fbpx
Wikipedia

Reverse auction

A reverse auction (also known as buyer-determined auction or procurement auction) is a type of auction in which the traditional roles of buyer and seller are reversed.[1] Thus, there is one buyer and many potential sellers. In an ordinary auction also known as a forward auction, buyers compete to obtain goods or services by offering increasingly higher prices. In contrast, in a reverse auction, the sellers compete to obtain business from the buyer and prices will typically decrease as the sellers underbid each other.

A reverse auction is similar to a unique bid auction because the basic principle remains the same; however, a unique bid auction follows the traditional auction format more closely as each bid is kept confidential and one clear winner is defined after the auction finishes.

For business auctions, the term refers to a specific type of auction process (also called e-auction, sourcing event, e-sourcing or eRA, eRFP, e-RFO, e-procurement, B2B Auction). Open procurement processes, which are a form of reverse auction, have been commonly used in government procurement and in the private sector in many countries for many decades.

For consumer auctions, the term is often used to refer to sales processes that share some characteristics with auctions, but are not necessarily auctions in the traditional sense.

Context edit

One common example of reverse auctions is, in many countries, the procurement process in the public sector. Governments often purchase goods or services through an open procurement process by issuing a public tender. Public procurement arrangements for large projects or service programs are often quite complex, frequently involving dozens of individual procurement activities. Reverse auctions can also be used to reveal private opportunity cost information, which can be useful in the design of incentive programs to correct market failures and promote the provisioning of public goods, common-pool resources, and non-market ecosystem services, for example.[2][3]

Another common application of reverse auctions is for e-procurement, a purchasing strategy used for strategic sourcing and other supply management activities. E-procurement arrangements enable suppliers to compete online in real time and is changing the way firms and their consortia select and behave with their suppliers worldwide. It can help improve the effectiveness of the sourcing process and facilitate access to new suppliers. This may in the future lead to a standardization of sourcing procedures, reduced order cycle, which can enable businesses to reduce prices and generally provide a higher level of service.[4]

  • In a traditional auction, the seller offers an item for sale. Potential buyers are then free to bid on the item until the time period expires. The buyer with the highest offer wins the right to purchase the item for the price determined at the end of the auction.
  • A reverse auction is different in that a single buyer offers a contract out for bidding. (In an e-procurement arrangement this is done either by using specialized software or through an on-line marketplace.) Multiple sellers are invited to offer bids on the contract. In public procurement, time limits for the receipt of bids apply.[5]

E-procurement

In the case of e-procurement, When real-time e-bidding is permitted, the price decreases as sellers compete to offer lower bids than their competitors whilst still meeting all of the specifications of the original contract.

Bidding performed in real-time via the Internet results in a dynamic, competitive process. This helps achieve rapid downward price pressure that is not normally attainable using traditional static paper-based bidding processes. Many reverse auction software companies or service providers report an average price reduction of 18–20 percent following the initial auction's completion.[6]

The buyer may award the contract to the seller who bid the lowest price. Or, a buyer may award contracts to suppliers who bid higher prices depending on the buyer's specific needs with regard to quality, lead-time, capacity, or other value-adding capabilities.

The use of optimization software has become popular since 2002[clarification needed] to help buyers determine which supplier is likely to provide the best value in providing goods or services. The software includes relevant buyer and seller business data, including constraints.[citation needed]

Reverse auctions are used to fill both large and small value contracts for both public sector and private commercial organizations. In addition to items traditionally thought of as commodities, reverse auctions are also used to source buyer-designed goods and services; and they have even been used to source reverse auction providers. The first time this occurred was in August 2001, when America West Airlines (which later became US Airways) used FreeMarkets software and awarded the contract to MaterialNet.[citation needed]

One form of reverse auction is static auction (RFQ or tender). Static auction is alternative to dynamic auction and regular negotiation process in commerce especially on B2B electronic marketplace.

In 2003, researchers claimed an average of five percent of total corporate spending was sourced using reverse auctions.[7] They have been found to be more appropriate and suitable in industries and sectors like advertising, auto components, bulk chemicals, consumer durables, computers and peripherals, contract manufacturing, courier services, FMCG, healthcare, hospitality, insurance, leasing, logistics, maritime shipping, MRO, retail, software licensing, textiles, tourism, transport and warehousing.[4]

History of internet-based reverse auctions edit

The pioneer of online e-procurement reverse auctions in the United States, FreeMarkets, was founded in 1995 by former McKinsey & Company consultant and General Electric executive Glen Meakem after he failed to find internal backing for the idea of a reverse auction division at General Electric. Meakem hired McKinsey colleague Sam Kinney, who developed much of the intellectual property behind FreeMarkets. Headquartered in Pittsburgh, FreeMarkets built teams of "market makers" and "commodity managers" to manage the process of running the online tender process and set up market operations to manage auctions on a global basis.[citation needed]

