fbpx
Wikipedia

Pollock v. Farmers' Loan & Trust Co.

Pollock v. Farmers' Loan & Trust Company, 157 U.S. 429 (1895), affirmed on rehearing, 158 U.S. 601 (1895), was a landmark case of the Supreme Court of the United States. In a 5-4 decision, the Supreme Court struck down the income tax imposed by the Wilson–Gorman Tariff Act for being an unapportioned direct tax. The decision was superseded in 1913 by the Sixteenth Amendment to the United States Constitution, which allows Congress to levy income taxes without apportioning them among the states.

Pollock v. Farmers' Loan & Trust Co.
Argued March 7–8, 11–13, 1895
Decided April 8, 1895
Full case nameCharles Pollock v. Farmers' Loan and Trust Company
Citations157 U.S. 429 (more)
15 S. Ct. 673; 39 L. Ed. 759; 1895 U.S. LEXIS 2215; 3 A.F.T.R. (P-H) 2557
Case history
PriorAppeal from the Circuit Court of the United States for the Southern District of New York
Holding
The unapportioned income taxes on interest, dividends, and rents imposed by the Income Tax Act of 1894 were, in effect, direct taxes, and were unconstitutional because they violated the rule that direct taxes be apportioned.
Court membership
Chief Justice
Melville Fuller
Associate Justices
Stephen J. Field · John M. Harlan
Horace Gray · David J. Brewer
Henry B. Brown · George Shiras Jr.
Howell E. Jackson · Edward D. White
Case opinions
MajorityFuller, joined by Field, Gray, Brewer, Shiras
ConcurrenceField
DissentWhite, joined by Harlan
DissentHarlan
DissentBrown
DissentJackson
Superseded by
U.S. Const. amend. XVI (in part)
Overruled by
South Carolina v. Baker, 485 U.S. 505 (1988) (in part)

The US Congress had introduced an income tax during the American Civil War, but the tax was repealed in 1872. In 1894, Congress passed the Wilson-Gorman Tariff Act, which lowered tariff rates and made up for some of the lost revenue by introducing taxes on income, corporate profits, gifts, and inheritances. Chief Justice Melville Fuller's majority opinion in Pollock held that a federal tax on income derived from property was unconstitutional when it was not apportioned among the states according to representation in the House of Representatives. Fuller also held that federal taxation of interest earned on certain state bonds violated the doctrine of intergovernmental tax immunity. In one dissent, Associate Justice Henry Billings Brown wrote that the majority opinion "involves nothing less than the surrender of the taxing power to the moneyed class."

The Court's decision in Pollock was unpopular but effectively prevented Congress from implementing another income tax over the next two decades since the apportionment requirements were widely regarded as unworkable. The ratification of the Sixteenth Amendment essentially overturned the key holding in Pollock, and Congress established a new federal income tax in the Revenue Act of 1913. The Court's holding regarding the taxation of interest income on certain bonds was later overruled in the 1988 case of South Carolina v. Baker.

Before Pollock edit

Early income tax edit

In order to help pay for its war effort in the American Civil War, Congress imposed the first federal income tax in U.S. history through passage of the Revenue Act of 1861.[1] The act created a flat tax of three percent on incomes above $800 ($27,100 in current dollar terms). The taxation of income reflected the increasing amount of wealth held in stocks and bonds, rather than property, which the federal government had taxed in the past.[2] Congress later further raised taxes, and by the end of the war, the income tax constituted about one fifth of the revenue of the federal government.[3] The federal income tax remained in effect until its repeal in 1872.[4] The constitutionality of the federal income tax was later upheld by the Supreme Court in the 1881 case of Springer v. United States.

The Socialist Labor Party advocated a graduated income tax in 1887.[5] The Populist Party "demanded a graduated income tax" in its 1892 platform.[6]

Wilson-Gorman Tariff Act edit

After winning control of Congress and the presidency in the 1892 elections, the Democratic Party made tariff reduction a key priority.[7] President Grover Cleveland and his congressional allies proposed a bill that affected moderate downward revisions in the tariff, especially on raw materials.[8] The shortfall in revenue was to be made up by an income tax of two percent on income above $4,000,[8] equivalent to $136,000 today.[9] Corporate profits, gifts, and inheritances would also be taxed at a two percent rate.[10] The bill would restore the federal income tax for the first time since the 1870s; supporters of the income tax believed that it would help reduce income inequality and shift the burden of taxation to the wealthy.[11]

The Cleveland administration was ambivalent about the income tax but included it in the proposed bill in large part because of the efforts of Congressmen William Jennings Bryan and Benton McMillin.[12] Despite strong conservative opposition to the income tax in the US Senate, it remained a component of the final tariff bill, partly because many members of Congress believed that the US Supreme Court would eventually declare the tax to be unconstitutional.[13] In August 1894, the bill became law as the Wilson–Gorman Tariff Act.

