fbpx
Wikipedia

Tournament (graph theory)

A tournament is a directed graph (digraph) obtained by assigning a direction for each edge in an undirected complete graph. That is, it is an orientation of a complete graph, or equivalently a directed graph in which every pair of distinct vertices is connected by a directed edge (often, called an arc) with any one of the two possible orientations.

Tournament
A tournament on 4 vertices
Vertices
Edges
Table of graphs and parameters

Many of the important properties of tournaments were first investigated by H. G. Landau in Landau (1953) to model dominance relations in flocks of chickens. Current applications of tournaments include the study of voting theory and social choice theory among other things.

The name tournament originates from such a graph's interpretation as the outcome of a round-robin tournament in which every player encounters every other player exactly once, and in which no draws occur. In the tournament digraph, the vertices correspond to the players. The edge between each pair of players is oriented from the winner to the loser. If player beats player , then it is said that dominates . If every player beats the same number of other players (indegree = outdegree), the tournament is called regular.

Paths and cycles edit

Theorem —  Any tournament on a finite number   of vertices contains a Hamiltonian path, i.e., directed path on all   vertices (Rédei 1934).

 
a is inserted between v2 and v3.

This is easily shown by induction on  : suppose that the statement holds for  , and consider any tournament   on   vertices. Choose a vertex   of   and consider a directed path   in  . There is some   such that  . (One possibility is to let   be maximal such that for every  . Alternatively, let   be minimal such that  .)

 

is a directed path as desired. This argument also gives an algorithm for finding the Hamiltonian path. More efficient algorithms, that require examining only   of the edges, are known. The Hamiltonian paths are in one-to-one correspondence with the minimal feedback arc sets of the tournament.[1] Rédei's theorem is the special case for complete graphs of the Gallai–Hasse–Roy–Vitaver theorem, relating the lengths of paths in orientations of graphs to the chromatic number of these graphs.[2]

Another basic result on tournaments is that every strongly connected tournament has a Hamiltonian cycle.[3] More strongly, every strongly connected tournament is vertex pancyclic: for each vertex  , and each   in the range from three to the number of vertices in the tournament, there is a cycle of length   containing  .[4] A tournament  is  -strongly connected if for every set   of   vertices of  ,   is strongly connected. If the tournament is 4‑strongly connected, then each pair of vertices can be connected with a Hamiltonian path.[5] For every set   of at most   arcs of a  -strongly connected tournament  , we have that   has a Hamiltonian cycle.[6] This result was extended by Bang-Jensen, Gutin & Yeo (1997).

Transitivity edit

 
A transitive tournament on 8 vertices.

A tournament in which   and       is called transitive. In other words, in a transitive tournament, the vertices may be (strictly) totally ordered by the edge relation, and the edge relation is the same as reachability.

Equivalent conditions edit

The following statements are equivalent for a tournament   on   vertices:

  1.   is transitive.
  2.   is a strict total ordering.
  3.   is acyclic.
  4.   does not contain a cycle of length 3.
  5. The score sequence (set of outdegrees) of   is  .
  6.   has exactly one Hamiltonian path.

Ramsey theory edit

Transitive tournaments play a role in Ramsey theory analogous to that of cliques in undirected graphs. In particular, every tournament on   vertices contains a transitive subtournament on   vertices.[7] The proof is simple: choose any one vertex   to be part of this subtournament, and form the rest of the subtournament recursively on either the set of incoming neighbors of   or the set of outgoing neighbors of  , whichever is larger. For instance, every tournament on seven vertices contains a three-vertex transitive subtournament; the Paley tournament on seven vertices shows that this is the most that can be guaranteed (Erdős & Moser 1964). However, Reid & Parker (1970) showed that this bound is not tight for some larger values of  .

Erdős & Moser (1964) proved that there are tournaments on   vertices without a transitive subtournament of size   Their proof uses a counting argument: the number of ways that a  -element transitive tournament can occur as a subtournament of a larger tournament on   labeled vertices is

 

and when   is larger than  , this number is too small to allow for an occurrence of a transitive tournament within each of the   different tournaments on the same set of   labeled vertices.