The company's growth was aided greatly by the hype of the dot-com boom era. FreeMarkets customers included BP, United Technologies, Visteon, Heinz, Phelps Dodge, ExxonMobil, and Royal Dutch Shell, to name a few. Dozens of competing start-up reverse auction service providers and established companies such as General Motors (an early FreeMarkets customer) and SAP, rushed to join the reverse auction marketspace.[citation needed]

Although FreeMarkets survived the winding down of the dot-com boom, by the early-2000s, it was apparent that its business model was really like an old-economy consulting firm with some sophisticated proprietary software. Online reverse auctions started to become mainstream and the prices that FreeMarkets had commanded for its services dropped significantly. This led to a consolidation of the reverse auction service marketplace. In January 2004, Ariba announced its purchase of FreeMarkets for US$493 million.[8]

Fortune published an article in March 2000, describing the early days of internet-based reverse auctions.[9]

In the past few years mobile reverse auction have evolved.[10] Unlike business-to-business (B2B) reverse auctions, mobile reverse auctions are business-to-consumer (B2C) and allow consumers to bid on products for pennies. The lowest unique bid wins.[citation needed]

Very recently business-to-consumer auctions with a twist have started to evolve; they are more similar to the original business-to-business auctions than mobile reverse auctions in that they offer consumers the option of placing a specification before retailers or resellers and allowing them to publicly bid for their business.[citation needed]

In congressional testimony on the 2008 proposed legislative package to use federal funds to buy toxic assets from troubled financial firms, Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke proposed that a reverse auction could be used to price the assets.[citation needed]

In 2004, the White House Office of Federal Procurement Policy (OFPP) issued a memorandum encouraging increased use of commercially available online procurement tools, including reverse auctions.[11] In 2005, both the Government Accountability Office and Court of Federal Claims upheld the legality of federal agency use of online reverse auctions.[12] In 2008, OFPP issued a government-wide memorandum encouraging agencies to improve and increase competitive procurement and included specific examples of competition best practices, including reverse auctions.[13] In 2010, The White House Office of Management and Budget cited "continued implementation of innovative procurement methods, such as the use of web-based electronic reverse auctions" as one of the contracting reforms helping agencies meet acquisition savings goals.[14]

Scoring Auctions edit

A common form of procurement auction is known as a scoring auction. In that auction form, the score that the buyer gives each bidder depends on well-defined attributes of the offer and the bidder. This scoring function is formulated and announced prior to the start of the auction.[15]

Buyer Determined Auctions edit

Many procurement auctions are "buyer determined" in that the buyer reserves the right to select the winner on any basis following the conclusion of the auction. The literature on buyer-determined auctions is often empirical in nature and is concerned with identifying the unannounced implicit scoring function the buyer uses. This is typically done through a discrete choice model, wherein the econometrician uses the observed attributes, including price, and maps them to the probability of being chosen as the winner. This allows the econometrician to identify the weight on each attribute. [16] Conceptually and theoretically, the effect of this format on buyer-supplier relationships is of paramount importance.[17] Instead of each bidder as submitting a price and the lowest price bidder winning the contract, here each bidder can be perceived as submitting a total "score" involving a price + nonprice attributes. The winner is the bidder who has the highest score. Unlike scoring auctions, there is no pre-announced or binding weight on each quality attribute that will determine the winner in a formal fashion. Rather, bidders operate in an uncertain environment in which only the buyer knows its own considerations. Given the uncertainty regarding other bidders’ nonprice qualities, it may be that bidders learn about the competition by observing other bidders’ bids. One can therefore expect systematic differences in their response patterns to competitive bids. [18] Likewise, the provision of information on other bidders in such auctions is generally known to affect prices [19] Pre-existing relationships are known to be the key driver in the buyer’s selection and therefore bidding aggressiveness in the auction-- in terms of the number of bids submitted, the rate at which the bids are submitted, and the price concessions offered—are related to these relationships. [20] Theoretically, the factors that determine under what circumstances a buyer would prefer this format over a price-based format have been explored. [21][22]

Demsetz auction edit

A Demsetz auction is a system which awards an exclusive contract to the agent bidding the lowest price named after Harold Demsetz.[23] This is sometimes referred to "competition for the field." It is in contrast to "competition in the field," which calls for two or more agents to be granted the contract and provide the good or service competitively. Martin Ricketts writes that "under competitive conditions, the bid prices should fall until they just enable firms to achieve a normal return on capital."[24] Disadvantages of a Demsetz auction include the fact that the entire risk associated with falling demand is borne by one agent and that the winner of the bid, once locked into the contract, may accumulate non-transferable know-how that can then be used to gain leverage for contract renewal. Demsetz auctions are often used to award contracts for public-private partnerships for highway construction.

Spectrum auction edit

In the United States, the Federal Communications Commission created FCC auction 1001 as a reverse auction in order to get back much of the 600MHz band from television broadcasting. The remaining TV stations would then be repacked onto the lower UHF and even VHF TV channels. After the reverse auction in June 2016, a forward spectrum auction (FCC auction 1002) will then be held, with mostly mobile phone carriers as the buyers.