Plaintiff edit

In compliance with the Act, the New York-based Farmers' Loan & Trust Company announced to its shareholders that it would not only pay the tax but also provide, to the collector of internal revenue in the Department of the Treasury, the names of all people for whom the company was acting and thus were liable for being taxed under the Act.

Charles Pollock was a Massachusetts citizen who owned only ten shares of stock in the Farmers' Loan & Trust Company. He sued the company to prevent the company from paying the tax. He lost in the lower courts but finally appealed to the United States Supreme Court, which agreed to hear the case.

Arguing for Pollock was Joseph Hodges Choate, one of the most eminent Wall Street lawyers of his day.[14]

Decision edit

 
The Fuller Court.

The Court handed down its decision on April 8, 1895, with Chief Justice Melville Fuller delivering the opinion of the Court. He ruled in Pollock's favor by stating that the taxes levied by the Wilson-Gorman Act on income from property were unconstitutional. The Court treated the tax on income from property as a direct tax. The Constitution of the United States then said that such direct taxes were required to be imposed in proportion to the states' population. The tax in question had not been apportioned and so was invalid. As Chief Justice Fuller stated:

First. We adhere to the opinion already announced—that, taxes on real estate being indisputably direct taxes, taxes on the rents or income of real estate are equally direct taxes.

Second. We are of opinion that taxes on personal property, or on the income of personal property, are likewise direct taxes.

Third. The tax imposed by sections 27 to 37, inclusive, of the act of 1894, so far as it falls on the income of real estate, and of personal property, being a direct tax, within the meaning of the constitution, and therefore unconstitutional and void, because not apportioned according to representation, all those sections, constituting one entire scheme of taxation, are necessarily invalid.

The decrees hereinbefore entered in this court will be vacated. The decrees below will be reversed, and the cases remanded, with instructions to grant the relief prayed.[15]

The Supreme Court did not rule that all income taxes were direct taxes. Instead, the Court held that although generally income taxes are indirect taxes (excises) authorized by the United States Constitution in Article 1, Section 8, Clause 1, taxes on interest, dividends, and rents in the 1894 Act had a profound effect on the underlying assets. The Court ruled that the tax on dividends, interest, and rent should be viewed as a direct tax, as they fell on the property itself, rather than as an indirect tax. Direct taxes were required to follow the rule of apportionment found in Article 1, Section 2, Clause 3. The rule of apportionment requires the amount of a direct tax collected to be divided by the number of members in the United States House of Representatives, with the quotient then multiplied by the number of representatives each state has to determine each state's share of the tax that it then needs to lay and collect, through its own taxing authority.

A separate holding by the Court in Pollock, that federal taxation of interest earned on certain state bonds violated the doctrine of intergovernmental tax immunity, was declared by the U.S. Supreme Court in 1988 to have been "effectively overruled by subsequent case law" (see South Carolina v. Baker).

Dissent edit

Justices John Marshall Harlan, Howell Edmunds Jackson, Edward Douglass White, and Henry Billings Brown dissented from the majority opinion. Justice White argued:

It is, I submit, greatly to be deplored that after more than 100 years of our national existence, after the government has withstood the strain of foreign wars and the dread ordeal of civil strife, and its people have become united and powerful, this court should consider itself compelled to go back to a long repudiated and rejected theory of the constitution, by which the government is deprived of an inherent attribute of its being—a necessary power of taxation.[16]

In his dissent, Justice Brown wrote:

The decision involves nothing less than the surrender of the taxing power to the moneyed class. By resuscitating an argument that was exploded in the Hylton Case, and has lain practically dormant for a hundred years, it is made to do duty in nullifying, not this law alone, but every similar law that is not based upon an impossible theory of apportionment. Even the spectre of socialism is conjured up to frighten Congress from laying taxes upon the people in proportion to their ability to pay them.[17]