Paradoxical tournaments edit

A player who wins all games would naturally be the tournament's winner. However, as the existence of non-transitive tournaments shows, there may not be such a player. A tournament for which every player loses at least one game is called a 1-paradoxical tournament. More generally, a tournament   is called  -paradoxical if for every  -element subset   of   there is a vertex   in   such that   for all  . By means of the probabilistic method, Paul Erdős showed that for any fixed value of  , if  , then almost every tournament on   is  -paradoxical.[8] On the other hand, an easy argument shows that any  -paradoxical tournament must have at least   players, which was improved to   by Esther and George Szekeres (1965).[9] There is an explicit construction of  -paradoxical tournaments with   players by Graham and Spencer (1971) namely the Paley tournament.

Condensation edit

The condensation of any tournament is itself a transitive tournament. Thus, even for tournaments that are not transitive, the strongly connected components of the tournament may be totally ordered.[10]

Score sequences and score sets edit

The score sequence of a tournament is the nondecreasing sequence of outdegrees of the vertices of a tournament. The score set of a tournament is the set of integers that are the outdegrees of vertices in that tournament.

Landau's Theorem (1953) A nondecreasing sequence of integers   is a score sequence if and only if :

  1.  
  2.  
  3.  

Let   be the number of different score sequences of size  . The sequence   (sequence A000571 in the OEIS) starts as:

1, 1, 1, 2, 4, 9, 22, 59, 167, 490, 1486, 4639, 14805, 48107, ...

Winston and Kleitman proved that for sufficiently large n:

 

where   Takács later showed, using some reasonable but unproven assumptions, that

 

where  

Together these provide evidence that:

 

Here   signifies an asymptotically tight bound.

Yao showed that every nonempty set of nonnegative integers is the score set for some tournament.

Majority relations edit

In social choice theory, tournaments naturally arise as majority relations of preference profiles.[11] Let   be a finite set of alternatives, and consider a list   of linear orders over  . We interpret each order   as the preference ranking of a voter  . The (strict) majority relation   of   over   is then defined so that   if and only if a majority of the voters prefer   to  , that is  . If the number   of voters is odd, then the majority relation forms the dominance relation of a tournament on vertex set  .

By a lemma of McGarvey, every tournament on   vertices can be obtained as the majority relation of at most   voters.[11][12] Results by Stearns and Erdős & Moser later established that   voters are needed to induce every tournament on   vertices.[13]

Laslier (1997) studies in what sense a set of vertices can be called the set of "winners" of a tournament. This revealed to be useful in Political Science to study, in formal models of political economy, what can be the outcome of a democratic process.[14]

See also edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ Bar-Noy & Naor (1990).
  2. ^ Havet (2013).
  3. ^ Camion (1959).
  4. ^ Moon (1966), Theorem 1.
  5. ^ Thomassen (1980).
  6. ^ Fraisse & Thomassen (1987).
  7. ^ Erdős & Moser (1964).
  8. ^ Erdős (1963)
  9. ^ Szekeres, E.; Szekeres, G. (1965). "On a problem of Schütte and Erdős". Math. Gaz. 49: 290–293.
  10. ^ Harary & Moser (1966), Corollary 5b.
  11. ^ a b Brandt, Felix and Brill, Markus and Harrenstein, Paul, "Tournament Solutions". Chapter 3 in: Brandt, Felix; Conitzer, Vincent; Endriss, Ulle; Lang, Jérôme; Procaccia, Ariel D. (2016). Handbook of Computational Social Choice. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9781107060432. (free online version)
  12. ^ McGarvey, David C. (1953). "A Theorem on the Construction of Voting Paradoxes". Econometrica. 21 (4): 608–610. doi:10.2307/1907926. JSTOR 1907926.
  13. ^ Stearns, Richard (1959). "The Voting Problem". The American Mathematical Monthly. 66 (9): 761–763. doi:10.2307/2310461. JSTOR 2310461.
  14. ^ Austen-Smith, D. and J. Banks, Positive Political theory, 1999, The University of Michigan Press.

