fbpx
Wikipedia

Monopoly price

In microeconomics, a monopoly price is set by a monopoly.[1][2] A monopoly occurs when a firm lacks any viable competition and is the sole producer of the industry's product.[1][2] Because a monopoly faces no competition, it has absolute market power and can set a price above the firm's marginal cost.[1][2]

The monopoly ensures a monopoly price exists when it establishes the quantity of the product.[1] As the sole supplier of the product within the market, its sales establish the entire industry's supply within the market, and the monopoly's production and sales decisions can establish a single price for the industry without any influence from competing firms.[1][2][3] The monopoly always considers the demand for its product as it considers what price is appropriate, such that it chooses a production supply and price combination that ensures a maximum economic profit,[1][2] which is determined by ensuring that the marginal cost (determined by the firm's technical limitations that form its cost structure) is the same as the marginal revenue (MR) (as determined by the impact a change in the price of the product will impact the quantity demanded) at the quantity it decides to sell.[1][2] The marginal revenue is solely determined by the demand for the product within the industry and is the change in revenue that will occur by lowering the price just enough to ensure a single additional unit is sold.[1][2] The marginal revenue is positive, but it is lower than its associated price because lowering the price will increase the demand for its product and increase the firm's sales revenue, and lower the price paid by those who are willing to buy the product at the higher price, which ensures a lower sales revenue on the product sales than those willing to pay the higher price.[1]

Marginal revenue can be calculated as , where .[2][clarification needed]

Reduction in price increases the quantity demanded, but reduces payments by those who would be willing to pay a higher price: MR < P

Marginal cost (MC) relates to the firm's technical cost structure within production, and indicates the rise in total cost that must occur for an additional unit to be supplied to the market by the firm.[1] The marginal cost is higher than the average cost because of diminishing marginal product in the short run.[1] It can be calculated as , where .[2][4][clarification needed]

Diminishing marginal product ensures the rise in cost from producing an additional item (marginal cost) is always greater than the average variable (controllable) cost at that level of production. Since some costs cannot be controlled in the short run, the variable (controllable) costs will always be lower than the total costs in the short run.

Samuelson[who?] indicates this point on the consumer demand curve is where the price is equal to one over one plus the reciprocal of the price elasticity of demand.[5] This rule does not apply to competitive firms, as they are price takers and do not have the market power to control either prices or industry-wide sales.[1]

Although the term markup is sometimes used in economics to refer to the difference between a monopoly price and the monopoly's MC,[6] it is frequently used in American accounting and finance to define the difference between the price of the product and its per unit accounting cost. Accepted neo-classical micro-economic theory indicates the American accounting and finance definition of markup, as it exists in most competitive markets, ensures an accounting profit that is just enough to solely compensate the equity owners of a competitive firm within a competitive market for the economic cost (opportunity cost) they must bear if they hold on to the firm's equity.[3] The economic cost of holding onto equity at its present value is the opportunity cost the investor must bear when giving up the interest earnings on debt of similar present value (they hold onto equity instead of the debt).[3] Economists would indicate that a markup rule on economic cost used by a monopoly to set a monopoly price that will maximize its profit is excessive markup that leads to inefficiencies within an economic system.[1][2][7][8]

Mathematical derivation: how a monopoly sets the monopoly price edit

Mathematically, the general rule a monopoly uses to maximize monopoly profit can be derived through simple calculus. The basic equation for economic profit, in which the total economic cost varies directly with the quantity produced, can be expressed as

 , where

  •   = quantity sold,
  •   = inverse demand function; the price at which   can be sold given the existing demand
  •   = total cost of producing  .
  •   = economic profit


This is done by equating the derivative of   with respect to   to 0. The profit of a firm is given by total revenue (price times quantity sold) minus total cost:

 , where

  •   = quantity sold,
  •   = the partial derivative of the inverse demand function, and the price at which   can be sold given the existing demand
  •   = marginal cost, or the partial derivative of the total cost of producing  


which yields

 
where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. This is usually called the first order conditions for a profit maximum.[2]

 
A monopolist will set a price and production quantity where MC=MR, such that MR is always below the monopoly price set. A competitive firm's MR is the price it gets for its product, and will have Price=MC.