Subsequent history edit

In a nation in which the federal government was beginning its battle against monopolies and trusts, and the great bulk of wealth was concentrated in the hands of a few, the decision in Pollock was unpopular, much like the decision in United States v. E. C. Knight Co., 156 U.S. 1 (1895) of the same year. The following year, the Democratic Party, which had grabbed hold of the Populist movement, included an income tax plank in its election platform.[citation needed] Nonetheless, in the years after Pollock, Congress did not implement another federal income tax, partly because many Congressmen feared that any tax would be struck down by the Supreme Court.[18] Few considered attempting to impose an apportioned income tax since such a tax was widely regarded as unworkable.[19] Justice Harlan had predicted that in his dissent in Pollock:

When, therefore, this court adjudges, as it does now adjudge, that Congress cannot impose a duty or tax upon personal property, or upon income arising either from rents of real estate or from personal property, including invested personal property, bonds, stocks, and investments of all kinds, except by apportioning the sum to be so raised among the States according to population, it practically decides that, without an amendment of the Constitution—two-thirds of both Houses of Congress and three-fourths of the States concurring—such property and incomes can never be made to contribute to the support of the national government.[20]

Subsequent court treatments of Pollock and the Sixteenth Amendment edit

Nebraska Republican Senator Norris Brown publicly decried the Court's decision in Pollock and proposed a constitutional amendment to remove the requirement that certain income taxes to be apportioned among the states by population. Brown's proposal would be ratified in 1913 as the Sixteenth Amendment.[21][22] The Sixteenth Amendment removed the requirement for those income taxes deemed to be direct in substance (such as taxes on income from property) to be apportioned among the states according to population. Thus, the effect of Pollock has indeed been overturned by the Sixteenth Amendment.[21][23][24][25][26] The Revenue Act of 1913, which greatly lowered tariffs and implemented a federal income tax, was enacted shortly after the Sixteenth Amendment was ratified.[27]

Three years after ratification of the Sixteenth Amendment, the United States Supreme Court rendered its decision in the case of Brushaber v. Union Pacific Railroad. In Brushaber, the Court reviewed the history of the dichotomy between excises (indirect taxes) and direct taxes. The Court noted that the 1913 Income Tax Act was written as an indirect tax and did not violate the rule of uniformity. Thus, it was not written as a direct tax and was not subject to the rule of apportionment. The Court summarized what it had decided in Pollock and then went on to state the effect of the Sixteenth Amendment with respect to income taxes:

[T]he command of the amendment that all income taxes shall not be subject to the rule of apportionment by a consideration of the source from which the taxed income may be derived forbids the application to such taxes of the rule applied in the Pollock case by which alone such taxes were removed from the great class of excises, duties, and imposts subject to the rule of uniformity and were placed under the other or direct class.[28]

The Court in Brushaber also noted that before Pollock, taxes on income from professions, trades, employments, or vocations were excises. They were indirect in both form and substance and therefore had never been apportioned and thus they were entitled to be so enforced afterwards.[29]

In contrast, with respect to taxes on income from property, the Pollock decision had disregarded form and considered substance alone. Justice White's decision in Brushaber shows how the Sixteenth Amendment was written to prevent consideration of the direct effects of any income tax laid by Congress.

The Supreme Court in Stanton v. Baltic Mining Co. added that the "Sixteenth Amendment conferred no new power of taxation but simply prohibited the previous complete and plenary power of income taxation possessed by Congress from the beginning from being taken out of the category of indirect taxation to which it inherently belonged." 240 U.S. 112 (1916).[30]

That effect was reaffirmed in Bowers v. Kerbaugh-Empire Co., 271 U.S. 170 (1926), in which the Supreme Court reviewed Pollock, the Corporation Excise Tax Act of 1909, and the Sixteenth Amendment. The Court concluded, "It was not the purpose or effect of that amendment to bring any new subject within the taxing power. Congress already had power to tax all incomes."

