fbpx
Wikipedia

Marginal product of labor

In economics, the marginal product of labor (MPL) is the change in output that results from employing an added unit of labor.[1] It is a feature of the production function and depends on the amounts of physical capital and labor already in use.

Definition edit

The marginal product of a factor of production is generally defined as the change in output resulting from a unit or infinitesimal change in the quantity of that factor used, holding all other input usages in the production process constant.

The marginal product of labor is then the change in output (Y) per unit change in labor (L). In discrete terms the marginal product of labor is:

 

In continuous terms, the MPL is the first derivative of the production function:

 [2]

Graphically, the MPL is the slope of the production function.

Examples edit

 
Marginal product of labor table

There is a factory which produces toys. When there are no workers in the factory, no toys are produced. When there is one worker in the factory, six toys are produced per hour. When there are two workers in the factory, eleven toys are produced per hour. There is a marginal product of labor of five when there are two workers in the factory compared to one. When the marginal product of labor is increasing, this is called increasing marginal returns. However, as the number of workers increases, the marginal product of labor may not increase indefinitely. When not scaled properly, the marginal product of labor may go down when the number of employees goes up, creating a situation known as diminishing marginal returns. When the marginal product of labor becomes negative, it is known as negative marginal returns.

Marginal costs edit

The marginal product of labor is directly related to costs of production. Costs are divided between fixed and variable costs. Fixed costs are costs that relate to the fixed input, capital, or rK, where r is the rental cost of capital and K is the quantity of capital. Variable costs (VC) are the costs of the variable input, labor, or wL, where w is the wage rate and L is the amount of labor employed. Thus, VC = wL. Marginal cost (MC) is the change in total cost per unit change in output or ∆C/∆Q. In the short run, production can be varied only by changing the variable input. Thus only variable costs change as output increases: ∆C = ∆VC = ∆(wL). Marginal cost is ∆(Lw)/∆Q. Now, ∆L/∆Q is the reciprocal of the marginal product of labor (∆Q/∆L). Therefore, marginal cost is simply the wage rate w divided by the marginal product of labor

 

(the change in quantity of labor to effect a one unit change in output)  

Therefore  

Thus, if the marginal product of labor is rising, then marginal costs will be falling, and if the marginal product of labor is falling, marginal costs will be rising (assuming a constant wage rate).[3]

Relation between MPL and APL edit

The average product of labor (APL) is the total product of labor divided by the number of units of labor employed, or Q/L.[2] The average product of labor is a common measure of labor productivity.[4][5] The APL curve is shaped like an inverted “u”. At low production levels the APL tends to increase as additional labor is added. The primary reason for the increase is specialization and division of labor.[6] At the point the APL reaches its maximum value APL equals the MPL.[7] Beyond this point the APL falls.

During the early stages of production MPL is greater than APL. When the MPL is above the APL the APL will increase. Eventually the MPL reaches it maximum value at the point of diminishing returns. Beyond this point MPL will decrease. However, at the point of diminishing returns the MPL is still above the APL and APL will continue to increase until MPL equals APL. When MPL is below APL, APL will decrease.

Graphically, the APL curve can be derived from the total product curve by drawing secants from the origin that intersect (cut) the total product curve. The slope of the secant line equals the average product of labor, where the slope = dQ/dL.[6] The slope of the curve at each intersection marks a point on the average product curve. The slope increases until the line reaches a point of tangency with the total product curve. This point marks the maximum average product of labor. It also marks the point where MPL (which is the slope of the total product curve)[8] equals the APL (the slope of the secant).[9] Beyond this point the slope of the secants become progressively smaller as APL declines. The MPL curve intersects the APL curve from above at the maximum point of the APL curve. Thereafter, the MPL curve is below the APL curve.

Diminishing marginal returns edit

The falling MPL is due to the law of diminishing marginal returns. The law states, "as units of one input are added (with all other inputs held constant) a point will be reached where the resulting additions to output will begin to decrease; that is marginal product will decline."[10] The law of diminishing marginal returns applies regardless of whether the production function exhibits increasing, decreasing, or constant returns to scale. The key factor is that the variable input is being changed while all other factors of production are being held constant. Under such circumstances diminishing marginal returns are inevitable at some level of production.[11]

Diminishing marginal returns differs from diminishing returns. Diminishing marginal returns means that the marginal product of the variable input is falling. Diminishing returns occur when the marginal product of the variable input is negative. That is when a unit increase in the variable input causes total product to fall. At the point that diminishing returns begin the MPL is zero.[12]

MPL, MRPL and profit maximization edit

The general rule is that a firm maximizes profit by producing that quantity of output where marginal revenue equals marginal costs. The profit maximization issue can also be approached from the input side. That is, what is the profit maximizing usage of the variable input? To maximize profits the firm should increase usage "up to the point where the input’s marginal revenue product equals its marginal costs". So, mathematically the profit maximizing rule is MRPL = MCL.[10] The marginal profit per unit of labor equals the marginal revenue product of labor minus the marginal cost of labor or MπL = MRPL − MCLA firm maximizes profits where MπL = 0.