References edit

This article incorporates material from tournament on PlanetMath, which is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share-Alike License.

tournament, graph, theory, tournament, directed, graph, digraph, obtained, assigning, direction, each, edge, undirected, complete, graph, that, orientation, complete, graph, equivalently, directed, graph, which, every, pair, distinct, vertices, connected, dire. A tournament is a directed graph digraph obtained by assigning a direction for each edge in an undirected complete graph That is it is an orientation of a complete graph or equivalently a directed graph in which every pair of distinct vertices is connected by a directed edge often called an arc with any one of the two possible orientations TournamentA tournament on 4 verticesVerticesn displaystyle n Edges n2 displaystyle binom n 2 Table of graphs and parametersMany of the important properties of tournaments were first investigated by H G Landau in Landau 1953 to model dominance relations in flocks of chickens Current applications of tournaments include the study of voting theory and social choice theory among other things The name tournament originates from such a graph s interpretation as the outcome of a round robin tournament in which every player encounters every other player exactly once and in which no draws occur In the tournament digraph the vertices correspond to the players The edge between each pair of players is oriented from the winner to the loser If player a displaystyle a beats player b displaystyle b then it is said that a displaystyle a dominates b displaystyle b If every player beats the same number of other players indegree outdegree the tournament is called regular Contents 1 Paths and cycles 2 Transitivity 2 1 Equivalent conditions 2 2 Ramsey theory 2 3 Paradoxical tournaments 2 4 Condensation 3 Score sequences and score sets 4 Majority relations 5 See also 6 Notes 7 ReferencesPaths and cycles editTheorem Any tournament on a finite number n displaystyle n nbsp of vertices contains a Hamiltonian path i e directed path on all n displaystyle n nbsp vertices Redei 1934 nbsp a is inserted between v2 and v3 This is easily shown by induction on n displaystyle n nbsp suppose that the statement holds for n displaystyle n nbsp and consider any tournament T displaystyle T nbsp on n 1 displaystyle n 1 nbsp vertices Choose a vertex v0 displaystyle v 0 nbsp of T displaystyle T nbsp and consider a directed path v1 v2 vn displaystyle v 1 v 2 ldots v n nbsp in T v0 displaystyle T setminus v 0 nbsp There is some i 0 n displaystyle i in 0 ldots n nbsp such that i 0 vi v0 v0 vi 1 i n displaystyle i 0 vee v i rightarrow v 0 wedge v 0 rightarrow v i 1 vee i n nbsp One possibility is to let i 0 n displaystyle i in 0 ldots n nbsp be maximal such that for every j i vj v0 displaystyle j leq i v j rightarrow v 0 nbsp Alternatively let i displaystyle i nbsp be minimal such that j gt i v0 vj displaystyle forall j gt i v 0 rightarrow v j nbsp v1 vi v0 vi 1 vn displaystyle v 1 ldots v i v 0 v i 1 ldots v n nbsp dd is a directed path as desired This argument also gives an algorithm for finding the Hamiltonian path More efficient algorithms that require examining only O nlog n displaystyle O n log n nbsp of the edges are known The Hamiltonian paths are in one to one correspondence with the minimal feedback arc sets of the tournament 1 Redei s theorem is the special case for complete graphs of the Gallai Hasse Roy Vitaver theorem relating the lengths of paths in orientations of graphs to the chromatic number of these graphs 2 Another basic result on tournaments is that every strongly connected tournament has a Hamiltonian cycle 3 More strongly every strongly connected tournament is vertex pancyclic for each vertex v displaystyle v nbsp and each k displaystyle k nbsp in the range