Dutch reverse auctions edit

While a traditional Dutch Auction starts at a high bid which will then decrease, a Reverse Dutch Auction works the opposite way as it starts at a low price and then gradually increases over time.[25] It contains a list of items that buyers want to procure and the price rises after fixed intervals until a reserved price is reached. Before the reserved price is reached, if a supplier places a bid for the item, it is allocated to the supplier and the item closes for bidding.

In this auction, the buyer specifies a starting price, price change value, time interval between price changes, and the reserved price.

The auction opens with the first item with a specified start price and increases by the price change value (amount or percentage) after a fixed interval. The start price keeps on increasing until any supplier places a bid or the start price reaches the reserved price. After the bidding is closed for the item it moves to another item sequentially.

Auction is closed when the bidding for all items is completed.[26]

Japanese reverse auctions edit

Although the history of the Japanese reverse auction is unknown, they are widely used in the world of business-to-business procurement as a form of cost negotiation.

A Japanese auction is where the host of the auction states an opening price and participants have to accept that price level or withdraw from the auction. Acceptance indicates that the participant is prepared to supply at the stated price. When all participants reply to a certain price, the software lowers the price level by a predetermined amount and again asks participants to accept or decline at the new price level.

This kind of auction continues until there are no more participants bidding.[27]

Comparison of Japanese and Dutch reverse auctions edit

The major difference between Japanese and Dutch reverse auctions is in putting suppliers in two different position. While in Dutch reverse auctions suppliers opt-in at intended price point and thus end the auction immediately, in reverse Japanese auctions suppliers explicitly opt-out of a given market at their intended price point.

The benefits of the Japanese reverse auction are based on the fact that the buying organization has greater transparency to the actual market itself. In this regard, the format more closely mirrors that of a traditional reverse auction by providing greater visibility to each participant's lowest offer.

But in contrast to a Dutch auction format, Japanese auctions do not put what one Dutch auction users describes as "maximum psychological pressure" on the supply base and especially on the incumbent suppliers. This can put the buyer in a better position regarding with potentially earning more than he should based on the market.[28]

Strategy in Reverse auctions edit

The suppliers should firstly determine the lowest price for which they are willing to sell their products. To do this effectively they must be able to compute their true marginal cost and identify extra-auctions costs and benefits. However, that does not mean that the best strategy is to bid the lowest price. In the analysis of extra-auction costs and benefits, they should examine areas where winning or losing can generate unexpected benefits or avoided costs. Some examples include:

  • Winning or losing changes their volume discount, rebates and incentives with key suppliers,
  • Losing requires laying off personnel with its associated termination costs,
  • Winning opens a new account more inexpensively than hiring a sales representative.

Based on this analysis, the supplier should choose his goals for the auction. The obvious goal is to win the auction at a profitable price. However, that is not always the best goal. Because of the examples of reasons mentioned above the supplier might choose as a goal for example:

  • To come in second (or third) while keeping the price high,
  • To come in second while driving the price down to unprofitable levels for the winner,
  • To bid down to a certain price and stop, regardless of winning position and potential profitability.

