fbpx
Wikipedia

Glass–Steagall in post-financial crisis reform debate

There have been several efforts or appeals in the United States to reinstate repealed sections of the Glass–Steagall Act following the financial crisis of 2007-08, as well as elsewhere to adopt similar financial reforms.

Efforts to restore Sections 20 and 32 as part of Dodd–Frank edit

During the 2009 United States House of Representatives consideration of H.R. 4173, the bill that became the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010, Representative Maurice Hinchey (D-NY) proposed an amendment to the bill that would have reenacted Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32, which had been repealed by the 1999 Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act (GLBA), and also prohibited bank insurance activities. The amendment was not voted on by the House.[1]

On December 16, 2009, Senators John McCain (R-AZ) and Maria Cantwell (D-WA) introduced in the United States Senate the "Banking Integrity Act of 2009" (S.2886), which would have reinstated Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32, but was not voted on by the Senate.[1][2]

Before the Senate acted on its version of what became the Dodd–Frank Act, the Congressional Research Service issued a report describing securities activities banks and their affiliates had conducted before the GLBA. The Report stated Glass–Steagall had "imperfectly separated, to a certain degree" commercial and investment banking and described the extensive securities activities the Federal Reserve Board had authorized for "Section 20 affiliates" since the 1980s.[3]

The Obama Administration has been criticized for opposing Glass–Steagall reenactment.[1][4] In 2009, Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner testified to the Joint Economic Committee that he opposed reenacting Glass–Steagall and that he did not believe "the end of Glass–Steagall played a significant role" in causing the financial crisis.[5]

Post-2010 efforts edit

On April 12, 2011, Representative Marcy Kaptur (D-OH) introduced in the House the "Return to Prudent Banking Act of 2011" (H.R. 129), which would have (1) amended the Federal Deposit Insurance Act to add prohibitions on FDIC insured bank affiliations instead of reenacting the affiliation restrictions in Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32, (2) directed federal banking regulators and courts to interpret these affiliation provisions and Glass–Steagall Sections 16 and 21 in accordance with the Supreme Court decision in Investment Company Institute v. Camp,[6] and (3) repealed various GLBA changes to the Bank Holding Company Act.[7] The bill was reported to a House subcommittees but not further acted upon before the 112th Congress adjourned.[8]

On May 16, 2013, Senator Tom Harkin (D-IA) introduced S. 985 to restore the original Glass-Steagall Act, on the 80th anniversary of the original act.[9] On July 13, 2013 Senator Elizabeth Warren (D-MA) introduced alongside John McCain (R-AZ), Maria Cantwell (D-WA), and Angus King (I-ME) the 21st Century Glass–Steagall Act (S.1282).[10][11][12][13][14] Warren wrote in a press release: "The 21st Century Glass-Steagall Act will reestablish a wall between commercial and investment banking, make our financial system more stable and secure, and protect American families."[13] Instead of restoring repealed Glass–Steagall sections 20 and 32, the bill would[15]

  1. separate traditional banks that offer savings and checking accounts insured by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation from riskier financial services like investment banking, swaps dealings, hedge funds and private equity activities, as well as from structured and synthetic products, and other products, that did not exist when Glass–Steagall was originally passed.
  2. define the "business of banking" to prevent national banks from engaging in risky activities and bars non-banking activities from being treated as "closely related" to banking. These restriction would counter regulatory loopholes for risky activities, because the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency and the Federal Reserve used these terms to allow traditional banks and bank-holding companies to engage in high-risk activities.
  3. address the issue of too big to fail: by separating depositary institutions from riskier activities, large financial institutions will shrink in size, become smaller and safer and won't be able to rely on federal depository insurance as a safety net for their risky activities. Although some financial institutions may still be large, the implicit government guarantee of a bailout will be reduced because such institutions would no longer be intertwined with depository institutions.
  4. institutes a five years transition period and penalties for any violation.

Many of her colleagues remain opposed, such as the Senators from Delaware, home to the corporate offices of many major banks.[16]

Volcker rule as "Glass–Steagall lite" edit

The Dodd–Frank Act included the Volcker Rule, which among other things limited proprietary trading by banks and their affiliates.[17] This proprietary trading ban was to generally prevent commercial banks and their affiliates from acquiring non-governmental securities with the intention of selling those securities for a profit in the "near term."[18] Some in 2010, have described the Volcker Rule, particularly its proprietary trading ban,[19] as "Glass–Steagall lite."[20]

As described in prohibitions apply to dealing in and underwriting or distributing securities, Glass–Steagall restricted commercial bank "dealing" in, not "trading" of, non-government securities the bank was permitted to purchase as "investment securities."[21] After the GLBA became law, Glass–Steagall Section 16 continued to restrict bank securities purchases. The GLBA, however, expanded the list of "bank-eligible" securities to permit banks to buy, underwrite, and deal in municipal revenue bonds, not only "full faith and credit" government bonds.[22]

The Volcker Rule permits "market making" and other "dealer" activities in non-government securities as services for customers.[23] Glass–Steagall Section 16 prohibits banks from being a "market maker" or otherwise "dealing" in non-government (i.e., "bank-ineligible") securities.[24] Glass–Steagall Section 16 permits a bank to purchase and sell (i.e., permits "trading") for a bank's own account non-government securities that the OCC approves as "investment securities."[21] The Volcker Rule will prohibit such "proprietary trading" of non-government securities.[25]

Before and after the late-2000s financial crisis, banking regulators worried that banks were incorrectly reporting non-traded assets as held in their "trading account" because of lower regulatory capital requirements for assets held in a "trading account."[26] Under the Volcker Rule, U.S. banking regulators have proposed that banks and their affiliates be prohibited from holding any asset (other than government securities and other listed exceptions) as a "trading position."[27]

In 2011, Senators Jeff Merkley (D-OR) and Carl Levin (D-MI) wrote that "proprietary trading losses" played "a central role in bringing the financial system to its knees." They wrote that the Volcker Rule's proprietary trading ban contained in statutory language they proposed is a "modern Glass–Steagall" because Glass–Steagall was both "over-inclusive" (in prohibiting some "truly client-oriented activities that could be managed by developments in securities and banking law") and "under-inclusive" in failing to cover derivatives trading.[28]

In 2002, Arthur Wilmarth wrote, that from 1990-1997 the nine U.S. banks with the greatest securities activities held more than 20% of their assets as trading assets.[29] By 1997, 40% of J.P. Morgan's revenue was from trading.[30] A 1995 study by the federal banking regulators of commercial bank trading activity from June 30, 1984, to June 30, 1994, concluded that "trading activities are an increasingly important source of revenue for banks" and that "[n]otwithstanding the numerous press reports that focus on negative events, the major commercial banks have experienced long-term success in serving customers and generating revenues with these activities." In reporting the study results, the American Banker described "proprietary trading" as "basically securities trading not connected to customer-related bank activities" and summarized the study as finding that "proprietary trading has been getting a bad rap."[31]

