisdiction noted 62 S Ct 919 1942 HoldingProduction quotas under the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938 were constitutionally applied to agricultural production that was consumed purely intrastate because its effect upon interstate commerce placed it within the power of Congress to regulate under the Commerce Clause Court membershipChief Justice Harlan F Stone Associate Justices Owen Roberts Hugo BlackStanley F Reed Felix FrankfurterWilliam O Douglas Frank MurphyRobert H JacksonCase opinionMajorityJackson joined by unanimousLaws appliedU S Const amends I V 7 U S C 1281 et seq 1941 Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938 An Ohio farmer Roscoe Filburn was growing wheat to feed animals on his own farm The U S government had established limits on wheat production based on the acreage owned by a farmer to stabilize wheat prices and supplies Filburn grew more than was permitted and so was ordered to pay a penalty In response he said that because his wheat was not sold it could not be regulated as commerce let alone interstate commerce described in the Constitution as Commerce among the several states The Supreme Court disagreed Whether the subject of the regulation in question was production consumption or marketing is therefore not material for purposes of deciding the question of federal power before us But even if appellee s activity be local and though it may not be regarded as commerce it may still whatever its nature be reached by Congress if it exerts a substantial economic effect on interstate commerce and this irrespective of whether such effect is what might at some earlier time have been defined as direct or indirect 2 The Supreme Court interpreted the Constitution s Commerce Clause in Article I Section 8 of the Constitution which permits the U S Congress to regulate Commerce with foreign Nations and among the several States and with the Indian Tribes The Court decided that Filburn s wheat growing activities reduced the amount of wheat he would buy for animal feed on the open market which is traded nationally is thus interstate and is therefore within the scope of the Commerce Clause Although Filburn s relatively small amount of production of more wheat than he was allotted would not affect interstate commerce itself the cumulative actions of thousands of other farmers like Filburn would become substantial Therefore the Court decided that the federal government could regulate Filburn s production 3 Contents 1 Background 2 Decision 3 Aftermath 4 See also 5 References 6 Further reading 7 External linksBackground editThe Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938 limited the area that farmers could devote to wheat production Its stated purpose was to stabilize the price of wheat in the national market by controlling the amount of wheat produced It was motivated by a belief by Congress that great international fluctuations in the supply and the demand for wheat were leading to wide swings in the price of wheat which were deemed to be harmful to the U S agricultural economy The Supreme Court s decision states that the parties had stipulated as to the economic conditions leading to passage of the legislation The parties have stipulated a summary of the economics of the wheat industry The wheat industry has been a problem industry for some years Largely as a result of increased foreign production and import restrictions annual exports of wheat and flour from the United States during the ten year period ending in 1940 averaged less than 10 percent of total production while during the 1920s they averaged more than 25 percent The decline in the export trade has left a large surplus in production which in connection with an abnormally large supply of wheat and other grains in recent years caused congestion in a number of markets tied up railroad cars and caused elevators in some instances to turn away grains and railroads to institute embargoes to prevent further congestion Many countries both importing and exporting have sought to modify the impact of the world market conditions on their own economy Importing countries have taken measures to stimulate production and self sufficiency The four large exporting countries of Argentina Australia Canada and the United States have all undertaken various programs for the relief of growers Such measures have been designed in part at least to protect the domestic price received by producers Such plans have generally evolved towards control by the central government In the absence of regulation the price of wheat in the United States would be much affected by world conditions During 1941 producers who cooperated with the Agricultural Adjustment program received an average price on the farm of about 1 16 a bushel as compared with the world market price of 40 cents a bushel Roscoe Filburn was a farmer in what is now suburban Dayton Ohio 4 He admitted producing wheat in excess of the amount permitted He maintained however that the excess wheat was produced for his private consumption on his own farm Since it never entered commerce at all much less interstate commerce he argued that it was not a proper subject of federal regulation under the Commerce Clause In July 1940 pursuant to the Agricultural Adjustment Act AAA of 1938 Filburn s 1941 allotment was established at 11 1 acres 4 5 ha and a normal yield of 20 1 bushels of wheat per acre 1 4 metric tons per hectare Filburn was given notice of the allotment in July 1940 before the fall planting of his 1941 crop of wheat and again in July 1941 before it was harvested Despite the notices Filburn planted 23 acres 9 3 ha and harvested 239 more bushels 6 500 