According to Samuelson,

 

By definition,   is the reciprocal of the price elasticity of demand (or  ), or

 

This gives the markup rule:

 .

Note that the price elasticity of demand (and its reciprocal) is negative,  , so a more intuitive formula, using the absolute value of the elasticity, is

 .

This shows clearly that the profit-maximizing price is set at a point where "demand is elastic", namely, the price elasticity of demand must be greater than unity in absolute terms, in order for the profit-maximizing price to be positive.

Letting   be the reciprocal of the price elasticity of demand,

 

Thus the monopolistic firm chooses the quantity at which the demand price satisfies this rule. Since   for a price setting firm, it means that a firm with market power will charge a price above marginal cost and earn a monopoly rent. On the other hand, a competitive firm by definition faces a perfectly elastic demand,  , which means that it sets price equal to marginal cost.

The rule also implies that, absent menu costs, a monopolistic firm will never choose a point on the inelastic portion of its demand curve. For an equilibrium to exist in a monopoly or in an oligopoly market, the price elasticity of demand must be less than negative one ( ), for marginal revenue to be positive.[4] The mathematical profit maximization conditions ("first order conditions") ensure the price elasticity of demand must be less than negative one,[2][7] since no rational firm that attempts to maximize its profit would incur additional cost (a positive marginal cost) in order to reduce revenue (when MR < 0).[1]


In the case of price elasticity of demand, it also called Lerner index. The formula can be expressed:  ,   means monopoly price set by firms   means the marginal cost of production

The Lerner index measures the level of market power and monopoly power that a firm owned.The higher Lerner index indicated the more monopoly power allows a company have chance to establish prices that are higher than their marginal costs and then lead a higher monopoly price. In conclusion, a monopoly price is established by a monopolistic firm while they have no rivals in the market and feasible to raise price further above their marginal cost. In order to ensure a maximum economic return, the monopoly price is established at the point where marginal revenue equals marginal cost based on the firm's evaluation of the demand for its product. The Lerner index can be used to measured the degree of monopoly power and monopoly price.

In addition, monopoly price will prevent new business from entering the market and restrict innovation. A monopoly would not like to invest more on research and development or innovation due to it already has a captive market. Then the lack of innovation may block market competition and limit the industry’s growth potential in long run. The monopoly’s entrance restrictions also make it difficult for new businesses to enter the market, which reduces the scope for innovation and new ideas.

In sum up, monopoly pricing generally has negative consequences on consumers and the overall economy, resulting in higher costs, lower quantity desired, inefficiencies and a lack of innovation.

Properties edit

Objectives edit

Of the many price-setting methods, a monopoly will set the price with respect to market demand id est demand-based pricing.

When a firm with absolute market power sets the monopoly price, the primary objective is to maximize its own profits by capturing consumer surplus and maximizing its own. A monopoly accomplishes this by setting a price above its marginal cost and producing at a quantity that meets market demand and corresponds to the set price.

Nature edit

Monopoly Price and market inefficiencies edit

 
Static Monopoly Price: Deadweight Loss

Monopoly pricing without perfect price discrimination results in market inefficiencies when compared to other market structures. The inefficiencies in question are a loss of both consumer and producer surplus otherwise known as a deadweight loss. The loss in both surplus' are deemed allocatively inefficient and not socially optimal. In contrast, when the firm has more information and discrimination is present, monopoly pricing becomes increasingly efficient as it approaches perfect discrimination through the various forms of price discrimination:

Theoretical Considerations edit

Dynamic Pricing for Monopolies edit

Much of the empirical literature suggest that setting a dynamic or variable monopoly price is market-efficient and can maximize total profits for the firm. However, this is only true when certain assumptions are made and specific circumstances are present. A paper written by Harris and Raviv [9] advise firms who are restricted by productive capacity to set their prices on a priority-basis. If production capacity is capped and not only restricted, Harris and Raviv suggest pricing goods in an auction format to be optimal for maximizing profits. Both pricing schemes are argued to be effective under the assumptions that price adjustments are costless. Further studies by Rajan et al. (1993)[10] have also concluded that a variable pricing scheme to be optimal for maximizing profits. Rajan argues that dynamic costs such as purchasing and carrying costs should lead to an increase in price. Additionally, He suggests goods that drop in value or decay should lead to a decrease in price as demand for said goods also decrease therefore the firm should drop the price as to maximize profits again and reclaim lost producer surplus.


Market structure of monopoly edit

A market structure is defined by three factors which are barriers to entry, number of firms in the market, and product substitutability.

Below is the market structure for a monopoly:

Market structure for a monopoly
Barriers to entry[11] Number of firms in the market Product substitutability
  • intensity of competition (short term)
  • entry sunk cost faced by entrants
  • fixed cost faced by incumbents
1 No other perfect substitutes of product

Unlike perfect competition where firms can freely enter and exit the market, it is not the case for monopolistic competition. For a monopoly to exist, there must be high barriers to entry for new firms. Barriers to entry must be strong enough to discourage potential competitors from entering. However, if the number of firms in the market for a specific good or service increases, the perceived value of firms in the market will decrease. Therefore, the likelihood for firms to exit the market is higher, leaving one firm to monopolise the market.

The difference between the products or services of a perfect competition and one in a monopoly is if the products or services are differentiated. Thereby, the products or services sold in the monopolistic market are not perfect substitutes for one another.[12]

Market power of monopoly edit

Market power is the firm's ability to affect terms and conditions of exchange. [13] A monopoly possesses a substantial amount of market power, however, it is not unlimited. A monopoly is a price maker, not a price taker, meaning that a monopoly has the power to set the market price. [14] The firm in monopoly is the market as it sets its price based on their circumstances of what best suits them.

Summary of monopoly characteristics edit

To easily identify a monopoly, it would have one or more of these five characteristics

Summary of monopoly characteristics
Characteristics Explanation
Profit maximiser Monopolist will maximise their profits by ensuring marginal cost (MC) = marginal revenue (MR).
Price Maker The monopolist sets the price according to its own circumstances and not what other firms are pricing their products or services as.
High barriers to entry Other firms are unable to enter the market of the monopoly
Single seller/ firm The monopolist is the only seller in the market that produces all the outputs meeting all the demands of the market.
Price discrimination The firm in monopoly can change the price and quantity of the product as they please. Therefore, to meet all demands and gain a profit, they may sell high quantities at a low price in an elastic market and sell lower quantities at a high price in an inelastic market.

References edit

  1. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n Roger LeRoy Miller, Intermediate Microeconomics Theory Issues Applications, Third Edition, New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc, 1982.
  2. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l Tirole, Jean, "The Theory of Industrial Organization", Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press, 1988.
  3. ^ a b c John Black, "Oxford Dictionary of Economics", New York: Oxford University Press, 2003.
  4. ^ a b Henderson, James M., and Richard E. Quandt, "Micro Economic Theory, A Mathematical Approach. 3rd Edition", New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1980. Glenview, Illinois: Scott, Foresmand and Company, 1988. Usually, in many textbooks, economic cost, here presented by  , is divided into two categories; labor costs and capital costs:  , where
    •   = labor hired,
    •   = wage rate,
    •   = total amount of capital financed by both debt and equity,
    •   = cost of capital, including both interest expense and the minimum required rate of return on equity
    •   =   = a function of the quantity of labor and capital employed in production
  5. ^ Samuelson; Marks (2003). p.104
  6. ^ Nicholson, Walter and Christopher Snyder, Microeconomic Theory: Basic Principles and Extensions, Mason, OH: Thomson/South-Western, 2008.
  7. ^ a b Henderson, James M., and Richard E. Quandt, "Micro Economic Theory, A Mathematical Approach. 3rd Edition", New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1980. Glenview, Illinois: Scott, Foresmand and Company, 1988.
  8. ^ Bradley R. chiller, "Essentials of Economics", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc., 1991.
  9. ^ Harris, Milton; Raviv, Artur (1981). "A Theory of Monopoly Pricing Schemes with Demand Uncertainty". The American Economic Review. 71 (3): 347–365. ISSN 0002-8282.
  10. ^ Rajan, Arvind; Steinberg, Rakesh; Steinberg, Richard (1992). "Dynamic Pricing and Ordering Decisions by a Monopolist". Management Science. 38 (2): 240–262. ISSN 0025-1909.
  11. ^ Samuelson, William F; Marks, Stephen G (2003). Managerial Economics. Wiley. pp. 365–366. ISBN 978-0-470-00041-0.
  12. ^ Hirschey (2000). Managerial Economics. Dreyden. p. 426.
  13. ^ Krugman, Paul; Wells, Robin (2009). Microeconomics (2nd ed.). Worth.
  14. ^ Melvin, Michael; Boyes, William (2002). Microeconomics (5th ed.). Houghton Mifflin. p. 239.