Paul Volcker supported the Volcker Rule prohibition on proprietary trading as part of bringing commercial banks back to "concentrating on continuing customer interest."[32] As described in the article Decline of the Glass–Steagall Act, Volcker had long testified to Congress in support of repealing Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32.[33][34][35][36] In 2010 he explained that he understood Glass–Steagall as preventing banks from being principally engaged in underwriting and dealing in corporate securities. Volcker stated that with securitization and other developments he believes it is a proper bank function to underwrite corporate securities "as serving a legitimate customer need." He, therefore, did not believe "repeal of Glass–Steagall was terrible" but that Congress "should have thought about what they replace it with." Volcker's criticism was that Congress "didn't replace it with other restrictions."[37]

Separate from its proprietary trading ban, the Volcker Rule restricts bank and affiliate sponsorship and ownership of hedge funds and private equity funds.[20] The GLBA amended the Bank Holding Company Act to permit "merchant banking" investments by bank affiliates subject to various restrictions.[38] It also authorized the Treasury Department and Federal Reserve Board to permit such merchant banking activities by direct bank subsidiaries ("financial subsidiaries") after five years, but they have not provided such permission.[39] This was not a Glass–Steagall change but a change to the Bank Holding Company Act, which previously limited the size of investments bank affiliates could make in a company engaged in activities not "closely related to banking."[40] Such merchant banking investments may be made through private equity funds.[41] The Volcker Rule will affect the ability of bank affiliates to make such investments.[42]

Other reform proposals that have been compared to Glass–Steagall edit

Both in the US and elsewhere, a number of reform proposals have been put forward that bear some resemblance to Glass–Steagall.

"Ring fencing" proposals edit

In the UK, the Independent Commission on Banking's (ICB) proposal to "ring fence" retail and small business commercial banking from investment banking[43][44] seeks to isolate the "retail banking" functions of a banking firm within a separate corporation that would not be affected by the failure of the overall firm so long as the "ring fenced" retail bank itself remained solvent.[45] Bank of England Governor Mervyn King expressed concern the European Commission could block implementation of the ICB proposal as a violation of Commission standards.[46] Although Michel Barnier, European Union internal market Commissioner, proposed limits on capital requirements for banks that could have hindered the UK ring fencing proposal and indicated support for the French and German position against breaking up banking groups, in November 2011 he announced an "expert commission" would "study the mandatory separation of risky investment banking activities from traditional retail lenders."[47]

In 2016 it was reported that Bank of England "would press ahead with plans for banks to ringfence their retail operations by 2019".[48]

On October 2, 2012, the EU committee appointed to study the issue, through its Liikanen report, recommended a form of "ring fencing" similar to the proposal in the United Kingdom.[49] In April 2013 the Bank for International Settlements has issued a working paper comparing the Volcker Rule, the ICB proposals, the Liikanen report proposals, and other international proposals for bank structural reform.[50]

Debate on "firewalls" edit

Congressional and bank regulator efforts to "repeal", "reform" or apply Glass–Steagall were based on isolating a commercial banking firm's expanded securities activities in a separately capitalized bank affiliate.[51][52] Much of the debate concerned whether such affiliates could be owned by a bank (as with "operating subsidiaries" in the 1990s) or would be bank holding company subsidiaries outside the chain of bank ownership.[53][54] In either case, "firewalls" were intended to isolate the bank from the affiliate.[55]

Banking regulators and commentators debated whether "firewalls" could truly separate a bank from its affiliate in a crisis and often cited the early 1980s' statement by then Citicorp CEO Walter Wriston that "it is inconceivable that any major bank would walk away from any subsidiary of its holding company."[56] Alan Greenspan and Paul Volcker testified to Congress that firewalls so strong that they truly separated different businesses would eliminate the benefits of combining the two activities.[57] Both testified that in a crisis the owners of the overall firm would inevitably find ways to use the assets of any solvent part of the firm to assist the troubled part.[57] Thus, "firewalls" sufficient to prevent a bank from assisting its affiliate would eliminate the purpose of the combination, but "workable" firewalls would be insufficient to prevent such assistance. Both Volcker and Greenspan proposed that the solution was adequate supervision, including sufficient capital and other requirements.[57]

In 1998 and 1999 Greenspan testified to Congress in opposition to the Clinton Administration proposal to permit national bank subsidiaries to engage in expanded securities and other activities. He argued such direct bank subsidiary activities would be "financed by the sovereign credit of the United States" through the "federal safety net" for banks, despite the Treasury Department's assurance that "firewalls" between the bank and its operating subsidiary would prevent the expansion of the "federal safety net."[58]

As described in commentator response to Section 20 and 32 repeal, Gary Stern, Arthur Wilmarth, and others questioned whether either operating subsidiaries or separate holding company affiliates could be isolated from an affiliated bank in a financial crisis and feared that the "too big to fail" doctrine gave competitive benefits to banking firms entering the securities or insurance business through either structure.[59] Greenspan did not deny that the government might act to "manage an orderly liquidation" of a large financial "intermediary" in a crisis, but he suggested that only insured creditors would be fully repaid, that shareholders would be unprotected, and that uninsured creditors would receive less than full payment through a discount or "haircut."[60] Commentators pointed to the 1990 failure of Drexel Burnham Lambert as suggesting "too-big-to-fail" considerations need not force a government rescue of creditors to a failing investment bank or other nonbank,[61] although Greenspan had pointed to that experience as questioning the ability of firewalls to isolate one part of a financial firm from the rest.[57]

After the late-2000s financial crisis commentators noted that the Federal Reserve Board used its power to grant exemptions from Federal Reserve Act Section 23A (part of the 1933 Banking Act and the "principle statutory" firewall between banks and their affiliates) to permit banks to "rescue" various affiliates or bank sponsored participants in the "shadow banking system" as part of a general effort to restore liquidity in financial markets.[62] Section 23A generally prevented banks from funding securities purchases by their affiliates before the financial crisis (i.e., prevented the affiliates from "using insured deposits to purchase risky investments") by "limiting the ability of depository institutions to transfer to affiliates the subsidy arising from the institutions' access to the federal safety net," but the Federal Reserve Board's exemptions allowed banks to transfer such investments from the shadow banking market to FDIC insured banks during the crisis.[63] The Federal Reserve Board's General Counsel has defended these actions by arguing that all the Section 23A exemptions required that bank funding of affiliate or shadow banking investments be "fully collateralized" on a daily basis with qualifying collateral, so that the bank was "very much protected," and that in the end the exemptions did not prove very "useful."[64]

The ICB proposes to erect a barrier between the "ring-fenced bank" and its "wider corporate group" that will permit banking regulators to isolate the ring-fenced bank "from the rest of the group in a matter of days and continue the provision of its services without providing solvency support."[65]