from three to the number of vertices in the tournament there is a cycle of length k displaystyle k nbsp containing v displaystyle v nbsp 4 A tournament T displaystyle T nbsp is k displaystyle k nbsp strongly connected if for every set U displaystyle U nbsp of k 1 displaystyle k 1 nbsp vertices of T displaystyle T nbsp T U displaystyle T U nbsp is strongly connected If the tournament is 4 strongly connected then each pair of vertices can be connected with a Hamiltonian path 5 For every set B displaystyle B nbsp of at most k 1 displaystyle k 1 nbsp arcs of a k displaystyle k nbsp strongly connected tournament T displaystyle T nbsp we have that T B displaystyle T B nbsp has a Hamiltonian cycle 6 This result was extended by Bang Jensen Gutin amp Yeo 1997 Transitivity edit nbsp A transitive tournament on 8 vertices A tournament in which a b displaystyle a rightarrow b nbsp and b c displaystyle b rightarrow c nbsp displaystyle Rightarrow nbsp a c displaystyle a rightarrow c nbsp is called transitive In other words in a transitive tournament the vertices may be strictly totally ordered by the edge relation and the edge relation is the same as reachability Equivalent conditions edit The following statements are equivalent for a tournament T displaystyle T nbsp on n displaystyle n nbsp vertices T displaystyle T nbsp is transitive T displaystyle T nbsp is a strict total ordering T displaystyle T nbsp is acyclic T displaystyle T nbsp does not contain a cycle of length 3 The score sequence set of outdegrees of T displaystyle T nbsp is 0 1 2 n 1 displaystyle 0 1 2 ldots n 1 nbsp T displaystyle T nbsp has exactly one Hamiltonian path Ramsey theory edit Transitive tournaments play a role in Ramsey theory analogous to that of cliques in undirected graphs In particular every tournament on n displaystyle n nbsp vertices contains a transitive subtournament on 1 log2 n displaystyle 1 lfloor log 2 n rfloor nbsp vertices 7 The proof is simple choose any one vertex v displaystyle v nbsp to be part of this subtournament and form the rest of the subtournament recursively on either the set of incoming neighbors of v displaystyle v nbsp or the set of outgoing neighbors of v displaystyle v nbsp whichever is larger For instance every tournament on seven vertices contains a three vertex transitive subtournament the Paley tournament on seven vertices shows that this is the most that can be guaranteed Erdos amp Moser 1964 However Reid amp Parker 1970 showed that this bound is not tight for some larger values of n displaystyle n nbsp Erdos amp Moser 1964 proved that there are tournaments on n displaystyle n nbsp vertices without a transitive subtournament of size 2 2 log2 n displaystyle 2 2 lfloor log 2 n rfloor nbsp Their proof uses a counting argument the number of ways that a k displaystyle k nbsp element transitive tournament can occur as a subtournament of a larger tournament on n displaystyle n nbsp labeled vertices is nk k 2 n2 k2 displaystyle binom n k k 2 binom n 2 binom k 2 nbsp and when k displaystyle k nbsp is larger than 2 2 log2 n displaystyle 2 2 lfloor log 2 n rfloor nbsp this number is too small to allow for an occurrence of a transitive tournament within each of the 2 n2 displaystyle 2 binom n 2 nbsp different tournaments on the same set of n displaystyle n nbsp labeled vertices Paradoxical tournaments edit A player who wins all games would naturally be the tournament s winner However as the existence of non transitive tournaments shows there may not be such a player A tournament for which every player loses at least one game is called a 1 paradoxical tournament More generally a tournament T V E displaystyle T V E nbsp is called k displaystyle k nbsp paradoxical if for every k displaystyle k nbsp element subset S displaystyle S nbsp of V displaystyle V nbsp there is a vertex v0 displaystyle v 0 nbsp in