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Joseph A. Hill, "The Civil War Income Tax," Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol. 8, No. 4 (Jul., 1894), pp. 416–452 in JSTOR; appendix in JSTOR
  2. ^ Weisman (2002), pp. 30–35.
  3. ^ Pollack, Sheldon D. (2014). "The First National Income Tax, 1861–1872" (PDF). Tax Lawyer. 67 (2).
  4. ^ Weisman (2002), pp. 99–101.
  5. ^ Socialist Labor Party Platform
  6. ^ Populist Party Platform, 1892
  7. ^ Weisman, 120, 131
  8. ^ a b Nevins, 564–566; Jeffers, 285–287
  9. ^ 1634–1699: McCusker, J. J. (1997). How Much Is That in Real Money? A Historical Price Index for Use as a Deflator of Money Values in the Economy of the United States: Addenda et Corrigenda (PDF). American Antiquarian Society. 1700–1799: McCusker, J. J. (1992). How Much Is That in Real Money? A Historical Price Index for Use as a Deflator of Money Values in the Economy of the United States (PDF). American Antiquarian Society. 1800–present: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. "Consumer Price Index (estimate) 1800–". Retrieved February 29, 2024.
  10. ^ Welch, 132–133
  11. ^ Weisman, 122–124, 137–139.
  12. ^ Weisman, 132–133
  13. ^ Weisman, 144–145
  14. ^ Irons, Peter. A People's History of the Supreme Court. New York, Penguin, 1999, p. 244.
  15. ^ 158 U.S. 601, 638
  16. ^ 158 U.S. 638
  17. ^ Irons, p. 245.
  18. ^ Weisman 2002, p. 177
  19. ^ Jensen, Erik M. (2014). "DID THE SIXTEENTH AMENDMENT EVER MATTER? DOES IT MATTER TODAY?". Northwestern University Law Review. 108 (3): 804, 809–810.
  20. ^ Harlan dissent to Pollock decision
  21. ^ a b Bittker, Boris I. (1987). "Constitutional Limits on the Taxing Power of the Federal Government". The Tax Lawyer. 41 (1): 3. ISSN 0890-4898. (Pollock case "was in effect reversed by the sixteenth amendment").
  22. ^ "The Sixteenth Amendment to the Constitution overruled Pollock [....]" Graf v. Commissioner, 44 T.C.M. (CCH) 66, TC Memo. 1982-317, CCH December 39,080(M) (1982).
  23. ^ William D. Andrews, Basic Federal Income Taxation, p. 2, Little, Brown and Company (3d ed. 1985) ("In 1913 the Sixteenth Amendment to the Constitution was adopted, overrruling Pollock.").
  24. ^ Calvin H. Johnson, "The Constitutional Meaning of 'Apportionment of Direct Taxes'", 80 Tax Notes 591 (Aug. 3, 1998) ("Pollock should also be understood as reversed in full by the Sixteenth Amendment....")
  25. ^ Sheldon D. Pollack, "Origins of the Modern Income Tax, 1894-1913," 66 Tax Lawyer 295, 323-324, Winter 2013 (Amer. Bar Ass'n) ("...the Sixteenth Amendment to the Constitution was duly ratified as of February 3, 1913. With that, the Pollock decision was overturned, restoring the status quo ante....) (footnote omitted).
  26. ^ In 2012, the U.S. Supreme Court stated: "In 1895, we expanded our interpretation [of the term direct tax] to include taxes on personal property and income from personal property, in the course of striking down aspects of the federal income tax. Pollock v. Farmers’ Loan & Trust Co., 158 U. S. 601, 618 (1895). That result was overturned by the Sixteenth Amendment [...]". National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius, no. 11-393; no. 11-398; no. 11-400 (p. 41, slip opinion, U.S. Supreme Court, June 28, 2012).
  27. ^ Weisman 2002, pp. 230–232, 278–282
  28. ^ 240 U.S. 1 18-19 (1916).
  29. ^ FindLaw for Legal Professionals - Case Law, Federal and State Resources, Forms, and Code
  30. ^ Howard Zaritsky, Legislative Attorney American Law Division, "Some Constitutional Questions Regarding The Federal Income Tax Laws" Report No. 79-131 A, (Congressional Research Service Report for Congress) May 25, 1979.