Limited purpose banking and narrow banking edit

Laurence Kotlikoff was disappointed the ICB did not adopt the "limited purpose banking" he proposed to the ICB.[66][67] This would require a bank to operate like a mutual fund in repaying "deposits" based on the current market value of the bank's assets. Kotlikoff argues there will always be financial crises if banks lend deposits but are required to repay the full amount of those deposits "on demand."[68] Kotlikoff would only permit a bank (restructured as a mutual fund) to promise payment of deposits at "par" (i.e., $1 for every $1 deposited) if the bank (i.e., mutual fund) held 100% of all deposits in cash as a trustee.[67][69]

As Kotlikoff notes, in 1987 Robert Litan proposed "narrow banking."[70] Litan suggested commercial banking firms be freed from Glass–Steagall limits (and other activity restrictions) so long as they isolated FDIC insured deposits in a "narrow bank" that was only permitted to invest those deposits in "safe securities" approved by the FDIC.[71] In 1995 Arthur Wilmarth proposed applying Litan's "narrow bank" proposal to U.S. banks ("global banks") that had become heavily involved in "capital markets" activities through "Section 20 affiliates," derivatives, and other activities.[72] Under Wilmarth's proposal (which he repeated in 2001 after the GLBA became law[73]) only banks that limited their activities to taking deposits and making commercial loans would be permitted to make commercial loans with FDIC insured deposits.[74] Wilmarth expected only "community banks" specialized in making consumer and small business loans would continue to operate as such traditional banks.[75] The large "global banks" would fund their lending through the capital markets just like investment banks and other "shadow banking" lenders.[76]

Narrow banking and wholesale financial institutions edit

The Litan and Wilmarth proposals were very different from the Kotlikoff limited purpose banking proposal in that they would only limit the activities of companies that owned FDIC insured banks. Whereas Kotlikoff would require a company to hold the full amount of its "demand deposits" in cash, Litan and Wilmarth would permit companies to issue such "demand deposits" without restriction, so long as the demand deposits were not FDIC insured. Congress considered this type of proposal when it debated the repeal of Glass-Steagall sections 20 and 32.

In 1997 the Clinton Administration proposed that "wholesale financial institutions" (known as "woofies") be authorized to be members of the Federal Reserve System but not "banks" under the Bank Holding Company Act because they would own non-FDIC insured banks that would only take deposits of $100,000 or more.[77] Whereas "narrow banks" would be FDIC insured, but only invest in FDIC approved "safe securities," "woofies" would be free to lend, purchase securities, and make other investments, because they would not hold any FDIC insured deposits. The proposal was intended to permit securities firms to continue to maintain ownership of commercial firms while gaining access to the Federal Reserve's "payment system" and "discount window", so long as the firm did not take FDIC insured deposits.[78]

"Woofies" were not authorized by the GLBA because of a dispute between Senator Phil Gramm and the Clinton Administration over the application of the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) to "woofies." In their October 1999 compromise on CRA provisions in the GLBA,[79] the Clinton Administration agreed with Gramm that CRA would not apply to woofies so long as only a company that did not then own any FDIC insured depository institution would be permitted to qualify as a "wholesale financial institution."[80] The Clinton Administration wanted this restriction to prevent existing bank holding companies from disposing of their FDIC insured banks to qualify as "woofies," which could reduce the deposit base subject to CRA requirements.[81] When Chase and J.P. Morgan lobbied to change the final legislation to permit them to become woofies, they complained only Goldman Sachs and "a few others" could qualify as a woofie.[80][81] When negotiators decided they could not resolve the dispute, permission for woofies was eliminated from the final GLBA.[80][81]

"Woofies" were similar to the "global bank" structure suggested by Arthur Wilmarth because they would not use FDIC insured deposits to make commercial loans. They would, however, be subject to Federal Reserve supervision unlike lenders in the unsupervised "shadow banking" system. Because woofies would have had access to the Federal Reserve discount window and payments service, critics (including the Independent Bankers Association of America and Paul Volcker) opposed woofies (and a similar 1996 proposal by Representative James A. Leach) for providing unfair competition to banks.[82] Although October 1999 press reports suggested bank holding companies were interested in becoming woofies,[80][81] the New York Times reported in July 1999 that banking and securities firms had lost interest in becoming woofies.[83]

Shadow banking in financial reform proposals edit

The ICB Report rejected "narrow banking" in part because it would lead to more credit (and all credit during times of stress) being provided by a "less regulated sector."[84] In 1993 Jane D'Arista and Tom Schlesinger noted that the "parallel banking system" had grown because it did not incur the regulatory costs of commercial banks.[85] They proposed to equalize the cost by establishing "uniform regulation" of banks and the lenders and investors in the parallel banking system.[86] As with Kotlikoff's "limited purpose banking" proposal, only investment pools funded 100% from equity interests would remain unregulated as banks.[87] Although D'Arista and Schlesinger acknowledged the regulation of banks and of the parallel banking system would end up only being "comparable," their goal was to eliminate so far as possible the competitive advantages of the "parallel" or "shadow" banking market.[88]

Many commentators have argued that the failure to regulate the shadow banking market was a primary cause of the financial crisis.[89][90] There is general agreement that the crisis emerged in the shadow banking markets not in the traditional banking market.[91] As described in the article Decline of the Glass–Steagall Act, Helen Garten had identified the "consumerization" of banking regulation as producing "a largely unregulated, sophisticated wholesale market,"[92] which created the risk of the "underproduction of regulation" of that market.[93]

Laurence Kotlikoff's "limited purpose banking" proposal rejects bank regulation (based on rules and supervision to ensure "safety and soundness") and replaces it with a prohibition on any company operating like a traditional "bank." All limited liability financial companies (not only today's "banks") that receive money from the public for investment or "lending" and that issue promises to pay amounts in the future (whether as insurance companies, hedge funds, securities firms, or otherwise) could only issue obligations to repay amounts equal to the value of their assets.[67][94] All "depositors" in or "lenders" to such companies would become "investors" (as in a mutual fund) with the right to receive the full return on the investments made by the companies (minus fees) and obligated to bear the full loss on those investments.[67][95]

Thomas Hoenig rejects both "limited purpose banking" and the proposal to regulate shadow banking as part of the banking system. Hoenig argues it is not necessary to regulate "shadow banking system" lenders as banks if those lenders are prohibited from issuing liabilities that function like bank demand deposits. He suggests that requiring money market funds to redeem shares at the funds' fluctuating daily net asset values would prevent those funds from functioning like bank checking accounts and that eliminating special Bankruptcy Code treatment for repurchase agreements would delay repayment of those transactions in a bankruptcy and thereby end their treatment as "cash equivalents" when the "repo" was funding illiquid, long term securities. By limiting the ability of "shadow banks" to compete with traditional banks in creating "money-like" instruments, Hoenig hopes to better assure that the safety net is not ultimately called upon to "bail them [i.e., shadow banks such as Bear Stearns and AIG during the financial crisis] out in a crisis." He proposes to deal with actual commercial banks by imposing "Glass–Steagall-type boundaries" so that banks "that have access to the safety net should be restricted to certain core activities that the safety net was intended to protect—making loans and taking deposits—and related activities consistent with the presence of the safety net."[96]