After this preparation, the supplier should try to achieve his goal within the specific auction protocols and characteristics of the auction interface. The important characteristics that differ between auctions are the ability to see the current low bid and the knowing of their current relative position.[29]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Chen, Rachel R.; Roundy, Robin O.; Zhang, Rachel Q.; Janakiraman, Ganesh (1 March 2005). "Efficient Auction Mechanisms for Supply Chain Procurement". Management Science. 51 (3): 467–482. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1040.0329. ISSN 0025-1909.
  2. ^ Kindu, Mengistie (2022). "Auctioning approaches for ecosystem services–Evidence and applications" (PDF). Science of the Total Environment. 853. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2022.158534. (PDF) from the original on 26 February 2024. Retrieved 26 February 2024 – via mediaTUM.
  3. ^ Jindal, Rohit (2013). "Social dimensions of procurement auctions for environmental service contracts: Evaluating tradeoffs between cost-effectiveness and participation by the poor in rural Tanzania". Land Use Policy. 31 (March 2013): 71–80. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2011.11.008. Retrieved 26 February 2024.
  4. ^ a b Srivastava, Samir K, "Managerial Implications from Indian Case Studies on e-Reverse Auctions", Business Process Management Journal, 18(3), 2012, pp. 513-531.
  5. ^ Pliatsidis, Andreas Christos (2022-01-01). "Impact of the time limits for the receipt of tenders on the number of bidders: evidence from public procurement in Greece". Journal of Public Procurement. 22 (4): 314–335. doi:10.1108/JOPP-05-2022-0025. ISSN 2150-6930. S2CID 253312170.
  6. ^ "B2B Online Reverse Auctions: The Complete Guide". 16 June 2015.
  7. ^ Beall, S., Carter, C., Carter, P., Germer, T., Hendrick, T., Jap, S., Kaufmann, L., Maciejewski, D., Monczka, R., and Peterson, K., (2003), "The Role of Reverse Auctions in Strategic Sourcing", CAPS Research Report, CAPS Research, Tempe, AZ
  8. ^ Kawamoto, Dawn (Jan 23, 2004). . ZDNet. Archived from the original on Apr 28, 2008.
  9. ^ Tully, Shawn (2000-03-20). "Going, Going, Gone! The B2B Tool That Really Is Changing The World. Web Auctions Are Revolutionizing The $5 Trillion Market For Industrial Parts. In The Process They're Wiring The Rust Belt For Good". CNN.
  10. ^ "Industrial Auctions". www.aucto.com.
  11. ^ Memorandum for Federal Acquisition Council Agency Senior Procurement Executives, White House Office of Federal Procurement Policy, May 12, 2004
  12. ^ MTB Group, Inc. v. United States, 65 Fed. Cl. 516, 523-24, February 23, 2005
  13. ^ Memorandum for Chief Acquisition Officers, White House Office of Federal Procurement Policy, July 18, 2008
  14. ^ Memorandum for Senior Executive Service from Jeffrey Zients, Federal Chief Performance Officer, September 14, 2010
  15. ^ Asker, J., & Cantillon, E. (2008). Properties of scoring auctions. The RAND Journal of Economics, 39(1), 69-85.
  16. ^ Brosig‐Koch, J., & Heinrich, T. (2014). Reputation and mechanism choice in procurement auctions: An experiment. Production and Operations Management, 23(2), 210-220.
  17. ^ Jap, S. D. (2007). The impact of online reverse auction design on buyer–supplier relationships. Journal of Marketing, 71(1), 146-159.
  18. ^ Haruvy, E., & Jap, S. D. (2013). Differentiated bidders and bidding behavior in procurement auctions. Journal of Marketing Research, 50(2), 241-258.
  19. ^ Haruvy, E., & Katok, E. (2013). Increasing revenue by decreasing information in procurement auctions. Production and Operations Management, 22(1), 19-35.
  20. ^ Jap, S. D., & Haruvy, E. (2008). Interorganizational relationships and bidding behavior in industrial online reverse auctions. Journal of Marketing Research, 45(5), 550-561
  21. ^ Engelbrecht-Wiggans, R., Haruvy, E., & Katok, E. (2007). A comparison of buyer-determined and price-based multiattribute mechanisms. Marketing Science, 26(5), 629-641.
  22. ^ Katok, Elena, and Achim Wambach. "Collusion in dynamic buyer-determined reverse auctions." Management Science (2008): 1-27.
  23. ^ Engel, Eduardo M. R. A.; Fischer, Ronald D.; Galetovic, Alexander (2004). "How to Auction a Bottleneck Monopoly When Underhand Vertical Agreements are Possible". The Journal of Industrial Economics. 52 (3): 427–455. doi:10.1111/j.0022-1821.2004.00233.x. ISSN 1467-6451. S2CID 15404063.
  24. ^ Ricketts, Martin. The Economics of Business Enterprise.
  25. ^ PROCUREHERE. "The Benefits of a Reverse Dutch Auction | Procurehere Blog". Retrieved 2019-04-30.
  26. ^ "IBM Knowledge Center". www.ibm.com (in European Spanish). Retrieved 2019-04-30.
  27. ^ "Market Dojo Why Japanese Auctions". On-Demand eProcurement. Retrieved 2018-01-04.
  28. ^ "Japanese vs. Dutch Reverse Auctions". Spend Matters. 2009-10-05. Retrieved 2019-04-30.
  29. ^ Maudlin, Stuart (30 April 2019). "Game tactics: How to participate in reverse auctions". LEA Global.

Further reading edit

  • Schoenherr, T., and Mabert, V.A. (2007), "Online reverse auctions: common myths versus evolving reality", Business Horizons, 50, 373-384.
  • Bounds, G., "Toyota Supplier Development", in Cases in Quality, G. Bounds, Editor, R.D. Irwin Co., Chicago, IL, 1996, pp. 3–25
  • Shalev, E. Moshe and Asbjornsen, S., "Electronic Reverse Auctions and the Public Sector – Factors of Success", Journal of Public Procurement, 10(3) 428-452.
  • Bounds, G., Shaw, A., and Gillard, J., "Partnering the Honda Way", in Cases in Quality, G. Bounds, Editor, R.D. Irwin Co., Chicago, IL, 1996, pp. 26–56
  • Dyer, J. and Nobeoka, K., "Creating and Managing a High-Performance Knowledge Sharing Network: The Toyota Case," Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 21, 2000, pp. 345–367
  • Liker, J. and Choi, T., "Building Deep Supplier Relationships", Harvard Business Review, Vol. 82, No. 12, December 2004, pp. 104–113
  • Womack, J., Jones, D., and Roos, D., The Machine that Changed the World, Rawson Associates, New York, 1990, Chapter 6
  • Jap, Sandy D. (2007), "The Impact of Online Reverse Auction Design on Buyer-Supplier Relationships", Journal of Marketing, 71(1), 146-50
  • Hammami, Farouk; Rekik, Monia; Coelho, Leandro C. (2019). "Exact and heuristic solution approaches for the bid construction problem in transportation procurement auctions with a heterogeneous fleet". Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review. 127: 150–177. doi:10.1016/j.tre.2019.05.009. S2CID 182223089..