monopoly, price, microeconomics, monopoly, price, monopoly, monopoly, occurs, when, firm, lacks, viable, competition, sole, producer, industry, product, because, monopoly, faces, competition, absolute, market, power, price, above, firm, marginal, cost, monopol. In microeconomics a monopoly price is set by a monopoly 1 2 A monopoly occurs when a firm lacks any viable competition and is the sole producer of the industry s product 1 2 Because a monopoly faces no competition it has absolute market power and can set a price above the firm s marginal cost 1 2 The monopoly ensures a monopoly price exists when it establishes the quantity of the product 1 As the sole supplier of the product within the market its sales establish the entire industry s supply within the market and the monopoly s production and sales decisions can establish a single price for the industry without any influence from competing firms 1 2 3 The monopoly always considers the demand for its product as it considers what price is appropriate such that it chooses a production supply and price combination that ensures a maximum economic profit 1 2 which is determined by ensuring that the marginal cost determined by the firm s technical limitations that form its cost structure is the same as the marginal revenue MR as determined by the impact a change in the price of the product will impact the quantity demanded at the quantity it decides to sell 1 2 The marginal revenue is solely determined by the demand for the product within the industry and is the change in revenue that will occur by lowering the price just enough to ensure a single additional unit is sold 1 2 The marginal revenue is positive but it is lower than its associated price because lowering the price will increase the demand for its product and increase the firm s sales revenue and lower the price paid by those who are willing to buy the product at the higher price which ensures a lower sales revenue on the product sales than those willing to pay the higher price 1 Marginal revenue can be calculated as M R P P Q Q displaystyle MR P P Q Q where 0 gt P Q displaystyle 0 gt P Q 2 clarification needed Reduction in price increases the quantity demanded but reduces payments by those who would be willing to pay a higher price MR lt PMarginal cost MC relates to the firm s technical cost structure within production and indicates the rise in total cost that must occur for an additional unit to be supplied to the market by the firm 1 The marginal cost is higher than the average cost because of diminishing marginal product in the short run 1 It can be calculated as M C C Q displaystyle MC C Q where 0 lt C Q displaystyle 0 lt C Q 2 4 clarification needed Diminishing marginal product ensures the rise in cost from producing an additional item marginal cost is always greater than the average variable controllable cost at that level of production Since some costs cannot be controlled in the short run the variable controllable costs will always be lower than the total costs in the short run Samuelson who indicates this point on the consumer demand curve is where the price is equal to one over one plus the reciprocal of the price elasticity of demand 5 This rule does not apply to competitive firms as they are price takers and do not have the market power to control either prices or industry wide sales 1 Although the term markup is sometimes used in economics to refer to the difference between a monopoly price and the monopoly s MC 6 it is frequently used in American accounting and finance to define the difference between the price of the product and its per unit accounting cost Accepted neo classical micro economic theory indicates the American accounting and finance definition of markup as it exists in most competitive markets ensures an accounting profit that is just enough to solely compensate the equity owners of a competitive firm within a competitive market for the economic cost opportunity cost they must bear if they hold on to the firm s equity 3 The economic cost of holding onto equity at its present value is the opportunity cost the investor must bear when giving up the interest earnings on debt of similar present value they hold onto equity instead of the debt 3 Economists would indicate that a markup rule on economic cost used by a monopoly to set a monopoly price that will maximize its profit is