Further reading edit

  • Jones, Francis R. (1895). "Pollock v. Farmers' Loan and Trust Company". Harvard Law Review. 9 (3): 198–211. doi:10.2307/1321669. JSTOR 1321669.
  • Weisman, Steven R. (2002). The Great Tax Wars: Lincoln to Wilson-The Fierce Battles over Money That Transformed the Nation. Simon & Schuster. ISBN 0-684-85068-0.
  • Welch, Richard E. Jr. The Presidencies of Grover Cleveland (1988) ISBN 0-7006-0355-7

External links edit

  •   Works related to Pollock v. Farmers' Loan and Trust Company at Wikisource
  • Text of Pollock v. Farmers' Loan & Trust Company, 157 U.S. 429 (1895) is available from: Cornell  CourtListener  Google Scholar  Justia  Library of Congress  OpenJurist  Oyez (oral argument audio) 

pollock, farmers, loan, trust, pollock, farmers, loan, trust, company, 1895, affirmed, rehearing, 1895, landmark, case, supreme, court, united, states, decision, supreme, court, struck, down, income, imposed, wilson, gorman, tariff, being, unapportioned, direc. Pollock v Farmers Loan amp Trust Company 157 U S 429 1895 affirmed on rehearing 158 U S 601 1895 was a landmark case of the Supreme Court of the United States In a 5 4 decision the Supreme Court struck down the income tax imposed by the Wilson Gorman Tariff Act for being an unapportioned direct tax The decision was superseded in 1913 by the Sixteenth Amendment to the United States Constitution which allows Congress to levy income taxes without apportioning them among the states Pollock v Farmers Loan amp Trust Co Supreme Court of the United StatesArgued March 7 8 11 13 1895Decided April 8 1895Full case nameCharles Pollock v Farmers Loan and Trust CompanyCitations157 U S 429 more 15 S Ct 673 39 L Ed 759 1895 U S LEXIS 2215 3 A F T R P H 2557Case historyPriorAppeal from the Circuit Court of the United States for the Southern District of New YorkHoldingThe unapportioned income taxes on interest dividends and rents imposed by the Income Tax Act of 1894 were in effect direct taxes and were unconstitutional because they violated the rule that direct taxes be apportioned Court membershipChief Justice Melville Fuller Associate Justices Stephen J Field John M HarlanHorace Gray David J BrewerHenry B Brown George Shiras Jr Howell E Jackson Edward D WhiteCase opinionsMajorityFuller joined by Field Gray Brewer ShirasConcurrenceFieldDissentWhite joined by HarlanDissentHarlanDissentBrownDissentJacksonSuperseded byU S Const amend XVI in part Overruled bySouth Carolina v Baker 485 U S 505 1988 in part The US Congress had introduced an income tax during the American Civil War but the tax was repealed in 1872 In 1894 Congress passed the Wilson Gorman Tariff Act which lowered tariff rates and made up for some of the lost revenue by introducing taxes on income corporate profits gifts and inheritances Chief Justice Melville Fuller s majority opinion in Pollock held that a federal tax on income derived from property was unconstitutional when it was not apportioned among the states according to representation in the House of Representatives Fuller also held that federal taxation of interest earned on certain state bonds violated the doctrine of intergovernmental tax immunity In one dissent Associate Justice Henry Billings Brown wrote that the majority opinion involves nothing less than the surrender of the taxing power to the moneyed class The Court s decision in Pollock was unpopular but effectively prevented Congress from implementing another income tax over the next two decades since the apportionment requirements were widely regarded as unworkable The ratification of the Sixteenth Amendment essentially overturned the key holding in Pollock and Congress established a new federal income tax in the Revenue Act of 1913 The Court s holding regarding the taxation of interest income on certain bonds was later overruled in the 1988 case of South Carolina v Baker Contents 1 Before Pollock 1 1 Early income tax 1 2 Wilson Gorman Tariff Act 2 Plaintiff 3 Decision 3 1 Dissent 4 Subsequent history 4 1 Subsequent court treatments of Pollock and the Sixteenth Amendment 5 See also 6 References 7 Further reading 8 External linksBefore Pollock editEarly income tax edit See also History of taxation in the United States In order to help pay for its war effort in the American Civil War Congress imposed the first federal income tax in U S history through passage of the Revenue Act of 1861 1 The act created a flat tax of three percent on incomes above 800 27 100 in current dollar terms The taxation of income reflected the increasing amount of wealth held in stocks and bonds rather than property which the federal government had taxed in the past 2 Congress later further raised taxes and by the end of the war the income tax constituted about one fifth of the revenue of the federal government 3 The federal income tax remained in effect until its repeal in 1872 4 The constitutionality of the federal income tax was later upheld by the Supreme Court