Glass–Steagall references in financial reform proposals edit

Although the UK's ICB and the commentators presenting the proposals described above to modify banks or banking regulation address issues beyond the scope of the Glass–Steagall separation of commercial and investment banking, each specifically examines Glass–Steagall. The ICB stated Glass–Steagall had been "undermined in part by the development of derivatives."[97] The ICB also argued that the development before 1999 of "the world's leading investment banks out of the US despite Glass–Steagall in place at the time" should caution against assuming the "activity restrictions" it recommended in its "ring fencing" proposal would hinder UK investment banks from competing internationally.[98]

Boston University economist Laurence J. Kotlikoff suggests commercial banks only became involved with CDOs, SIVs, and other "risky products" after Glass–Steagall was "repealed," but he rejects Glass–Steagall reinstatement (after suggesting Paul Volcker favors it) as a "non-starter" because it would give the "nonbank/shadow bank/investment bank industry" a "competitive advantage" without requiring it to pay for the "implicit" "lender-of-last-resort" protection it receives from the government.[99] Robert Litan and Arthur Wilmarth presented their "narrow bank" proposals as a basis for eliminating Glass–Steagall (and other) restrictions on bank affiliates.[100] Writing in 1993, Jane D'Artista and Tom Schlesinger noted that "the ongoing integration of financial industry activities makes it increasingly difficult to separate banking and securities operations meaningfully" but rejected Glass–Steagall repeal because "the separation of banking and securities functions is a proven, least-cost method of preventing the problems of one financial sector from spilling over into the other" (which they stated was "most recently demonstrated in the October 1987 market crash.")[101]

During the Senate debate of the bill that became the Dodd–Frank Act, Thomas Hoenig wrote Senators Maria Cantwell and John McCain (the co-sponsors of legislation to reinstate Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32) supporting a "substantive debate" on "the unintended consequences of leaving investment banking commingled with commercial banking" and reiterating that he had "long supported" reinstating "Glass–Steagall-type laws" to separate "higher risk, often more leveraged, activities of investment banks" from commercial banking. As described above in post 2010 efforts to enact Glass–Steagall inspired financial reform legislation Elizabeth Warren and other senators have joined Cantwell and McCain in their effort to legislate Glass–Steagall inspired restrictions.[102] Hoenig agreed with Paul Volcker, however, that "financial market developments" had caused underwriting corporate bonds (the prohibition of which Volcker described as the purpose of Glass–Steagall[37]), and also underwriting of corporate equity, revenue bonds, and "high quality asset-backed securities," to be "natural extensions of commercial banking." Instead of reinstating Glass–Steagall prohibitions on such underwriting, Hoenig proposed restoring "the principles underlying the separation of commercial and investment banking firms."[103]

In Mainland Europe, some scholars have suggested Glass–Steagall should be a model for any in-depth reform of bank regulation: notably in France where SFAF and World Pensions Council (WPC) banking experts have argued that "a new Glass–Steagall Act" should be viewed within the broader context of separation of powers in European Union law.[104]

This perspective has gained ground after the unraveling of the Libor scandal in July 2012, with mainstream opinion leaders such as the Financial Times editorialists calling for the adoption of an EU-wide "Glass Steagall II".[105]