V S displaystyle V setminus S nbsp such that v0 v displaystyle v 0 rightarrow v nbsp for all v S displaystyle v in S nbsp By means of the probabilistic method Paul Erdos showed that for any fixed value of k displaystyle k nbsp if V k22kln 2 o 1 displaystyle V geq k 2 2 k ln 2 o 1 nbsp then almost every tournament on V displaystyle V nbsp is k displaystyle k nbsp paradoxical 8 On the other hand an easy argument shows that any k displaystyle k nbsp paradoxical tournament must have at least 2k 1 1 displaystyle 2 k 1 1 nbsp players which was improved to k 2 2k 1 1 displaystyle k 2 2 k 1 1 nbsp by Esther and George Szekeres 1965 9 There is an explicit construction of k displaystyle k nbsp paradoxical tournaments with k24k 1 1 o 1 displaystyle k 2 4 k 1 1 o 1 nbsp players by Graham and Spencer 1971 namely the Paley tournament Condensation edit The condensation of any tournament is itself a transitive tournament Thus even for tournaments that are not transitive the strongly connected components of the tournament may be totally ordered 10 Score sequences and score sets editThe score sequence of a tournament is the nondecreasing sequence of outdegrees of the vertices of a tournament The score set of a tournament is the set of integers that are the outdegrees of vertices in that tournament Landau s Theorem 1953 A nondecreasing sequence of integers s1 s2 sn displaystyle s 1 s 2 ldots s n nbsp is a score sequence if and only if 0 s1 s2 sn displaystyle 0 leq s 1 leq s 2 leq cdots leq s n nbsp s1 s2 si i2 for i 1 2 n 1 displaystyle s 1 s 2 cdots s i geq i choose 2 text for i 1 2 ldots n 1 nbsp s1 s2 sn n2 displaystyle s 1 s 2 cdots s n n choose 2 nbsp Let s n displaystyle s n nbsp be the number of different score sequences of size n displaystyle n nbsp The sequence s n displaystyle s n nbsp sequence A000571 in the OEIS starts as 1 1 1 2 4 9 22 59 167 490 1486 4639 14805 48107 Winston and Kleitman proved that for sufficiently large n s n gt c14nn 5 2 displaystyle s n gt c 1 4 n n 5 2 nbsp where c1 0 049 displaystyle c 1 0 049 nbsp Takacs later showed using some reasonable but unproven assumptions that s n lt c24nn 5 2 displaystyle s n lt c 2 4 n n 5 2 nbsp where c2 lt 4 858 displaystyle c 2 lt 4 858 nbsp Together these provide evidence that s n 8 4nn 5 2 displaystyle s n in Theta 4 n n 5 2 nbsp Here 8 displaystyle Theta nbsp signifies an asymptotically tight bound Yao showed that every nonempty set of nonnegative integers is the score set for some tournament Majority relations editIn social choice theory tournaments naturally arise as majority relations of preference profiles 11 Let A displaystyle A nbsp be a finite set of alternatives and consider a list P 1 n displaystyle P succ 1 dots succ n nbsp of linear orders over A displaystyle A nbsp We interpret each order i displaystyle succ i nbsp as the preference ranking of a voter i displaystyle i nbsp The strict majority relation maj displaystyle succ text maj nbsp of P displaystyle P nbsp over A displaystyle A nbsp is then defined so that a majb displaystyle a succ text maj b nbsp if and only if a majority of the voters prefer a displaystyle a nbsp to b displaystyle b nbsp that is i n a ib gt i n b ia displaystyle i in n a succ i b gt i in n b succ i a nbsp If the number n displaystyle n nbsp of voters is odd then the majority relation forms the dominance relation of a tournament on vertex set A displaystyle A nbsp By a lemma of McGarvey every tournament on m displaystyle m nbsp vertices can be obtained as the majority relation of at most m m 1 displaystyle m m 1 nbsp voters 11 12 Results by Stearns and Erdos amp Moser later established that 8 m log m displaystyle Theta m log m nbsp voters are needed to induce every tournament on m displaystyle m nbsp vertices 13 Laslier 1997 studies in what sense a set of vertices can be called the set of winners of