in the 1881 case of Springer v United States The Socialist Labor Party advocated a graduated income tax in 1887 5 The Populist Party demanded a graduated income tax in its 1892 platform 6 Wilson Gorman Tariff Act edit Main article Wilson Gorman Tariff Act See also Presidencies of Grover Cleveland After winning control of Congress and the presidency in the 1892 elections the Democratic Party made tariff reduction a key priority 7 President Grover Cleveland and his congressional allies proposed a bill that affected moderate downward revisions in the tariff especially on raw materials 8 The shortfall in revenue was to be made up by an income tax of two percent on income above 4 000 8 equivalent to 136 000 today 9 Corporate profits gifts and inheritances would also be taxed at a two percent rate 10 The bill would restore the federal income tax for the first time since the 1870s supporters of the income tax believed that it would help reduce income inequality and shift the burden of taxation to the wealthy 11 The Cleveland administration was ambivalent about the income tax but included it in the proposed bill in large part because of the efforts of Congressmen William Jennings Bryan and Benton McMillin 12 Despite strong conservative opposition to the income tax in the US Senate it remained a component of the final tariff bill partly because many members of Congress believed that the US Supreme Court would eventually declare the tax to be unconstitutional 13 In August 1894 the bill became law as the Wilson Gorman Tariff Act Plaintiff editIn compliance with the Act the New York based Farmers Loan amp Trust Company announced to its shareholders that it would not only pay the tax but also provide to the collector of internal revenue in the Department of the Treasury the names of all people for whom the company was acting and thus were liable for being taxed under the Act Charles Pollock was a Massachusetts citizen who owned only ten shares of stock in the Farmers Loan amp Trust Company He sued the company to prevent the company from paying the tax He lost in the lower courts but finally appealed to the United States Supreme Court which agreed to hear the case Arguing for Pollock was Joseph Hodges Choate one of the most eminent Wall Street lawyers of his day 14 Decision edit nbsp The Fuller Court The Court handed down its decision on April 8 1895 with Chief Justice Melville Fuller delivering the opinion of the Court He ruled in Pollock s favor by stating that the taxes levied by the Wilson Gorman Act on income from property were unconstitutional The Court treated the tax on income from property as a direct tax The Constitution of the United States then said that such direct taxes were required to be imposed in proportion to the states population The tax in question had not been apportioned and so was invalid As Chief Justice Fuller stated First We adhere to the opinion already announced that taxes on real estate being indisputably direct taxes taxes on the rents or income of real estate are equally direct taxes Second We are of opinion that taxes on personal property or on the income of personal property are likewise direct taxes Third The tax imposed by sections 27 to 37 inclusive of the act of 1894 so far as it falls on the income of real estate and of personal property being a direct tax within the meaning of the constitution and therefore unconstitutional and void because not apportioned according to representation all those sections constituting one entire scheme of taxation are necessarily invalid The decrees hereinbefore entered in this court will be vacated The decrees below will be reversed and the cases remanded with instructions to grant the relief prayed 15 The Supreme Court did not rule that all income taxes were direct taxes Instead the Court held that although generally income taxes are indirect taxes excises authorized by the United States Constitution in Article 1 Section 8 Clause 1 taxes on interest dividends and rents in the 1894 Act had a profound effect on the underlying assets The Court ruled that the tax on dividends interest and rent should be viewed as a direct tax as they fell on the property itself rather than as an indirect tax Direct taxes were required to follow the rule of apportionment found in Article 1 Section 2 Clause 3 The rule of apportionment requires the amount of a direct tax collected to be divided by the number of members in the United States House of Representatives with the quotient then multiplied by the number of representatives each state has to determine each state s share of the tax that it then needs to lay and collect through its own taxing authority A separate holding by the Court in Pollock that federal taxation of interest earned on certain state bonds violated the doctrine of intergovernmental tax immunity was declared by the U S Supreme Court in 1988 to have been effectively overruled by subsequent case law see South Carolina