On July 25, 2012, former Citigroup Chairman and CEO Sandy Weill, considered one of the driving forces behind the considerable financial deregulation and "mega-mergers" of the 1990s, surprised financial analysts in Europe and North America by "calling for splitting up the commercial banks from the investment banks. In effect, he says: bring back the Glass–Steagall Act of 1933 which led to half a century, free of financial crises."[106] However, Weill reversed his position a year later, arguing that "big banks don't have to be split if the 'right regulation' is in place," and instead that "[banks] should decide on their own to 'split if they figure that's the best way that they can provide their services.'"[107]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b c Robert Scheer (2010-01-06). "McCain Gets It, Obama Doesn't". The Nation.
  2. ^ S. 2866: Bill Summary & Status
  3. ^ CRS 2010a, pp. 1 and 13–15.
  4. ^ MacArthur, John R. (December 14, 2011), "President Obama Richly Deserves to Be Dumped", The Providence Journal, p. 2 ("the administration steadfastly opposes the restoration of the Glass–Steagall Act"), retrieved February 22, 2012.
  5. ^ Sloan, Stephen; Hopkins, Cheyenne (January 27, 2010), "Obama Plan Has Shades of Glass–Steagall Act", American Banker, p. 2 ("I would not support reinstating Glass–Steagall and I don't actually believe that the end of Glass–Steagall played a significant role in the cause of the crisis," Geithner told the Joint Economic Committee in November.), retrieved February 22, 2012. Financial Regulatory Reform: Protecting Taxpayers and the Economy, Hearing before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States (PDF), Government Printing Office, November 19, 2009, p. 19, retrieved February 22, 2012.
  6. ^ CRS 2010a, pp. 8–9.
  7. ^ Cook, Merrill (July 20, 2011), "Support the Kaptur/Jones Prudent Banking Act of 2011, H.R. 1489", Standard Examiner, Ogden, Utah, p. 2, retrieved February 22, 2012. Bill Text, 112th Congress (2011-2012), H.R. 1489.IH, Congress.gov Library of Congress, retrieved February 22, 2012.
  8. ^ Bill Summary & Status, 112th Congress (2011-2012), H.R. 1489, CRS Summary, Congress.gov Library of Congress, retrieved February 22, 2012.
  9. ^ Tom Harkin introduces Glass-Steagall bill, Daily Kos, May 20, 2013.
  10. ^ Matthews, Dylan (12 July 2013). "Elizabeth Warren and John McCain want Glass–Steagall back. Should you?". The Washington Post. Retrieved 15 September 2013.
  11. ^ Warren, Elizabeth (11 July 2013). "Bill Summary & Status - 113th Congress (2013 - 2014) - S.1282". Congress.gov (Library of Congress). Retrieved 15 September 2013.
  12. ^ Warren, Elisabeth (11 July 2013). "21st Century Glass-Steagall Act of 2013" (PDF). Retrieved 15 September 2013.
  13. ^ a b Warren, Elizabeth (11 July 2013). "Senators Warren, McCain, Cantwell, and King Introduce 21st Century Glass-Steagall Act". Retrieved 15 September 2013.
  14. ^ Carter, Zach (11 July 2013). "Glass-Steagall Act Would Be Revived In New Bill From Elizabeth Warren, Bipartisan Coalition". The Huffington Post. Retrieved 15 September 2013.
  15. ^ Warren, Elizabeth (13 July 2013). "21st Century Glass-Steagall Act Fact Sheet" (PDF). www.warren.senate.gov. Retrieved 15 September 2013. Warren, Elizabeth. "S._______, A Billt" (PDF). www.warren.senate.gov. Retrieved 17 October 2013.
  16. ^ Starkey, Jonathan, "Delaware lawmakers among opponents to resurrecting bank law, " Delaware Online (Gannett), 21-Jul-2013
  17. ^ Chapman and Cutler LLP 2010. Whitehead 2011, p. 47.
  18. ^ Whitehead 2011, p. 48. Chapman and Cutler LLP 2010, p. 1.
  19. ^ Watson, Bruce (October 12, 2011), Volcker Rule Made Simple: Banks Can't Gamble With Our Money (Probably), Daily Finance, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  20. ^ a b Glass–Steagall lite, The Economist, January 22, 2010, retrieved February 20, 2012. Copeland, Laurence (January 25, 2010), , The Great Debate UK, Reuters, archived from the original on 2010-01-28, retrieved July 18, 2023.
  21. ^ a b Fein 2011, § 4.04[C], p. 4-30 and § 7.06[A], pp. 7-90 to 7-91. Capatides 1992, p. 201.
  22. ^ C&B 1999, p. 12. "Supervisory guidance relating to a change to permissible securities activities of state member banks", SR 01-13, Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, p. 1, May 14, 2001, retrieved February 16, 2012.
  23. ^ Whitehead 2011, p. 50.
  24. ^ Fein 2011, § 7.06[A], p. 7-90. CRS 2010a, p. 5.
  25. ^ Whitehead 2011, pp. 48-49.
  26. ^ Rowe, David (March 2006), Regulatory arbitrage: back to basics (PDF), Risk Magazine, p. 66, retrieved February 20, 2012. Caresana, Annalisa (January 2009), Regulatory capital for banks' trading activities set to increase to eliminate regulatory arbitrage between trading book and banking book, Technical Update, Adkins Matchett & Toy, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  27. ^ Norris, Floyd (October 14, 2011), "Bank Rules That Serve Two Masters", New York Times, p. B1, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  28. ^ Merkley, Jeff; Levin, Carl (2011), "The Dodd–Frank Act Restrictions on Proprietary Trading and Conflicts of Interest: New Tools to Address Evolving Threats" (PDF), Harvard Journal of Legislation, 48 (2): 530 and 538–539, retrieved February 25, 2012.
  29. ^ Wilmarth 2002, p. 374.
  30. ^ Wilmarth 2002, p. 374, fn. 665.
  31. ^ de Senerpont Domas, Olaf (December 7, 1995), "Bank Trading Losses Minimal and Risks Limited, U.S. Says", American Banker, p. 24. Fein 2011, 7.06[A], p. 7-91. "Staff Paper Released On Trading Activities At Commercial Banks (NR 95-134)" (PDF) (Press release). Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and Federal Reserve Board. December 6, 1999. Retrieved February 19, 2012..
  32. ^ Dixon, Kim; Witkowski, Karey (March 30, 2010), Volcker: Proprietary trading not central to crisis, Reuters, retrieved February 19, 2012. Volcker, Paul (March 30, 2010), "Essential Elements of Financial Reform", Transcript of speech delivered at the Peterson Institute, retrieved February 19, 2012.
  33. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 71 (for opposition to underwriting corporate bonds), 74 and 76. Volcker, Paul (January 16, 1984), Statement before the Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, United States Senate (PDF), pp. 2–3 and 7–8, retrieved October 16, 2014.
  34. ^ Garrson, Robert M. (May 9, 1991), "Volcker: Public Must Re-Fund Bank Insurance", American Banker
  35. ^ Canan, Martha M. (April 6, 1995), "Leach Pushes Back Debate on Bank Reform to May 9", Bond Buyer. Volcker 1997a ("I have argued this morning the logic and practical desirability of finally eliminating Glass–Steagall restrictions").
  36. ^ Volcker, Paul (September 10, 1998), "Boost for Banking", Washington Post, p. A21 ( Op-Ed).
  37. ^ a b Conference Proceedings, 19th Annual Hyman P. Minsky Conference on the State of the U.S. and World Economies, After the Crisis: Planning a New Financial Structure (PDF), Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, April 14–16, 2010, p. 113, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  38. ^ CRS 2010b, pp. 5–7. Fein 2011, §§ 8.01 and 8.02[D], p. 8-3 to 8-5.
  39. ^ CRS 2010b, p. 9, fn.60. Fein 2011, § 8.03[D], p. 8-12.
  40. ^ Lockner and Hansche 2000, p. 37.
  41. ^ CRS 2010b, pp. 6–8.
  42. ^ Fein 2011, § 7.08[G], pp. 7-119 to 7-126 and § 8.04, p. 8-15.
  43. ^ ICB 2011
  44. ^ Hutton, Will (August 31, 2011), "Banking reform: ringfencing is the only solution", The Guardian, retrieved February 21, 2012.
  45. ^ Goff, Sharlene (August 31, 2011), "Just the facts: the Vickers Report", Financial Times, retrieved February 21, 2012
  46. ^ Samuel, Juliet (November 4, 2011), "King: EU could veto Vickers", City A.M., retrieved February 21, 2012
  47. ^ Pignal, Stanley; Barker, Alex (November 22, 2011), "Barnier panel to study break up of EU banks", Financial Times, retrieved February 21, 2012.
  48. ^ Binham, Caroline (May 26, 2016). "BoE sets out capital rules for ringfenced banks". The Financial Times. Retrieved 25 February 2017.
  49. ^ "Expert report suggests Europe's banks ring-fence investment banking from retail banking", Washington Post, [Associated Press], October 2, 2012, retrieved October 9, 2012[dead link]. Final Report (PDF), High-level Expert Group on reforming the structure of the EU banking sector, October 2, 2012, retrieved October 9, 2012