excessive markup that leads to inefficiencies within an economic system 1 2 7 8 Contents 1 Mathematical derivation how a monopoly sets the monopoly price 2 Properties 2 1 Objectives 2 2 Nature 2 2 1 Monopoly Price and market inefficiencies 3 Theoretical Considerations 3 1 Dynamic Pricing for Monopolies 4 Market structure of monopoly 5 Market power of monopoly 6 Summary of monopoly characteristics 7 ReferencesMathematical derivation how a monopoly sets the monopoly price editThis section needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section Unsourced material may be challenged and removed January 2022 Learn how and when to remove this template message Mathematically the general rule a monopoly uses to maximize monopoly profit can be derived through simple calculus The basic equation for economic profit in which the total economic cost varies directly with the quantity produced can be expressed asp P Q Q C Q displaystyle pi P Q times Q C Q nbsp where Q displaystyle Q nbsp quantity sold P Q displaystyle P Q nbsp inverse demand function the price at which Q displaystyle Q nbsp can be sold given the existing demand C Q displaystyle C Q nbsp total cost of producing Q displaystyle Q nbsp p displaystyle pi nbsp economic profit This is done by equating the derivative of p displaystyle pi nbsp with respect to Q displaystyle Q nbsp to 0 The profit of a firm is given by total revenue price times quantity sold minus total cost P Q Q P C Q 0 displaystyle P Q Q P C Q 0 nbsp where Q displaystyle Q nbsp quantity sold P Q displaystyle P Q nbsp the partial derivative of the inverse demand function and the price at which Q displaystyle Q nbsp can be sold given the existing demand C Q displaystyle C Q nbsp marginal cost or the partial derivative of the total cost of producing Q displaystyle Q nbsp which yieldsP Q Q P C Q displaystyle P Q Q P C Q nbsp where marginal revenue equals marginal cost This is usually called the first order conditions for a profit maximum 2 nbsp A monopolist will set a price and production quantity where MC MR such that MR is always below the monopoly price set A competitive firm s MR is the price it gets for its product and will have Price MC According to Samuelson P P Q P 1 M C displaystyle P P Q P 1 MC nbsp By definition P Q P displaystyle P Q P nbsp is the reciprocal of the price elasticity of demand or 1 ϵ displaystyle 1 epsilon nbsp orP 1 1 ϵ M C displaystyle P 1 1 epsilon MC nbsp This gives the markup rule P ϵ ϵ 1 M C displaystyle P frac epsilon epsilon 1 MC nbsp Note that the price elasticity of demand and its reciprocal is negative ϵ lt 0 displaystyle epsilon lt 0 nbsp so a more intuitive formula using the absolute value of the elasticity isP ϵ ϵ 1 M C displaystyle P frac epsilon epsilon 1 MC nbsp This shows clearly that the profit maximizing price is set at a point where demand is elastic namely the price elasticity of demand must be greater than unity in absolute terms in order for the profit maximizing price to be positive Letting h displaystyle eta nbsp be the reciprocal of the price elasticity of demand P 1 1 h M C displaystyle P frac 1 1 eta MC nbsp Thus the monopolistic firm chooses the quantity at which the demand price satisfies this rule Since h lt 0 displaystyle eta lt 0 nbsp for a price setting firm it means that a firm with market power will charge a price above marginal cost and earn a monopoly rent On the other hand a competitive firm by definition faces a perfectly elastic demand h 0 displaystyle eta 0 nbsp which means that it sets price equal to marginal cost The rule also implies that absent menu costs a monopolistic firm will never choose a point on the inelastic portion of its demand curve For an equilibrium to exist in a monopoly or in an oligopoly market the price elasticity of demand must be less than negative one 1 h lt 1 displaystyle frac 1 eta lt 1 nbsp for marginal revenue to be positive 4 The mathematical profit maximization conditions first order conditions ensure the price elasticity of demand must be less than negative one 2 7 since no rational firm that attempts to maximize its profit would incur additional cost a positive marginal cost in order to reduce revenue when MR lt 0 1 In the case of price elasticity of demand it also called Lerner index The formula can be expressed L P M C P displaystyle L frac P MC P nbsp P displaystyle P nbsp means monopoly price set by