kg than was allowed from his 11 9 acres 4 8 ha of excess area 3 5 The Federal District Court ruled in favor of Filburn The Act required an affirmative vote of farmers by plebiscite to implement the quota Much of the District Court decision related to the way in which the U S Secretary of Agriculture had campaigned for passage the District Court had held that the Secretary s comments were improper The government then appealed to the Supreme Court which called the District Court s holding against the campaign methods that led to passage of the quota by farmers a manifest error The Court then went on to uphold the Act under the Interstate Commerce Clause By the time that the case reached the high court eight out of the nine justices had been appointed by President Franklin Roosevelt the architect of the New Deal legislation In addition the case was heard during wartime shortly after the attack on Pearl Harbor galvanized the United States to enter the Second World War 6 7 The decision supported the President by holding that the Constitution allowed the federal government to regulate economic activity that was only indirectly related to interstate commerce Decision editThe Act s intended rationale was to stabilize the price of wheat on the national market The federal government has the power to regulate interstate commerce by the Commerce Clause of the Constitution In this decision the Court unanimously reasoned that the power to regulate the price at which commerce occurs was inherent in the power to regulate commerce Filburn argued that since the excess wheat that he produced was intended solely for home consumption his wheat production could not be regulated through the Interstate Commerce Clause The Supreme Court rejected the argument and reasoned that if Filburn had not produced his own wheat he would have bought wheat on the open market That effect on interstate commerce the Court reasoned may not be substantial from the actions of Filburn alone but the cumulative actions of thousands of other farmers just like Filburn would certainly make the effect become substantial Therefore Congress could regulate wholly intrastate non commercial activity if such activity viewed in the aggregate would have a substantial effect on interstate commerce even if the individual effects are trivial Some of the parties argument had focused on prior decisions especially those relating to the Dormant Commerce Clause in which the Court had tried to focus on whether a commercial activity was local or not Justice Robert H Jackson s decision rejected that approach as too formulaic The Government s concern lest the Act be held to be a regulation of production or consumption rather than of marketing is attributable to a few dicta and decisions of this Court which might be understood to lay it down that activities such as production manufacturing and mining are strictly local and except in special circumstances which are not present here cannot be regulated under the commerce power because their effects upon interstate commerce are as matter of law only indirect Even today when this power has been held to have great latitude there is no decision of this Court that such activities may be regulated where no part of the product is intended for interstate commerce or intermingled with the subjects thereof We believe that a review of the course of decision under the Commerce Clause will make plain however that questions of the power of Congress are not to be decided by reference to any formula which would give controlling force to nomenclature such as production and indirect and foreclose consideration of the actual effects of the activity in question upon interstate commerce 8 The issue was not how one characterized the activity as local Rather it was whether the activity exerts a substantial economic effect on interstate commerce Whether the subject of the regulation in question was production consumption or marketing is therefore not material for purposes of deciding the question of federal power before us That an activity is of local character may help in a doubtful case to determine whether Congress intended to reach it But even if appellee s activity be local and though it may not be regarded as commerce it may still whatever its nature be reached by Congress if it exerts a substantial economic effect on interstate commerce and this irrespective of whether such effect is what might at some earlier time have been defined as direct or indirect 9 The regulation of local production of wheat was rationally related to Congress s goal to stabilize prices by limiting the total supply of wheat produced and consumed It was clear the Court held that a factor of such volume and variability as home consumed wheat would have a substantial influence on price and market conditions Home grown wheat in this sense competes with wheat in commerce The stimulation of commerce is a use of the regulatory function quite as definitely as prohibitions or restrictions thereon This record leaves us in no doubt that Congress may properly have considered that wheat consumed on the farm where grown if wholly outside the scheme of regulation would have a substantial effect in defeating and obstructing its purpose to stimulate trade therein at increased prices 10 Aftermath editWickard marked the beginning of the Supreme Court s total deference to the claims of the U S Congress to Commerce Clause powers until the 1990s The Court s own decision however emphasizes the role of the democratic electoral process in confining the abuse of the power of Congress At the beginning Chief Justice Marshall described the Federal commerce power with a