  50. ^ Leonardo Gambacorta; Adrian van Rixtel (April 2013), BIS Working Papers No. 412, Structural bank regulation inititatives: approaches and implictions (PDF), Bank for International Settlements, retrieved October 15, 2013
  51. ^ Fisher, Keith R. (1992), "Reweaving the Safety Net: Bank Diversification into Securities and Insurance Activities", Wake Forest Law Review, 27 (1): 231–247, retrieved February 25, 2012. "Banking Reform, Deformed (editorial)", New York Times, p. A26, October 31, 1991.
  52. ^ Murphy, Brian D.; Haring, Sherri S. (1997), Removal of Three Section 20 Firewalls Enhances Opportunities for One-Stop Shopping in the Financial Services Industry, McGuire Woods LLP, retrieved February 13, 2012. Rodelli 1998, pp. 321-326.
  53. ^ Phil FRB 1999, pp. 1-2.
  54. ^ Wagner 2000, pp. 335-337 and 382-424. Fein 2011, §1.04[B] pp. 1-21 to 1-22.
  55. ^ Shull and White 1998, pp. 1, 8-10, and 14-17.
  56. ^ Shull and White 1998, p. 8. England, Catherine (1991), Governing Banking's Future: Markets vs. Regulation, Boston: Kluwer Academic, p. 65, ISBN 9780792391609, retrieved February 22, 2012. Wilmarth 2001, p. 22, fn. 37.
  57. ^ a b c d Shull and White 1998, pp. 8-9 (for Greenspan in 1990). Testimony by Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the Committee on Banking, Housing & Urban Affairs, United States Senate, July 12, 1990 (PDF), July 12, 1990, pp. 14–15, retrieved October 16, 2014. Rodelli 1998, p. 316, fn. 35 (for Volcker in 1995). Volcker 1997b, pp. 3-4 ("Firewalls"). Fein 2011, §1.04[B] p.1-22.
  58. ^ Wells, Rob (April 29, 1999), "Fed Chief Discourages New Bank Powers, Says Pending Bill Would Give Unfair Advantage", Bloomberg News. Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan, before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, June 17, 1998, "H.R. 10, the Financial Services Act of 1998", Federal Reserve Board, June 17, 1998, pp. 10–13 ("Operating Subsidiaries vs. Holding Companies"), retrieved February 22, 2012. Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan, before the Subcommittee on Finance and Hazardous Materials, Committee on Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives, "H.R. 10 and financial modernization", Federal Reserve Board, April 28, 1999, pp. 1–6 ("Operating Subsidiaries"), retrieved February 22, 2012.
  59. ^ Stern 2000. Stern and Feldman 2004, p. 77. Wilmarth 2001, p. 22. Wilmarth 2002, pp. 224-225.
  60. ^ Stern 2000, p. 9. Remarks of Chairman Alan Greenspan at the 36th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, "Banking evolution", Federal Reserve Board, May 4, 2000, p. 3, retrieved February 23, 2012.
  61. ^ Wilmarth 1995, p. 82.
  62. ^ Omarova 2011, pp. 1725-1756.
  63. ^ Omarova 2011, pp. 1689-1690, 1728, and 1734.
  64. ^ Alvarez, Scott (March 23, 2010), FCIC Interview of Scott Alvarez and Kieran Fallon (PDF), Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, pp. 62–67, retrieved October 9, 2012
  65. ^ ICB 2011, pp. 235–236.
  66. ^ "Why the Vickers Report failed the UK and the World", Economists' Forum, Financial Times, September 20, 2011, retrieved February 6, 2012.
  67. ^ a b c d Kotlikoff, Laurence (January 28, 2011), "Open letter to Sir John Vickers on his banking reform speech", Economists' Forum, Financial Times, retrieved February 6, 2012
  68. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, pp. 84-89.
  69. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, pp. 123-124 and 131-132.
  70. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, p. 132.
  71. ^ Litan 1987, pp. 70-71 and 164-178.
  72. ^ Wilmarth 1995, pp. 77-87.
  73. ^ Wilmarth 2001, pp. 73-81.
  74. ^ Wilmarth 1995, pp. 81-83. Wilmarth 2001, pp. 80-81
  75. ^ Wilmarth 1995, pp. 82-3. Wilmarth 2001, pp. 79-80.
  76. ^ Wilmarth 1995, pp. 86-87. Wilmarth 2001, pp. 80-81.
  77. ^ Pottinger, Matt (June 4, 1997), "Rubin Pitches Plan on Bank Deregulation", Chicago Tribune, p. 1. Hawke, Jr., John D. (June 3, 1997), Text as Prepared for Delivery: Treasury Undersecretary For Domestic Finance, John D. Hawke, House Banking and Financial Services, p. 3 (Wholesale Financial Institutions"), retrieved February 21, 2012. Taylor, Andrew (May 24, 1997), "BANKING: Under Treasury Plan, Congress to Decide Tough Issues", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1190.
  78. ^ Levitt 1998 ("A Competitive Two-Way Street"). Wayne, Leslie (July 7, 1999), "Push for Wholesale Banks stalls in Overhaul of Law", New York Times, p. 2, retrieved February 21, 2012.
  79. ^ Phil FRB 1999, pp. 1-2. Parks, Daniel J. (October 23, 1999), "BANKING: Financial Services Bill in the Final Stretch", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 2498–2503.
  80. ^ a b c d Day, Kathleen (October 28, 1999), "Wholesale Banks Cut from Overhaul Bill", Washington Post, p. E.02
  81. ^ a b c d Anason, Dean (October 28, 1999), "Capital Briefs: Wholesale Banking Cut from Reform Bill", American Banker, p. 2
  82. ^ "Statement of The Independent Bankers Association of America before the Committee on Banking and Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, on Financial Restructuring" (Press release). The Committee on Financial Services. May 7, 1997. p. 5 ("Wholesale Financial Institutions"). Retrieved February 22, 2012. de Senerpont Domas, Olaf (April 6, 1995), "Volcker Plays Down Usefulness of Firewalls in Remarks to Panel", American Banker, p. 2("Why should this particular class of institution be free of federal deposit insurance when it will be competing side by side with banks that have to pay deposit insurance premiums?")
  83. ^ Wayne, Leslie (July 7, 1999), "Push for Wholesale Banks stalls in Overhaul of Law", New York Times, p. 2, retrieved February 21, 2012
  84. ^ ICB 2011, Chapter 3.21, p. 44.
  85. ^ D'Arista and Schlesinger 1993, pp. 11-14.
  86. ^ D'Arista and Schlesinger 1993, p. 32-38.
  87. ^ D'Arista and Schlesinger 1993, p. 34.
  88. ^ D'Arista and Schlesinger 1993, pp. 36-37.
  89. ^ Date, Raj; Konczal, Michael (March 2011), "Out of the Shadows: Creating a 21st Century Glass–Steagall", Make Markets Be Markets (PDF), Roosevelt Institute, p. 61, retrieved February 6, 2012Date and Konczal 2011, p. 61.
  90. ^ FCIC 2011, pp. xvii, xx, 27–37, 255, 414, and 469.
  91. ^ Gorton, Gary; Metrick, Andrew (October 18, 2010), Regulating the Shadow Banking System, pp. 15–16, SSRN 1676947. FCIC 2011, pp. 245, 275, 343, 427, 446, and 478.
  92. ^ Garten 1999, p. 293.
  93. ^ Garten 1999, pp. 304-307.
  94. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, pp. 122-124.
  95. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, pp. 126 and 131-154.
  96. ^ Hoenig, Thomas (June 27, 2011), "Do SIFIs Have a Future" (PDF), Keynote remarks to "Dodd-Frank One Year On," Pew Financial Reform Project and New York University Stern School of Business Conference, Washington, D.C.: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp. 5 and 7–8, retrieved February 22, 2012.
  97. ^ ICB 2011, p. 36, fn. 1.
  98. ^ ICB 2011, p. 146.
  99. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, p. 151.
  100. ^ Litan 1987, pp. 164-178. Wilmarth 1995, pp. 80-82.
  101. ^ D'Arista and Schlesinger 1993, pp. 6-7.
  102. ^ "Warren Joins McCain to Push New Glass-Steagall Law for Banks". Bloomberg.
  103. ^ Hoenig, Thomas (May 10, 2010), Letter to The Honorable Senator Maria Cantwell and The Honorable Senator John McCain (PDF), Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, retrieved February 22, 2012
  104. ^ M. Nicolas J. Firzli quoted by Marie Lepesant (June 11, 2012). "Le Modèle des Banques Françaises en Question". Le Parisien Aujourd'hui en France. . Retrieved 12 June 2012.
  105. ^ Editorial, Page (July 3, 2012). "Restoring trust after Diamond". Financial Times. Retrieved 15 July 2012. quoting FT Editorial Page.
  106. ^ Denning, Steve (July 25, 2012). "Rethinking Capitalism: Sandy Weill Says Bring Back Glass–Steagall". Forbes. Retrieved 25 July 2012. Quoting interview on CNBC's Squawk-Box.
  107. ^ Belvidere, Matthew J. (September 10, 2013). "Big banks don't need to be split up: Sandy Weill". CNBC.com. Retrieved 19 October 2013.