firms M C displaystyle MC nbsp means the marginal cost of productionThe Lerner index measures the level of market power and monopoly power that a firm owned The higher Lerner index indicated the more monopoly power allows a company have chance to establish prices that are higher than their marginal costs and then lead a higher monopoly price In conclusion a monopoly price is established by a monopolistic firm while they have no rivals in the market and feasible to raise price further above their marginal cost In order to ensure a maximum economic return the monopoly price is established at the point where marginal revenue equals marginal cost based on the firm s evaluation of the demand for its product The Lerner index can be used to measured the degree of monopoly power and monopoly price In addition monopoly price will prevent new business from entering the market and restrict innovation A monopoly would not like to invest more on research and development or innovation due to it already has a captive market Then the lack of innovation may block market competition and limit the industry s growth potential in long run The monopoly s entrance restrictions also make it difficult for new businesses to enter the market which reduces the scope for innovation and new ideas In sum up monopoly pricing generally has negative consequences on consumers and the overall economy resulting in higher costs lower quantity desired inefficiencies and a lack of innovation Properties editObjectives edit Of the many price setting methods a monopoly will set the price with respect to market demand id est demand based pricing When a firm with absolute market power sets the monopoly price the primary objective is to maximize its own profits by capturing consumer surplus and maximizing its own A monopoly accomplishes this by setting a price above its marginal cost and producing at a quantity that meets market demand and corresponds to the set price Nature edit Monopoly Price and market inefficiencies edit nbsp Static Monopoly Price Deadweight Loss Monopoly pricing without perfect price discrimination results in market inefficiencies when compared to other market structures The inefficiencies in question are a loss of both consumer and producer surplus otherwise known as a deadweight loss The loss in both surplus are deemed allocatively inefficient and not socially optimal In contrast when the firm has more information and discrimination is present monopoly pricing becomes increasingly efficient as it approaches perfect discrimination through the various forms of price discrimination Quantity Discount Market Segregation Two part tariff Combination User Controlled Price DiscriminationTheoretical Considerations editDynamic Pricing for Monopolies edit Much of the empirical literature suggest that setting a dynamic or variable monopoly price is market efficient and can maximize total profits for the firm However this is only true when certain assumptions are made and specific circumstances are present A paper written by Harris and Raviv 9 advise firms who are restricted by productive capacity to set their prices on a priority basis If production capacity is capped and not only restricted Harris and Raviv suggest pricing goods in an auction format to be optimal for maximizing profits Both pricing schemes are argued to be effective under the assumptions that price adjustments are costless Further studies by Rajan et al 1993 10 have also concluded that a variable pricing scheme to be optimal for maximizing profits Rajan argues that dynamic costs such as purchasing and carrying costs should lead to an increase in price Additionally He suggests goods that drop in value or decay should lead to a decrease in price as demand for said goods also decrease therefore the firm should drop the price as to maximize profits again and reclaim lost producer surplus Market structure of monopoly editA market structure is defined by three factors which are barriers to entry number of firms in the market and product substitutability Below is the market structure for a monopoly Market structure for a monopoly Barriers to entry 11 Number of firms in the market Product substitutability intensity of competition short term entry sunk cost faced by entrants fixed cost faced by incumbents 1 No other perfect substitutes of product Unlike perfect competition where firms can freely