The marginal revenue product is the change in total revenue per unit change in the variable input assume labor.[10] That is, MRPL = ∆TR/∆L. MRPL is the product of marginal revenue and the marginal product of labor or MRPL = MR × MPL.

  • Derivation:
MR = ∆TR/∆Q
MPL = ∆Q/∆L
MRPL = MR × MPL = (∆TR/∆Q) × (∆Q/∆L) = ∆TR/∆L

Example edit

  • Assume that the production function is  [10]
  •  
  • Output price is $40 per unit.
 
 
 
  (Profit Max Rule)
 
 
 
44.625 is the profit maximizing number of workers.
 
 
 
 
  • Thus, the profit maximizing output is 2024.86 units, units might be given in thousands. Therefore, quantity must not be discrete.
  • And the profit is
 
  (Actually marginal cost of labor is wages paid for each worker. Therefore we get total cost if we multiply it by the quantity of labor not by the quantity of products)
 
  • Some might be confused by the fact that   as intuition would say that labor should be discrete. Remember, however, that labor is actually a time measure as well. Thus, it can be thought of as a worker not working the entire hour.

Marginal productivity ethics edit

In the aftermath of the marginal revolution in economics, a number of economists including John Bates Clark and Thomas Nixon Carver sought to derive an ethical theory of income distribution based on the idea that workers were morally entitled to receive a wage exactly equal to their marginal product. In the 20th century, marginal productivity ethics found few supporters among economists, being criticised not only by egalitarians but by economists associated with the Chicago school such as Frank Knight (in The Ethics of Competition) and the Austrian School, such as Leland Yeager.[13][failed verification] However, marginal productivity ethics were defended by George Stigler.

A Review of Economics and Economic Methodology argues against pay to their marginal product to pay equal to the amount of their labor input.[14] This is known as the Labor theory of value. Marx characterizes the value of labor as a relationship between the person and things and how the perceived exchange of products is viewed socially.[15] Alejandro Valle Baeza and Blanca Gloria Martínez González, Researchers compared productivity levels from countries that pay based on the marginal productivity and labor theory. The found that across countries, marginal productivity is more widely used than labor value, but when they measured productivity based on labor value, "productivity changes not only because of savings in both living labor and means of production, but it is also modified by changes in the productivity of these means of production."[15]

See also edit

Footnotes edit

  1. ^ O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Prentice Hall. p. 108. ISBN 0-13-063085-3.
  2. ^ a b Perloff, J., Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus, Pearson 2008. p. 173.
  3. ^ Pindyck, R. and D. Rubinfeld, Microeconomics, 5th ed. Prentice-Hall 2001.
  4. ^ Nicholson, W. and C. Snyder, Intermediate Microeconomics, Thomson 2007, p. 215.
  5. ^ Nicholson, W., Microeconomic Theory, 9th ed. Thomson 2005, p. 185.
  6. ^ a b Perloff, J., Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus, Pearson 2008, p. 176.
  7. ^ Binger, B. and E. Hoffman, Microeconomics with Calculus, 2nd ed. Addison-Wesley 1998, p. 253.
  8. ^ Krugman, Paul; Robin Wells (2010). Microeconomics. Worth Publishers. p. 306. ISBN 978-1429277914.
  9. ^ Perloff, J: Microeconomics Theory & Applications with Calculus page 177. Pearson 2008.
  10. ^ a b c d Samuelson, W. and S. Marks, Managerial Economics, 4th ed. Wiley 2003, p. 227.
  11. ^ Hal Varian, Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd ed. Norton 1992.
  12. ^ Perloff, J., Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus, Pearson 2008, p. 178.
  13. ^ "Can a Liberal Be an Equalitarian? Leland B. Yeager - Toward Liberty: Essays in Honor of Ludwig von Mises, vol. 2". Online Library of Liberty. 1971-09-29. Retrieved 2013-03-29.
  14. ^ Ellerman, David (2021), "Marginal Productivity Theory", Putting Jurisprudence Back Into Economics, Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 89–118, doi:10.1007/978-3-030-76096-0_5, ISBN 978-3-030-76095-3, retrieved 2021-11-07
  15. ^ a b Sen, Amartya (1978). "On the labour theory of value: some methodological issues". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 2 (2): 175–190. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035384. ISSN 0309-166X. JSTOR 23596406.