Works cited edit

  • Carpenter, David H.; Murphy, M. Maureen (2010a), (PDF), Congressional Research Service Report, no. R41181, archived from the original (PDF) on August 4, 2012, retrieved February 10, 2012
  • Carpenter, David H.; Murphy, M. Maureen (2010b), "The "Volcker Rule": Proposals to Limit "Speculative" Proprietary Trading by Banks" (PDF), Congressional Research Service Report, no. R41298, retrieved February 10, 2012.
  • Covington & Burling (November 12, 1999), Financial Modernization: The Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act, Summary (PDF), American Bankers Association, retrieved February 24, 2012.
  • Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission (2011), (PDF), archived from the original (PDF) on January 12, 2012, retrieved February 24, 2012.
  • Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia (1999), "Recent Developments: Financial Services Reform Enacted" (PDF), Banking Legislation & Policy, 18 (4): 1–4, retrieved February 24, 2012.
  • Independent Commission on Banking (September 2011), (PDF), pp. 1–354, archived from the original (PDF) on March 18, 2012, retrieved February 24, 2012.
  • Volcker, Paul A. (February 25, 1997), , The Committee on Financial Services, United States House of Representatives, archived from the original on October 17, 2012, retrieved February 25, 2012.
  • Volcker, Paul A. (May 14, 1997), , The Committee on Financial Services, United States House of Representatives, archived from the original on October 17, 2012, retrieved February 25, 2012.