reverse, auction, this, article, written, like, personal, reflection, personal, essay, argumentative, essay, that, states, wikipedia, editor, personal, feelings, presents, original, argument, about, topic, please, help, improve, rewriting, encyclopedic, style,. This article is written like a personal reflection personal essay or argumentative essay that states a Wikipedia editor s personal feelings or presents an original argument about a topic Please help improve it by rewriting it in an encyclopedic style October 2011 Learn how and when to remove this template message A reverse auction also known as buyer determined auction or procurement auction is a type of auction in which the traditional roles of buyer and seller are reversed 1 Thus there is one buyer and many potential sellers In an ordinary auction also known as a forward auction buyers compete to obtain goods or services by offering increasingly higher prices In contrast in a reverse auction the sellers compete to obtain business from the buyer and prices will typically decrease as the sellers underbid each other A reverse auction is similar to a unique bid auction because the basic principle remains the same however a unique bid auction follows the traditional auction format more closely as each bid is kept confidential and one clear winner is defined after the auction finishes For business auctions the term refers to a specific type of auction process also called e auction sourcing event e sourcing or eRA eRFP e RFO e procurement B2B Auction Open procurement processes which are a form of reverse auction have been commonly used in government procurement and in the private sector in many countries for many decades For consumer auctions the term is often used to refer to sales processes that share some characteristics with auctions but are not necessarily auctions in the traditional sense Contents 1 Context 2 History of internet based reverse auctions 3 Scoring Auctions 4 Buyer Determined Auctions 5 Demsetz auction 6 Spectrum auction 7 Dutch reverse auctions 8 Japanese reverse auctions 9 Comparison of Japanese and Dutch reverse auctions 10 Strategy in Reverse auctions 11 See also 12 References 13 Further readingContext editOne common example of reverse auctions is in many countries the procurement process in the public sector Governments often purchase goods or services through an open procurement process by issuing a public tender Public procurement arrangements for large projects or service programs are often quite complex frequently involving dozens of individual procurement activities Reverse auctions can also be used to reveal private opportunity cost information which can be useful in the design of incentive programs to correct market failures and promote the provisioning of public goods common pool resources and non market ecosystem services for example 2 3 Another common application of reverse auctions is for e procurement a purchasing strategy used for strategic sourcing and other supply management activities E procurement arrangements enable suppliers to compete online in real time and is changing the way firms and their consortia select and behave with their suppliers worldwide It can help improve the effectiveness of the sourcing process and facilitate access to new suppliers This may in the future lead to a standardization of sourcing procedures reduced order cycle which can enable businesses to reduce prices and generally provide a higher level of service 4 In a traditional auction the seller offers an item for sale Potential buyers are then free to bid on the item until the time period expires The buyer with the highest offer wins the right to purchase the item for the price determined at the end of the auction A reverse auction is different in that a single buyer offers a contract out for bidding In an e procurement arrangement this is done either by using specialized software or through an on line marketplace Multiple sellers are invited to offer bids on the contract In public procurement time limits for the receipt of bids apply 5 E procurementIn the case of e procurement When real time e bidding is permitted the price decreases as sellers compete to offer lower bids than their competitors whilst still meeting all of the specifications of the original contract Bidding performed in real time via the Internet results in a dynamic competitive process This helps achieve rapid downward price pressure that is not normally attainable using traditional static paper based bidding processes Many reverse auction software companies or service providers report an average price reduction of 18 20 percent following the initial auction s completion 6 The buyer may award the contract to the seller who bid the lowest price Or a buyer may award contracts to suppliers who bid higher prices depending on the buyer s specific needs with regard to quality lead time capacity or other value adding capabilities The use of optimization software has become popular since 2002 clarification needed to help buyers determine which supplier is likely to provide the best value in providing goods or services The software includes relevant buyer and seller business data including constraints citation needed Reverse auctions are used to fill both large and small value contracts for both public sector and private commercial organizations In addition to items traditionally thought of as commodities reverse auctions are also used to source buyer designed goods and services and they have even been used to source reverse auction providers The first time this occurred was in August 2001 when America West Airlines which later became US Airways used FreeMarkets software and awarded the contract to MaterialNet citation needed One form of reverse auction is static auction RFQ or tender Static auction is alternative to dynamic auction and regular negotiation