a tournament This revealed to be useful in Political Science to study in formal models of political economy what can be the outcome of a democratic process 14 See also editOriented graph Paley tournament Sumner s conjecture Tournament solutionNotes edit Bar Noy amp Naor 1990 Havet 2013 Camion 1959 Moon 1966 Theorem 1 Thomassen 1980 Fraisse amp Thomassen 1987 Erdos amp Moser 1964 Erdos 1963 Szekeres E Szekeres G 1965 On a problem of Schutte and Erdos Math Gaz 49 290 293 Harary amp Moser 1966 Corollary 5b a b Brandt Felix and Brill Markus and Harrenstein Paul Tournament Solutions Chapter 3 in Brandt Felix Conitzer Vincent Endriss Ulle Lang Jerome Procaccia Ariel D 2016 Handbook of Computational Social Choice Cambridge University Press ISBN 9781107060432 free online version McGarvey David C 1953 A Theorem on the Construction of Voting Paradoxes Econometrica 21 4 608 610 doi 10 2307 1907926 JSTOR 1907926 Stearns Richard 1959 The Voting Problem The American Mathematical Monthly 66 9 761 763 doi 10 2307 2310461 JSTOR 2310461 Austen Smith D and J Banks Positive Political theory 1999 The University of Michigan Press References editBang Jensen J Gutin G Yeo A 1997 Hamiltonian Cycles Avoiding Prescribed Arcs in Tournaments Combinatorics Probability and Computing 6 255 261 Bar Noy A Naor J 1990 Sorting Minimal Feedback Sets and Hamilton Paths in Tournaments SIAM Journal on Discrete Mathematics 3 1 7 20 doi 10 1137 0403002 Camion Paul 1959 Chemins et circuits hamiltoniens des graphes complets Comptes Rendus de l Academie des Sciences de Paris in French 249 2151 2152 Erdos P 1963 On a problem in graph theory PDF The Mathematical Gazette 47 220 223 JSTOR 3613396 MR 0159319 Erdos P Moser L 1964 On the representation of directed graphs as unions of orderings PDF Magyar Tud Akad Mat Kutato Int Kozl 9 125 132 MR 0168494 Fraisse P Thomassen C 1987 A constructive solution to a tournament problem Graphs and Combinatorics 3 239 250 Graham R L Spencer J H 1971 A constructive solution to a tournament problem Canadian Mathematical Bulletin 14 45 48 doi 10 4153 cmb 1971 007 1 MR 0292715 Harary Frank Moser Leo 1966 The theory of round robin tournaments American Mathematical Monthly 73 3 231 246 doi 10 2307 2315334 JSTOR 2315334 Havet Frederic 2013 Section 3 1 Gallai Roy Theorem and related results PDF Orientations and colouring of graphs Lecture notes for the summer school SGT 2013 in Oleron France pp 15 19 Landau H G 1953 On dominance relations and the structure of animal societies III The condition for a score structure Bulletin of Mathematical Biophysics 15 2 143 148 doi 10 1007 BF02476378 Laslier J F 1997 Tournament Solutions and Majority Voting Springer Moon J W 1966 On subtournaments of a tournament Canadian Mathematical Bulletin 9 3 297 301 doi 10 4153 CMB 1966 038 7 Redei Laszlo 1934 Ein kombinatorischer Satz Acta Litteraria Szeged 7 39 43 Reid K B Parker E T 1970 Disproof of a conjecture of Erdos and Moser Journal of Combinatorial Theory 9 3 225 238 doi 10 1016 S0021 9800 70 80061 8 Szekeres E Szekeres G 1965 On a problem of Schutte and Erdos The Mathematical Gazette 49 290 293 doi 10 2307 3612854 MR 0186566 Takacs Lajos 1991 A Bernoulli Excursion and Its Various Applications Advances in Applied Probability 23 3 Applied Probability Trust 557 585 doi 10 2307 1427622 JSTOR 1427622 Thomassen Carsten 1980 Hamiltonian Connected Tournaments Journal of Combinatorial Theory Series B 28 2 142 163 doi 10 1016 0095 8956 80 90061 1 Yao T X 1989 On Reid conjecture of score sets for tournaments Chinese Sci Bull 34 804 808 This article incorporates material from tournament on PlanetMath which is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution Share Alike License Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Tournament graph theory amp oldid 1136273892, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.