v Baker Dissent edit Justices John Marshall Harlan Howell Edmunds Jackson Edward Douglass White and Henry Billings Brown dissented from the majority opinion Justice White argued It is I submit greatly to be deplored that after more than 100 years of our national existence after the government has withstood the strain of foreign wars and the dread ordeal of civil strife and its people have become united and powerful this court should consider itself compelled to go back to a long repudiated and rejected theory of the constitution by which the government is deprived of an inherent attribute of its being a necessary power of taxation 16 In his dissent Justice Brown wrote The decision involves nothing less than the surrender of the taxing power to the moneyed class By resuscitating an argument that was exploded in the Hylton Case and has lain practically dormant for a hundred years it is made to do duty in nullifying not this law alone but every similar law that is not based upon an impossible theory of apportionment Even the spectre of socialism is conjured up to frighten Congress from laying taxes upon the people in proportion to their ability to pay them 17 Subsequent history editIn a nation in which the federal government was beginning its battle against monopolies and trusts and the great bulk of wealth was concentrated in the hands of a few the decision in Pollock was unpopular much like the decision in United States v E C Knight Co 156 U S 1 1895 of the same year The following year the Democratic Party which had grabbed hold of the Populist movement included an income tax plank in its election platform citation needed Nonetheless in the years after Pollock Congress did not implement another federal income tax partly because many Congressmen feared that any tax would be struck down by the Supreme Court 18 Few considered attempting to impose an apportioned income tax since such a tax was widely regarded as unworkable 19 Justice Harlan had predicted that in his dissent in Pollock When therefore this court adjudges as it does now adjudge that Congress cannot impose a duty or tax upon personal property or upon income arising either from rents of real estate or from personal property including invested personal property bonds stocks and investments of all kinds except by apportioning the sum to be so raised among the States according to population it practically decides that without an amendment of the Constitution two thirds of both Houses of Congress and three fourths of the States concurring such property and incomes can never be made to contribute to the support of the national government 20 Subsequent court treatments of Pollock and the Sixteenth Amendment edit Further information Sixteenth Amendment to the United States Constitution Nebraska Republican Senator Norris Brown publicly decried the Court s decision in Pollock and proposed a constitutional amendment to remove the requirement that certain income taxes to be apportioned among the states by population Brown s proposal would be ratified in 1913 as the Sixteenth Amendment 21 22 The Sixteenth Amendment removed the requirement for those income taxes deemed to be direct in substance such as taxes on income from property to be apportioned among the states according to population Thus the effect of Pollock has indeed been overturned by the Sixteenth Amendment 21 23 24 25 26 The Revenue Act of 1913 which greatly lowered tariffs and implemented a federal income tax was enacted shortly after the Sixteenth Amendment was ratified 27 Three years after ratification of the Sixteenth Amendment the United States Supreme Court rendered its decision in the case of Brushaber v Union Pacific Railroad In Brushaber the Court reviewed the history of the dichotomy between excises indirect taxes and direct taxes The Court noted that the 1913 Income Tax Act was written as an indirect tax and did not violate the rule of uniformity Thus it was not written as a direct tax and was not subject to the rule of apportionment The Court summarized what it had decided in Pollock and then went on to state the effect of the Sixteenth Amendment with respect to income taxes T he command of the amendment that all income taxes shall not be subject to the rule of apportionment by a consideration of the source from which the taxed income may be derived forbids the application to such taxes of the rule applied in the Pollock case by which alone such taxes were removed from the great class of excises duties and imposts subject to the rule of uniformity and were placed under the other or direct class 28 The Court in Brushaber also noted that before Pollock taxes on income from professions trades employments or vocations were excises They were indirect in both form and substance and therefore had never been apportioned and thus they were entitled to be so enforced afterwards 29 In contrast with respect to taxes on income from property the Pollock decision