process in commerce especially on B2B electronic marketplace In 2003 researchers claimed an average of five percent of total corporate spending was sourced using reverse auctions 7 They have been found to be more appropriate and suitable in industries and sectors like advertising auto components bulk chemicals consumer durables computers and peripherals contract manufacturing courier services FMCG healthcare hospitality insurance leasing logistics maritime shipping MRO retail software licensing textiles tourism transport and warehousing 4 History of internet based reverse auctions editThe pioneer of online e procurement reverse auctions in the United States FreeMarkets was founded in 1995 by former McKinsey amp Company consultant and General Electric executive Glen Meakem after he failed to find internal backing for the idea of a reverse auction division at General Electric Meakem hired McKinsey colleague Sam Kinney who developed much of the intellectual property behind FreeMarkets Headquartered in Pittsburgh FreeMarkets built teams of market makers and commodity managers to manage the process of running the online tender process and set up market operations to manage auctions on a global basis citation needed The company s growth was aided greatly by the hype of the dot com boom era FreeMarkets customers included BP United Technologies Visteon Heinz Phelps Dodge ExxonMobil and Royal Dutch Shell to name a few Dozens of competing start up reverse auction service providers and established companies such as General Motors an early FreeMarkets customer and SAP rushed to join the reverse auction marketspace citation needed Although FreeMarkets survived the winding down of the dot com boom by the early 2000s it was apparent that its business model was really like an old economy consulting firm with some sophisticated proprietary software Online reverse auctions started to become mainstream and the prices that FreeMarkets had commanded for its services dropped significantly This led to a consolidation of the reverse auction service marketplace In January 2004 Ariba announced its purchase of FreeMarkets for US 493 million 8 Fortune published an article in March 2000 describing the early days of internet based reverse auctions 9 In the past few years mobile reverse auction have evolved 10 Unlike business to business B2B reverse auctions mobile reverse auctions are business to consumer B2C and allow consumers to bid on products for pennies The lowest unique bid wins citation needed Very recently business to consumer auctions with a twist have started to evolve they are more similar to the original business to business auctions than mobile reverse auctions in that they offer consumers the option of placing a specification before retailers or resellers and allowing them to publicly bid for their business citation needed In congressional testimony on the 2008 proposed legislative package to use federal funds to buy toxic assets from troubled financial firms Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke proposed that a reverse auction could be used to price the assets citation needed In 2004 the White House Office of Federal Procurement Policy OFPP issued a memorandum encouraging increased use of commercially available online procurement tools including reverse auctions 11 In 2005 both the Government Accountability Office and Court of Federal Claims upheld the legality of federal agency use of online reverse auctions 12 In 2008 OFPP issued a government wide memorandum encouraging agencies to improve and increase competitive procurement and included specific examples of competition best practices including reverse auctions 13 In 2010 The White House Office of Management and Budget cited continued implementation of innovative procurement methods such as the use of web based electronic reverse auctions as one of the contracting reforms helping agencies meet acquisition savings goals 14 Scoring Auctions editA common form of procurement auction is known as a scoring auction In that auction form the score that the buyer gives each bidder depends on well defined attributes of the offer and the bidder This scoring function is formulated and announced prior to the start of the auction 15 Buyer Determined Auctions editMany procurement auctions are buyer determined in that the buyer reserves the right to select the winner on any basis following the conclusion of the auction The literature on buyer determined auctions is often empirical in nature and is concerned with identifying the unannounced implicit scoring function the buyer uses This is typically done through a discrete choice model wherein the econometrician uses the observed attributes including price and maps them to the probability of being chosen as the winner This allows the econometrician to identify the weight on each attribute 16 Conceptually and theoretically the effect of this format on buyer supplier relationships is of paramount importance 17 Instead of each bidder as submitting a price and the lowest price bidder winning the contract here each bidder can be perceived as submitting a total score involving a price nonprice attributes The winner is the bidder who has the highest score Unlike scoring auctions there is no pre announced or binding weight on each quality attribute that will determine the winner in a formal fashion Rather bidders operate in an uncertain environment in which only the buyer knows its own considerations Given the uncertainty regarding other bidders nonprice qualities it may be that bidders learn about the competition by observing other bidders bids One can therefore expect systematic differences in their response patterns to competitive bids 18 Likewise the provision of information on other bidders in such auctions is generally known to affect prices 19 Pre existing relationships are known to be the key