enter and exit the market it is not the case for monopolistic competition For a monopoly to exist there must be high barriers to entry for new firms Barriers to entry must be strong enough to discourage potential competitors from entering However if the number of firms in the market for a specific good or service increases the perceived value of firms in the market will decrease Therefore the likelihood for firms to exit the market is higher leaving one firm to monopolise the market The difference between the products or services of a perfect competition and one in a monopoly is if the products or services are differentiated Thereby the products or services sold in the monopolistic market are not perfect substitutes for one another 12 Market power of monopoly editMarket power is the firm s ability to affect terms and conditions of exchange 13 A monopoly possesses a substantial amount of market power however it is not unlimited A monopoly is a price maker not a price taker meaning that a monopoly has the power to set the market price 14 The firm in monopoly is the market as it sets its price based on their circumstances of what best suits them Summary of monopoly characteristics editTo easily identify a monopoly it would have one or more of these five characteristics Summary of monopoly characteristics Characteristics Explanation Profit maximiser Monopolist will maximise their profits by ensuring marginal cost MC marginal revenue MR Price Maker The monopolist sets the price according to its own circumstances and not what other firms are pricing their products or services as High barriers to entry Other firms are unable to enter the market of the monopoly Single seller firm The monopolist is the only seller in the market that produces all the outputs meeting all the demands of the market Price discrimination The firm in monopoly can change the price and quantity of the product as they please Therefore to meet all demands and gain a profit they may sell high quantities at a low price in an elastic market and sell lower quantities at a high price in an inelastic market References edit a b c d e f g h i j k l m n Roger LeRoy Miller Intermediate Microeconomics Theory Issues Applications Third Edition New York McGraw Hill Inc 1982 a b c d e f g h i j k l Tirole Jean The Theory of Industrial Organization Cambridge Massachusetts The MIT Press 1988 a b c John Black Oxford Dictionary of Economics New York Oxford University Press 2003 a b Henderson James M and Richard E Quandt Micro Economic Theory A Mathematical Approach 3rd Edition New York McGraw Hill Book Company 1980 Glenview Illinois Scott Foresmand and Company 1988 Usually in many textbooks economic cost here presented by C Q displaystyle C Q nbsp is divided into two categories labor costs and capital costs C Q L w K R displaystyle C Q Lw KR nbsp where L displaystyle L nbsp labor hired w displaystyle w nbsp wage rate K displaystyle K nbsp total amount of capital financed by both debt and equity R displaystyle R nbsp cost of capital including both interest expense and the minimum required rate of return on equity Q displaystyle Q nbsp Q L K displaystyle Q L K nbsp a function of the quantity of labor and capital employed in production Samuelson Marks 2003 p 104 Nicholson Walter and Christopher Snyder Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensions Mason OH Thomson South Western 2008 a b Henderson James M and Richard E Quandt Micro Economic Theory A Mathematical Approach 3rd Edition New York McGraw Hill Book Company 1980 Glenview Illinois Scott Foresmand and Company 1988 Bradley R chiller Essentials of Economics New York McGraw Hill Inc 1991 Harris Milton Raviv Artur 1981 A Theory of Monopoly Pricing Schemes with Demand Uncertainty The American Economic Review 71 3 347 365 ISSN 0002 8282 Rajan Arvind Steinberg Rakesh Steinberg Richard 1992 Dynamic Pricing and Ordering Decisions by a Monopolist Management Science 38 2 240 262 ISSN 0025 1909 Samuelson William F Marks Stephen G 2003 Managerial Economics Wiley pp 365 366 ISBN 978 0 470 00041 0 Hirschey 2000 Managerial Economics Dreyden p 426 Krugman Paul Wells Robin 2009 Microeconomics 2nd ed Worth Melvin Michael Boyes William 2002 Microeconomics 5th ed Houghton Mifflin p 239 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Monopoly price amp oldid 1168758833, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.