References edit

  • Binger, B. and E. Hoffman, Microeconomics with Calculus, 2nd ed. Addison-Wesley 1998, ISBN 0-321-01225-9
  • Krugman, Paul, and Robin Wells (2009), Microeconomics 2d ed. Worth Publishers, ISBN 978-1429277914
  • Nicholson, W., Microeconomic Theory, 9th ed. Thomson 2005.
  • Nicholson, W. and C. Snyder, Intermediate Microeconomics, Thomson 2007, ISBN 0-324-31968-1
  • Perloff, J., Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus, Pearson 2008, ISBN 978-0-321-27794-7
  • Pindyck, R. and D. Rubinfeld, Microeconomics, 5th ed. Prentice-Hall 2001. ISBN 0-13-019673-8
  • Samuelson, W. and S. Marks, Managerial Economics, 4th ed. Wiley 2003.
  • Varian, Hal, Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd ed. Norton 1992.
  • Baeza, A. V., & González, B. G. M. (2020). Labor Productivity and Marxist Theory of Labor Value. World Review of Political Economy, 11(3), 377–387. https://doi.org/10.13169/worlrevipoliecon.11.3.0377
  • Sen, A. (1978). On the labour theory of value: some methodological issues. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 2(2), 175–190. JSTOR 23596406
  • Ellerman, D. (2017). Reframing the Labor Question: On Marginal Productivity Theory and the Labor Theory of Property. Review of Economics and Economic Methodology, 2(1), 9–44. https://doi-org.ezproxy.uta.edu/http://www.reemslovenia.com/