driver in the buyer s selection and therefore bidding aggressiveness in the auction in terms of the number of bids submitted the rate at which the bids are submitted and the price concessions offered are related to these relationships 20 Theoretically the factors that determine under what circumstances a buyer would prefer this format over a price based format have been explored 21 22 Demsetz auction editA Demsetz auction is a system which awards an exclusive contract to the agent bidding the lowest price named after Harold Demsetz 23 This is sometimes referred to competition for the field It is in contrast to competition in the field which calls for two or more agents to be granted the contract and provide the good or service competitively Martin Ricketts writes that under competitive conditions the bid prices should fall until they just enable firms to achieve a normal return on capital 24 Disadvantages of a Demsetz auction include the fact that the entire risk associated with falling demand is borne by one agent and that the winner of the bid once locked into the contract may accumulate non transferable know how that can then be used to gain leverage for contract renewal Demsetz auctions are often used to award contracts for public private partnerships for highway construction Spectrum auction editIn the United States the Federal Communications Commission created FCC auction 1001 as a reverse auction in order to get back much of the 600MHz band from television broadcasting The remaining TV stations would then be repacked onto the lower UHF and even VHF TV channels After the reverse auction in June 2016 a forward spectrum auction FCC auction 1002 will then be held with mostly mobile phone carriers as the buyers Dutch reverse auctions editWhile a traditional Dutch Auction starts at a high bid which will then decrease a Reverse Dutch Auction works the opposite way as it starts at a low price and then gradually increases over time 25 It contains a list of items that buyers want to procure and the price rises after fixed intervals until a reserved price is reached Before the reserved price is reached if a supplier places a bid for the item it is allocated to the supplier and the item closes for bidding In this auction the buyer specifies a starting price price change value time interval between price changes and the reserved price The auction opens with the first item with a specified start price and increases by the price change value amount or percentage after a fixed interval The start price keeps on increasing until any supplier places a bid or the start price reaches the reserved price After the bidding is closed for the item it moves to another item sequentially Auction is closed when the bidding for all items is completed 26 Japanese reverse auctions editAlthough the history of the Japanese reverse auction is unknown they are widely used in the world of business to business procurement as a form of cost negotiation A Japanese auction is where the host of the auction states an opening price and participants have to accept that price level or withdraw from the auction Acceptance indicates that the participant is prepared to supply at the stated price When all participants reply to a certain price the software lowers the price level by a predetermined amount and again asks participants to accept or decline at the new price level This kind of auction continues until there are no more participants bidding 27 Comparison of Japanese and Dutch reverse auctions editThe major difference between Japanese and Dutch reverse auctions is in putting suppliers in two different position While in Dutch reverse auctions suppliers opt in at intended price point and thus end the auction immediately in reverse Japanese auctions suppliers explicitly opt out of a given market at their intended price point The benefits of the Japanese reverse auction are based on the fact that the buying organization has greater transparency to the actual market itself In this regard the format more closely mirrors that of a traditional reverse auction by providing greater visibility to each participant s lowest offer But in contrast to a Dutch auction format Japanese auctions do not put what one Dutch auction users describes as maximum psychological pressure on the supply base and especially on the incumbent suppliers This can put the buyer in a better position regarding with potentially earning more than he should based on the market 28 Strategy in Reverse auctions editThe suppliers should firstly determine the lowest price for which they are willing to sell their products To do this effectively they must be able to compute their true marginal cost and identify extra auctions costs and benefits However that does not mean that the best strategy is to bid the lowest price In the analysis of extra auction costs and benefits they should examine areas where winning or losing can generate unexpected benefits or avoided costs Some examples include Winning or losing changes their volume discount rebates and incentives with key suppliers Losing requires laying off personnel with its associated termination costs Winning opens a new account more inexpensively than hiring a sales representative Based on this analysis the supplier should choose his goals for the auction The obvious goal is to win the auction at a profitable price However that is not always the best goal Because of the examples of reasons mentioned above the supplier might choose as a goal for example To come in second or third while keeping the price high To come in second while driving the price down to unprofitable levels for the winner To bid down to a certain price and stop regardless of winning position and potential profitability After this preparation the supplier should try to achieve his goal within the specific auction protocols and characteristics of