breadth never yet exceeded He made emphatic the embracing and penetrating nature of this power by warning that effective restraints on its exercise must proceed from political rather than from judicial processes Critics have noted that under Wickard there is no distinction between interstate and intrastate commerce to place any limits on Congress authority under the Commerce Clause 11 12 and that it allows regulation of activity that is generally not considered commerce 13 14 According to Earl M Maltz Wickard and other New Deal decisions gave Congress the authority to regulate private economic activity in a manner near limitless in its purview 15 That remained the case until United States v Lopez 1995 which was the first decision in six decades to invalidate a federal statute on the grounds that it exceeded the power of the Congress under the Commerce Clause The opinion described Wickard as perhaps the most far reaching example of Commerce Clause authority over intrastate commerce and judged that it greatly expanded the authority of Congress beyond what is defined in the Constitution under that Clause In Lopez the Court held that while Congress had broad lawmaking authority under the Commerce Clause the power was limited and did not extend so far from commerce as to authorize the regulation of the carrying of handguns especially when there was no evidence that carrying them affected the economy on a massive scale In a later case United States v Morrison the Court ruled in 2000 that Congress could not make such laws even when there was evidence of aggregate effect The Supreme Court has since relied heavily on Wickard in upholding the power of the federal government to prosecute individuals who grow their own medicinal marijuana pursuant to state law The Supreme Court would hold in Gonzales v Raich 2005 that like with the home grown wheat at issue in Wickard home grown marijuana is a legitimate subject of federal regulation because it competes with marijuana that moves in interstate commerce Wickard thus establishes that Congress can regulate purely intrastate activity that is not itself commercial in that it is not produced for sale if it concludes that failure to regulate that class of activity would undercut the regulation of the interstate market in that commodity In 2012 Wickard was central to arguments in National Federation of Independent Business v Sebelius and Florida v United States Department of Health and Human Services on the constitutionality of the individual mandate of the Affordable Care Act with both supporters and opponents of the mandate claiming that Wickard supported their positions 16 See also editGonzales v Raich 2005 References edit Jonathan R T Hughes 2014 The Governmental Habit Redux Economic Controls from Colonial Times to the Present Princeton University Press p 168 Wickard v Filburn 317 U S 111 125 1942 a b Burris Scott Berman Micah L Penn Matthew Holiday Tara Ramanathan 2018 The New Public Health Law A Transdisciplinary Approach to Practice and Advocacy Oxford Alpha Press American Public Health Association Oxford University Press pp xv 306 doi 10 1093 oso 9780190681050 001 0001 ISBN 978 0 19 068108 1 OCLC 1034605089 S2CID 158545523 ISBN 9780190681050 Ariane de Vogue Long Dead Ohio Farmer Roscoe Filburn Plays Crucial Role in Health Care Fight ABC News January 30 2012 James Chen Filburn s Legacy 52 Emory L J 1719 2003 Ross Nordeen America s Great Depression Timeline The Amateur Economist June 28 2011 In times of war this Court has deferred to a considerable extent and properly so to the military and to the Executive Branch Nos 03 334 03 343 Shafiq Rasul v George W Bush Fawzi Khalid Abdullah Fahad al Odah v United States On Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit Brief Amicus Curiae of Retired Military Officers in Support of Petitioners Mirna Adjami James C Schroeder Midwest Immigrant and Counsel of Record Human Rights Center January 2004 Wickard 317 U S at 119 20 Wickard 317 U S at 124 25 Wickard 317 U S at 128 29 Wickard v Filburn 1942 www cato org https www cato org blog court says regulation state noncommercial activity valid regulation interstate commerce Retrieved November 2 2023 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a Missing or empty title help Court precedents involving the commerce and necessary and proper clauses Washington Post May 20 2023 ISSN 0190 8286 Retrieved November 2 2023 DeVito Frank September 16 2022 Overturn Wickard v Filburn The American Conservative Retrieved November 2 2023 Earl M Maltz as quoted in Chen supra at footnote 223 Adam Liptak At Heart of Health Law Clash a 1942 Case of a Farmer s Wheat The New York Times March 19 2012 Further reading editJames Chen Filburn s Legacy 52 Emory L J 1719 2003 James Chen The Story of Wickard v Filburn Agriculture Aggregation and Commerce 2009 in Dorf Michael C 2009 Constitutional Law Stories Foundation Press Epstein Richard A 2006 How Progressives Rewrote the Constitution Washington Cato Institute ISBN 978 1 930865 87 7 Kommers D P Finn J E Jacobsohn G J 2004 American Constitutional Law Vol 2 2nd ed Boston Rowman amp Littlefield ISBN 978 0 7425 2688 4 Robert Natelson The Legal Meaning of Commerce in the Commerce Clause 80 St John s L Rev 789 2006 External links edit nbsp Works related to Wickard v Filburn at Wikisource Text of Wickard v Filburn 317 U S 111 1942 is available from Cornell CourtListener Findlaw Google Scholar Justia Library of Congress Case Brief for Wickard v Filburn at Lawnix com Long analysis of the case Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Wickard v Filburn amp oldid 1215916130, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.