marginal, product, labor, economics, marginal, product, labor, change, output, that, results, from, employing, added, unit, labor, feature, production, function, depends, amounts, physical, capital, labor, already, contents, definition, examples, marginal, cos. In economics the marginal product of labor MPL is the change in output that results from employing an added unit of labor 1 It is a feature of the production function and depends on the amounts of physical capital and labor already in use Contents 1 Definition 2 Examples 3 Marginal costs 4 Relation between MPL and APL 5 Diminishing marginal returns 6 MPL MRPL and profit maximization 6 1 Example 7 Marginal productivity ethics 8 See also 9 Footnotes 10 ReferencesDefinition editThe marginal product of a factor of production is generally defined as the change in output resulting from a unit or infinitesimal change in the quantity of that factor used holding all other input usages in the production process constant The marginal product of labor is then the change in output Y per unit change in labor L In discrete terms the marginal product of labor is D Y D L displaystyle frac Delta Y Delta L nbsp In continuous terms the MPL is the first derivative of the production function Y L displaystyle frac partial Y partial L nbsp 2 Graphically the MPL is the slope of the production function Examples edit nbsp Marginal product of labor tableThere is a factory which produces toys When there are no workers in the factory no toys are produced When there is one worker in the factory six toys are produced per hour When there are two workers in the factory eleven toys are produced per hour There is a marginal product of labor of five when there are two workers in the factory compared to one When the marginal product of labor is increasing this is called increasing marginal returns However as the number of workers increases the marginal product of labor may not increase indefinitely When not scaled properly the marginal product of labor may go down when the number of employees goes up creating a situation known as diminishing marginal returns When the marginal product of labor becomes negative it is known as negative marginal returns Marginal costs editThe marginal product of labor is directly related to costs of production Costs are divided between fixed and variable costs Fixed costs are costs that relate to the fixed input capital or rK where r is the rental cost of capital and K is the quantity of capital Variable costs VC are the costs of the variable input labor or wL where w is the wage rate and L is the amount of labor employed Thus VC wL Marginal cost MC is the change in total cost per unit change in output or C Q In the short run production can be varied only by changing the variable input Thus only variable costs change as output increases C VC wL Marginal cost is Lw Q Now L Q is the reciprocal of the marginal product of labor Q L Therefore marginal cost is simply the wage rate w divided by the marginal product of labor M C D V C D Q D V C w D L D L D Q displaystyle begin aligned MC amp frac Delta VC Delta Q 6pt Delta VC amp w Delta L 6pt amp Delta L Delta Q end aligned nbsp the change in quantity of labor to effect a one unit change in output 1 M P L displaystyle 1 MP L nbsp Therefore M C w M P L displaystyle MC w MP L nbsp Thus if the marginal product of labor is rising then marginal costs will be falling and if the marginal product of labor is falling marginal costs will be rising assuming a constant wage rate 3 Relation between MPL and APL editThe average product of labor APL is the total product of labor divided by the number of units of labor employed or Q L 2 The average product of labor is a common measure of labor productivity 4 5 The APL curve is shaped like an inverted u At low production levels the APL tends to increase as additional labor is added The primary reason for the increase is specialization and division of labor 6 At the point the APL reaches its maximum value APL equals the MPL 7 Beyond this point the APL falls During the early stages of production MPL is greater than APL When the MPL is above the APL the APL will increase Eventually the MPL reaches it maximum value at the point of diminishing returns Beyond this point MPL will decrease However at the point of diminishing returns the MPL is still above the APL and APL will continue to increase until MPL equals APL When MPL is below APL APL will decrease Graphically the APL curve can be derived from the total product curve by drawing secants from the origin that intersect cut the total product curve The slope of the secant line equals the average product of labor where the slope dQ dL 6 The slope of the curve at each intersection marks a point on the average product curve The slope increases until the line reaches a point of tangency with the total product curve This point marks the maximum average product of labor It also marks the point where MPL which is the slope of the total product curve 8 equals the APL the slope of the secant 9 Beyond this point the slope of the secants become progressively smaller as APL declines The MPL curve intersects the APL curve from above at the maximum point of the APL curve Thereafter the MPL curve is below the APL curve Diminishing marginal returns editThe falling MPL is due to the law of diminishing marginal returns The law states as units of one input are added with all other inputs held constant a point will be reached where the resulting additions to output will begin to decrease that is marginal product will decline 10 The law of diminishing marginal returns applies regardless of whether the production function exhibits increasing decreasing or constant returns to scale The key factor is that the variable input is being changed while all other factors of production are being held constant Under such circumstances diminishing marginal returns are inevitable at some level of production 11 Diminishing marginal returns differs from diminishing returns Diminishing marginal returns means that the marginal product of the variable input is falling Diminishing returns occur when the marginal product of the variable input is negative That is when a unit increase in the variable input causes total product to fall At the point that diminishing returns begin the MPL is zero 12 MPL MRPL and profit maximization editThe general rule is that a firm maximizes profit by producing that quantity of output where marginal revenue equals marginal costs The profit maximization issue can also be approached from the input side That is what is the profit maximizing usage of the variable