had disregarded form and considered substance alone Justice White s decision in Brushaber shows how the Sixteenth Amendment was written to prevent consideration of the direct effects of any income tax laid by Congress The Supreme Court in Stanton v Baltic Mining Co added that the Sixteenth Amendment conferred no new power of taxation but simply prohibited the previous complete and plenary power of income taxation possessed by Congress from the beginning from being taken out of the category of indirect taxation to which it inherently belonged 240 U S 112 1916 30 That effect was reaffirmed in Bowers v Kerbaugh Empire Co 271 U S 170 1926 in which the Supreme Court reviewed Pollock the Corporation Excise Tax Act of 1909 and the Sixteenth Amendment The Court concluded It was not the purpose or effect of that amendment to bring any new subject within the taxing power Congress already had power to tax all incomes See also editHylton v United States 3 U S 171 1796 United States v E C Knight Co 156 U S 1 1895 References edit Joseph A Hill The Civil War Income Tax Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol 8 No 4 Jul 1894 pp 416 452 in JSTOR appendix in JSTOR Weisman 2002 pp 30 35 Pollack Sheldon D 2014 The First National Income Tax 1861 1872 PDF Tax Lawyer 67 2 Weisman 2002 pp 99 101 Socialist Labor Party Platform Populist Party Platform 1892 Weisman 120 131 a b Nevins 564 566 Jeffers 285 287 1634 1699 McCusker J J 1997 How Much Is That in Real Money A Historical Price Index for Use as a Deflator of Money Values in the Economy of the United States Addenda et Corrigenda PDF American Antiquarian Society 1700 1799 McCusker J J 1992 How Much Is That in Real Money A Historical Price Index for Use as a Deflator of Money Values in the Economy of the United States PDF American Antiquarian Society 1800 present Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Consumer Price Index estimate 1800 Retrieved February 29 2024 Welch 132 133 Weisman 122 124 137 139 Weisman 132 133 Weisman 144 145 Irons Peter A People s History of the Supreme Court New York Penguin 1999 p 244 158 U S 601 638 158 U S 638 Irons p 245 Weisman 2002 p 177 Jensen Erik M 2014 DID THE SIXTEENTH AMENDMENT EVER MATTER DOES IT MATTER TODAY Northwestern University Law Review 108 3 804 809 810 Harlan dissent to Pollock decision a b Bittker Boris I 1987 Constitutional Limits on the Taxing Power of the Federal Government The Tax Lawyer 41 1 3 ISSN 0890 4898 Pollock case was in effect reversed by the sixteenth amendment The Sixteenth Amendment to the Constitution overruled Pollock Graf v Commissioner 44 T C M CCH 66 TC Memo 1982 317 CCH December 39 080 M 1982 William D Andrews Basic Federal Income Taxation p 2 Little Brown and Company 3d ed 1985 In 1913 the Sixteenth Amendment to the Constitution was adopted overrruling Pollock Calvin H Johnson The Constitutional Meaning of Apportionment of Direct Taxes 80 Tax Notes 591 Aug 3 1998 Pollock should also be understood as reversed in full by the Sixteenth Amendment Sheldon D Pollack Origins of the Modern Income Tax 1894 1913 66 Tax Lawyer 295 323 324 Winter 2013 Amer Bar Ass n the Sixteenth Amendment to the Constitution was duly ratified as of February 3 1913 With that the Pollock decision was overturned restoring the status quo ante footnote omitted In 2012 the U S Supreme Court stated In 1895 we expanded our interpretation of the term direct tax to include taxes on personal property and income from personal property in the course of striking down aspects of the federal income tax Pollock v Farmers Loan amp Trust Co 158 U S 601 618 1895 That result was overturned by the Sixteenth Amendment National Federation of Independent Business v Sebelius no 11 393 no 11 398 no 11 400 p 41 slip opinion U S Supreme Court June 28 2012 Weisman 2002 pp 230 232 278 282 240 U S 1 18 19 1916 FindLaw for Legal Professionals Case Law Federal and State Resources Forms and Code Howard Zaritsky Legislative Attorney American Law Division Some Constitutional Questions Regarding The Federal Income Tax Laws Report No 79 131 A Congressional Research Service Report for Congress May 25 1979 Further reading editJones Francis R 1895 Pollock v Farmers Loan and Trust Company Harvard Law Review 9 3 198 211 doi 10 2307 1321669 JSTOR 1321669 Weisman Steven R 2002 The Great Tax Wars Lincoln to Wilson The Fierce Battles over Money That Transformed the Nation Simon amp Schuster ISBN 0 684 85068 0 Welch Richard E Jr The Presidencies of Grover Cleveland 1988 ISBN 0 7006 0355 7External links edit nbsp Works related to Pollock v Farmers Loan and Trust Company at Wikisource Text of Pollock v Farmers Loan amp Trust Company 157 U S 429 1895 is available from Cornell CourtListener Google Scholar Justia Library of Congress OpenJurist Oyez oral argument audio Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Pollock v Farmers 27 Loan 26 Trust Co amp oldid 1175745598, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.