the auction interface The important characteristics that differ between auctions are the ability to see the current low bid and the knowing of their current relative position 29 See also editTendering Request for Quotation Request For Tender Request For Information Request For Proposal Optimization mathematics Operations research ShpoonkleReferences edit Chen Rachel R Roundy Robin O Zhang Rachel Q Janakiraman Ganesh 1 March 2005 Efficient Auction Mechanisms for Supply Chain Procurement Management Science 51 3 467 482 doi 10 1287 mnsc 1040 0329 ISSN 0025 1909 Kindu Mengistie 2022 Auctioning approaches for ecosystem services Evidence and applications PDF Science of the Total Environment 853 doi 10 1016 j scitotenv 2022 158534 Archived PDF from the original on 26 February 2024 Retrieved 26 February 2024 via mediaTUM Jindal Rohit 2013 Social dimensions of procurement auctions for environmental service contracts Evaluating tradeoffs between cost effectiveness and participation by the poor in rural Tanzania Land Use Policy 31 March 2013 71 80 doi 10 1016 j landusepol 2011 11 008 Retrieved 26 February 2024 a b Srivastava Samir K Managerial Implications from Indian Case Studies on e Reverse Auctions Business Process Management Journal 18 3 2012 pp 513 531 Pliatsidis Andreas Christos 2022 01 01 Impact of the time limits for the receipt of tenders on the number of bidders evidence from public procurement in Greece Journal of Public Procurement 22 4 314 335 doi 10 1108 JOPP 05 2022 0025 ISSN 2150 6930 S2CID 253312170 B2B Online Reverse Auctions The Complete Guide 16 June 2015 Beall S Carter C Carter P Germer T Hendrick T Jap S Kaufmann L Maciejewski D Monczka R and Peterson K 2003 The Role of Reverse Auctions in Strategic Sourcing CAPS Research Report CAPS Research Tempe AZ Kawamoto Dawn Jan 23 2004 Ariba to buy FreeMarkets for 493 million ZDNet Archived from the original on Apr 28 2008 Tully Shawn 2000 03 20 Going Going Gone The B2B Tool That Really Is Changing The World Web Auctions Are Revolutionizing The 5 Trillion Market For Industrial Parts In The Process They re Wiring The Rust Belt For Good CNN Industrial Auctions www aucto com Memorandum for Federal Acquisition Council Agency Senior Procurement Executives White House Office of Federal Procurement Policy May 12 2004 MTB Group Inc v United States 65 Fed Cl 516 523 24 February 23 2005 Memorandum for Chief Acquisition Officers White House Office of Federal Procurement Policy July 18 2008 Memorandum for Senior Executive Service from Jeffrey Zients Federal Chief Performance Officer September 14 2010 Asker J amp Cantillon E 2008 Properties of scoring auctions The RAND Journal of Economics 39 1 69 85 Brosig Koch J amp Heinrich T 2014 Reputation and mechanism choice in procurement auctions An experiment Production and Operations Management 23 2 210 220 Jap S D 2007 The impact of online reverse auction design on buyer supplier relationships Journal of Marketing 71 1 146 159 Haruvy E amp Jap S D 2013 Differentiated bidders and bidding behavior in procurement auctions Journal of Marketing Research 50 2 241 258 Haruvy E amp Katok E 2013 Increasing revenue by decreasing information in procurement auctions Production and Operations Management 22 1 19 35 Jap S D amp Haruvy E 2008 Interorganizational relationships and bidding behavior in industrial online reverse auctions Journal of Marketing Research 45 5 550 561 Engelbrecht Wiggans R Haruvy E amp Katok E 2007 A comparison of buyer determined and price based multiattribute mechanisms Marketing Science 26 5 629 641 Katok Elena and Achim Wambach Collusion in dynamic buyer determined reverse auctions Management Science 2008 1 27 Engel Eduardo M R A Fischer Ronald D Galetovic Alexander 2004 How to Auction a Bottleneck Monopoly When Underhand Vertical Agreements are Possible The Journal of Industrial Economics 52 3 427 455 doi 10 1111 j 0022 1821 2004 00233 x ISSN 1467 6451 S2CID 15404063 Ricketts Martin The Economics of Business Enterprise PROCUREHERE The Benefits of a Reverse Dutch Auction Procurehere Blog Retrieved 2019 04 30 IBM Knowledge Center www ibm com in European Spanish Retrieved 2019 04 30 Market Dojo Why Japanese Auctions On Demand eProcurement Retrieved 2018 01 04 Japanese vs Dutch Reverse Auctions Spend Matters 2009 10 05 Retrieved 2019 04 30 Maudlin Stuart 30 April 2019 Game tactics How to participate in reverse auctions LEA Global Further reading editSchoenherr T and Mabert V A 2007 Online reverse auctions common myths versus evolving reality Business Horizons 50 373 384 Bounds G Toyota Supplier Development in Cases in Quality G Bounds Editor R D Irwin Co Chicago IL 1996 pp 3 25 Shalev E Moshe and Asbjornsen S Electronic Reverse Auctions and the Public Sector Factors of Success Journal of Public Procurement 10 3 428 452 Bounds G Shaw A and Gillard J Partnering the Honda Way in Cases in Quality G Bounds Editor R D Irwin Co Chicago IL 1996 pp 26 56 Dyer J and Nobeoka K Creating and Managing a High Performance Knowledge Sharing Network The Toyota Case Strategic Management Journal Vol 21 2000 pp 345 367 Liker J and Choi T Building Deep Supplier Relationships Harvard Business Review Vol 82 No 12 December 2004 pp 104 113 Womack J Jones D and Roos D The Machine that Changed the World Rawson Associates New York 1990 Chapter 6 Jap Sandy D 2007 The Impact of Online Reverse Auction Design on Buyer Supplier Relationships Journal of Marketing 71 1 146 50 Hammami Farouk Rekik Monia Coelho Leandro C 2019 Exact and heuristic solution approaches for the bid construction problem in transportation procurement auctions with a heterogeneous fleet Transportation Research Part E Logistics and Transportation Review 127 150 177 doi 10 1016 j tre 2019 05 009 S2CID 182223089 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Reverse auction amp oldid 1218780225, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.