input To maximize profits the firm should increase usage up to the point where the input s marginal revenue product equals its marginal costs So mathematically the profit maximizing rule is MRPL MCL 10 The marginal profit per unit of labor equals the marginal revenue product of labor minus the marginal cost of labor or Mp L MRPL MCLA firm maximizes profits where Mp L 0 The marginal revenue product is the change in total revenue per unit change in the variable input assume labor 10 That is MRPL TR L MRPL is the product of marginal revenue and the marginal product of labor or MRPL MR MPL Derivation MR TR Q MPL Q L MRPL MR MPL TR Q Q L TR LExample edit Assume that the production function is Q 90 L L 2 displaystyle Q 90L L 2 nbsp 10 M C L 30 displaystyle MC L 30 nbsp Output price is 40 per unit M P L 90 2 L displaystyle MP L 90 2L nbsp M R P L 40 90 2 L displaystyle MRP L 40 90 2L nbsp M R P L 3600 80 L displaystyle MRP L 3600 80L nbsp M R P L M C L displaystyle MRP L MC L nbsp Profit Max Rule 3600 80 L 30 displaystyle 3600 80L 30 nbsp 3570 80 L displaystyle 3570 80L nbsp L 44 625 displaystyle L 44 625 nbsp 44 625 is the profit maximizing number of workers Q 90 L L 2 displaystyle Q 90L L 2 nbsp Q 90 44 625 44 625 2 displaystyle Q 90 44 625 44 625 2 nbsp Q 4016 25 1991 39 displaystyle Q 4016 25 1991 39 nbsp Q 2024 86 displaystyle Q 2024 86 nbsp Thus the profit maximizing output is 2024 86 units units might be given in thousands Therefore quantity must not be discrete And the profit isP T R T C displaystyle Pi TR TC nbsp T C M C L L displaystyle TC MC L cdot L nbsp Actually marginal cost of labor is wages paid for each worker Therefore we get total cost if we multiply it by the quantity of labor not by the quantity of products P 40 2024 86 30 44 625 80994 4 1338 75 79655 65 displaystyle Pi 40 2024 86 30 44 625 80994 4 1338 75 79655 65 nbsp Some might be confused by the fact that L 44 625 displaystyle L 44 625 nbsp as intuition would say that labor should be discrete Remember however that labor is actually a time measure as well Thus it can be thought of as a worker not working the entire hour Marginal productivity ethics editIn the aftermath of the marginal revolution in economics a number of economists including John Bates Clark and Thomas Nixon Carver sought to derive an ethical theory of income distribution based on the idea that workers were morally entitled to receive a wage exactly equal to their marginal product In the 20th century marginal productivity ethics found few supporters among economists being criticised not only by egalitarians but by economists associated with the Chicago school such as Frank Knight in The Ethics of Competition and the Austrian School such as Leland Yeager 13 failed verification However marginal productivity ethics were defended by George Stigler A Review of Economics and Economic Methodology argues against pay to their marginal product to pay equal to the amount of their labor input 14 This is known as the Labor theory of value Marx characterizes the value of labor as a relationship between the person and things and how the perceived exchange of products is viewed socially 15 Alejandro Valle Baeza and Blanca Gloria Martinez Gonzalez Researchers compared productivity levels from countries that pay based on the marginal productivity and labor theory The found that across countries marginal productivity is more widely used than labor value but when they measured productivity based on labor value productivity changes not only because of savings in both living labor and means of production but it is also modified by changes in the productivity of these means of production 15 See also edit nbsp Business and economics portalMarginal product of capitalFootnotes edit O Sullivan Arthur Sheffrin Steven M 2003 Economics Principles in Action Upper Saddle River NJ Pearson Prentice Hall p 108 ISBN 0 13 063085 3 a b Perloff J Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus Pearson 2008 p 173 Pindyck R and D Rubinfeld Microeconomics 5th ed Prentice Hall 2001 Nicholson W and C Snyder Intermediate Microeconomics Thomson 2007 p 215 Nicholson W Microeconomic Theory 9th ed Thomson 2005 p 185 a b Perloff J Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus Pearson 2008 p 176 Binger B and E Hoffman Microeconomics with Calculus 2nd ed Addison Wesley 1998 p 253 Krugman Paul Robin Wells 2010 Microeconomics Worth Publishers p 306 ISBN 978 1429277914 Perloff J Microeconomics Theory amp Applications with Calculus page 177 Pearson 2008 a b c d Samuelson W and S Marks Managerial Economics 4th ed Wiley 2003 p 227 Hal Varian Microeconomic Analysis 3rd ed Norton 1992 Perloff J Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus Pearson 2008 p 178 Can a Liberal Be an Equalitarian Leland B Yeager Toward Liberty Essays in Honor of Ludwig von Mises vol 2 Online Library of Liberty 1971 09 29 Retrieved 2013 03 29 Ellerman David 2021 Marginal Productivity Theory Putting Jurisprudence Back Into Economics Cham Springer International Publishing pp 89 118 doi 10 1007 978 3 030 76096 0 5 ISBN 978 3 030 76095 3 retrieved 2021 11 07 a b Sen Amartya 1978 On the labour theory of value some methodological issues Cambridge Journal of Economics 2 2 175 190 doi 10 1093 oxfordjournals cje a035384 ISSN 0309 166X JSTOR 23596406 References editBinger B and E Hoffman Microeconomics with Calculus 2nd ed Addison Wesley 1998 ISBN 0 321 01225 9 Krugman Paul and Robin Wells 2009 Microeconomics 2d ed Worth Publishers ISBN 978 1429277914 Nicholson W Microeconomic Theory 9th ed Thomson 2005 Nicholson W and C Snyder Intermediate Microeconomics Thomson 2007 ISBN 0 324 31968 1 Perloff J Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus Pearson 2008 ISBN 978 0 321 27794 7 Pindyck R and D Rubinfeld Microeconomics 5th ed Prentice Hall 2001 ISBN 0 13 019673 8 Samuelson W and S Marks Managerial Economics 4th ed Wiley 2003 Varian Hal Microeconomic Analysis 3rd ed Norton 1992 Baeza A V amp Gonzalez B G M 2020 Labor Productivity and Marxist Theory of Labor Value World Review of Political Economy 11 3 377 387 https doi org 10 13169 worlrevipoliecon 11 3 0377 Sen A 1978 On the labour theory of value some methodological issues Cambridge Journal of Economics 2 2 175 190 JSTOR 23596406 Ellerman D 2017 Reframing the Labor Question On Marginal Productivity Theory and the Labor Theory of Property Review of Economics and Economic Methodology 2 1 9 44 https doi org ezproxy uta edu http www reemslovenia com Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Marginal product of labor amp oldid 1187510811, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.