glass, steagall, post, financial, crisis, reform, debate, there, have, been, several, efforts, appeals, united, states, reinstate, repealed, sections, glass, steagall, following, financial, crisis, 2007, well, elsewhere, adopt, similar, financial, reforms, con. There have been several efforts or appeals in the United States to reinstate repealed sections of the Glass Steagall Act following the financial crisis of 2007 08 as well as elsewhere to adopt similar financial reforms Contents 1 Efforts to restore Sections 20 and 32 as part of Dodd Frank 2 Post 2010 efforts 3 Volcker rule as Glass Steagall lite 4 Other reform proposals that have been compared to Glass Steagall 4 1 Ring fencing proposals 4 1 1 Debate on firewalls 4 2 Limited purpose banking and narrow banking 4 2 1 Narrow banking and wholesale financial institutions 4 3 Shadow banking in financial reform proposals 4 4 Glass Steagall references in financial reform proposals 5 See also 6 References 6 1 Works citedEfforts to restore Sections 20 and 32 as part of Dodd Frank editDuring the 2009 United States House of Representatives consideration of H R 4173 the bill that became the Dodd Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010 Representative Maurice Hinchey D NY proposed an amendment to the bill that would have reenacted Glass Steagall Sections 20 and 32 which had been repealed by the 1999 Gramm Leach Bliley Act GLBA and also prohibited bank insurance activities The amendment was not voted on by the House 1 On December 16 2009 Senators John McCain R AZ and Maria Cantwell D WA introduced in the United States Senate the Banking Integrity Act of 2009 S 2886 which would have reinstated Glass Steagall Sections 20 and 32 but was not voted on by the Senate 1 2 Before the Senate acted on its version of what became the Dodd Frank Act the Congressional Research Service issued a report describing securities activities banks and their affiliates had conducted before the GLBA The Report stated Glass Steagall had imperfectly separated to a certain degree commercial and investment banking and described the extensive securities activities the Federal Reserve Board had authorized for Section 20 affiliates since the 1980s 3 The Obama Administration has been criticized for opposing Glass Steagall reenactment 1 4 In 2009 Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner testified to the Joint Economic Committee that he opposed reenacting Glass Steagall and that he did not believe the end of Glass Steagall played a significant role in causing the financial crisis 5 Post 2010 efforts editOn April 12 2011 Representative Marcy Kaptur D OH introduced in the House the Return to Prudent Banking Act of 2011 H R 129 which would have 1 amended the Federal Deposit Insurance Act to add prohibitions on FDIC insured bank affiliations instead of reenacting the affiliation restrictions in Glass Steagall Sections 20 and 32 2 directed federal banking regulators and courts to interpret these affiliation provisions and Glass Steagall Sections 16 and 21 in accordance with the Supreme Court decision in Investment Company Institute v Camp 6 and 3 repealed various GLBA changes to the Bank Holding Company Act 7 The bill was reported to a House subcommittees but not further acted upon before the 112th Congress adjourned 8 On May 16 2013 Senator Tom Harkin D IA introduced S 985 to restore the original Glass Steagall Act on the 80th anniversary of the original act 9 On July 13 2013 Senator Elizabeth Warren D MA introduced alongside John McCain R AZ Maria Cantwell D WA and Angus King I ME the 21st Century Glass Steagall Act S 1282 10 11 12 13 14 Warren wrote in a press release The 21st Century Glass Steagall Act will reestablish a wall between commercial and investment banking make our financial system more stable and secure and protect American families 13 Instead of restoring repealed Glass Steagall sections 20 and 32 the bill would 15 separate traditional banks that offer savings and checking accounts insured by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation from riskier financial services like investment banking swaps dealings hedge funds and private equity activities as well as from structured and synthetic products and other products that did not exist when Glass Steagall was originally passed define the business of banking to prevent national banks from engaging in risky activities and bars non banking activities from being treated as closely related to banking These restriction would counter regulatory loopholes for risky activities because the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency and the Federal Reserve used these terms to allow traditional banks and bank holding companies to engage in high risk activities address the issue of too big to fail by separating depositary institutions from riskier activities large financial institutions will shrink in size become smaller and safer and won t be able to rely on federal depository insurance as a safety net for their risky activities Although some financial institutions may still be large the implicit government guarantee of a bailout will be reduced because such institutions would no longer be intertwined with depository institutions institutes a five years transition period and penalties for any violation Many of her colleagues remain opposed such as the Senators from Delaware home to the corporate offices of many major banks 16 Volcker rule as Glass Steagall lite editThe Dodd Frank Act included the Volcker Rule which among other things limited proprietary trading by banks and their affiliates 17 This proprietary trading ban was to generally prevent commercial banks and their affiliates from acquiring non governmental securities with the intention of selling those securities for a profit in the near term 18 Some in 2010 have described the Volcker Rule particularly its proprietary trading ban 19 as Glass Steagall lite 20 As described in prohibitions apply to dealing in and underwriting or distributing securities Glass Steagall restricted commercial bank dealing in not trading of non government securities the bank was permitted to purchase as investment securities 21 After the GLBA became law Glass Steagall Section 16 continued to restrict bank securities purchases The GLBA however expanded the list of bank eligible securities to permit banks to buy underwrite and deal in municipal revenue bonds not only full faith and credit government bonds 22 The Volcker Rule permits market making and other dealer activities in non government securities as services for customers 23 Glass Steagall Section 16 prohibits banks from being a market maker or otherwise dealing in non government i e bank ineligible securities 24 Glass Steagall Section 16 permits a bank to purchase and sell i e permits trading for a bank s own account non government securities that the OCC approves as investment securities 21 The Volcker Rule will prohibit such proprietary trading of non government securities 25 Before and after the late 2000s financial crisis banking regulators worried that banks were incorrectly reporting non traded assets as held in their trading account because of lower regulatory capital requirements for assets held in a trading account 26 Under the Volcker Rule U S banking regulators have proposed that banks and their affiliates be prohibited from holding any asset other than government securities and other listed exceptions as a trading position 27 In 2011 Senators Jeff Merkley D OR and Carl Levin D MI wrote that proprietary trading losses played a central role in bringing the financial system to its knees They wrote that the Volcker Rule s proprietary trading ban contained in statutory language they proposed is a modern Glass Steagall because Glass Steagall was both over inclusive in prohibiting some truly client oriented activities that could be managed by developments in securities and banking law and under inclusive in failing to cover derivatives trading 28 In 2002 Arthur Wilmarth wrote that from 1990 1997 the nine U S banks with the greatest securities activities held more than 20 of their assets as trading assets 29 By 1997 40 of J P Morgan s revenue was from trading 30 A 1995 study by the federal banking regulators of commercial bank trading activity from June 30 1984 to June 30 1994 concluded that trading activities are an increasingly important source of revenue for banks and that n otwithstanding the numerous press reports that focus on negative events the major commercial banks have experienced long term success in serving customers and generating revenues with these activities In reporting the study results the American Banker described proprietary trading as basically securities trading not connected to customer related bank activities and summarized the study as finding that proprietary trading has been getting a bad rap 31 Paul Volcker supported the Volcker Rule prohibition on proprietary trading as part of bringing commercial banks back to concentrating on continuing customer interest 32 As described in the article Decline of the Glass Steagall Act Volcker had long testified to Congress in support of repealing Glass Steagall Sections 20 and 32 33 34 35 36 In 2010 he explained that he understood Glass Steagall as preventing banks from being principally engaged in underwriting and dealing in corporate securities Volcker stated that with securitization and other developments he believes it is a proper bank function to underwrite corporate securities as serving a legitimate customer need He therefore did not believe repeal of Glass Steagall was terrible but that Congress should have thought about what they replace it with Volcker s criticism was that Congress didn t replace it with other restrictions 37 Separate from its proprietary trading ban the Volcker Rule restricts bank and affiliate sponsorship and ownership of hedge funds and private equity funds 20 The GLBA amended the Bank Holding Company Act to permit merchant banking investments by bank affiliates subject to various restrictions 38 It also authorized the Treasury Department and Federal Reserve Board to permit such merchant banking activities by direct bank subsidiaries financial subsidiaries after five years but they have not provided such permission 39 This was not a Glass Steagall change but a change to the Bank Holding Company Act which previously limited the size of investments bank affiliates could make in a company engaged in activities not closely related to banking 40 Such merchant banking investments may be made through private equity funds 41 The Volcker Rule will affect the ability of bank affiliates to make such investments 42 Other reform proposals that have been compared to Glass Steagall editBoth in the US and elsewhere a number of reform proposals have been put forward that bear some resemblance to Glass Steagall Ring fencing proposals edit In the UK the Independent Commission on Banking s ICB proposal to ring fence retail and small business commercial banking from investment banking 43 44 seeks to isolate the retail banking functions of a banking firm within a separate corporation that would not be affected by the failure of the overall firm so long as the ring fenced retail bank itself remained solvent 45 Bank of England Governor Mervyn King expressed concern the European Commission could block implementation of the ICB proposal as a violation of Commission standards 46 Although Michel Barnier European Union internal market Commissioner proposed limits on capital requirements for banks that could have hindered the UK ring fencing proposal and indicated support for the French and German position against breaking up banking groups in November 2011 he announced an expert commission would study the mandatory separation of risky investment banking activities from traditional retail lenders 47 In 2016 it was reported that Bank of England would press ahead with plans for banks to ringfence their retail operations by 2019 48 On October 2 2012 the EU committee appointed to study the issue through its Liikanen report recommended a form of ring fencing similar to the proposal in the United Kingdom 49 In April 2013 the Bank for International Settlements has issued a working paper comparing the Volcker Rule the ICB proposals the Liikanen report proposals and other international proposals for bank structural reform 50 Debate on firewalls edit Congressional and bank regulator efforts to repeal reform or apply Glass Steagall were based on isolating a commercial banking firm s expanded securities activities in a separately capitalized bank affiliate 51 52 Much of the debate concerned whether such affiliates could be owned by a bank as with operating subsidiaries in the 1990s or would be bank holding company subsidiaries outside the chain of bank ownership 53 54 In either case firewalls were intended to isolate the bank from the affiliate 55 Banking regulators and commentators debated whether firewalls could truly separate a bank from its affiliate in a crisis and often cited the early 1980s statement by then Citicorp CEO Walter Wriston that it is inconceivable that any major bank would walk away from any subsidiary of its holding company 56 Alan Greenspan and Paul Volcker testified to Congress that firewalls so strong that they truly separated different businesses would eliminate the benefits of combining the two activities 57 Both testified that in a crisis the owners of the overall firm would inevitably find ways to use the assets of any solvent part of the firm to assist the troubled part 57 Thus firewalls sufficient to prevent a bank from assisting its affiliate would eliminate the purpose of the combination but workable firewalls would be insufficient to prevent such assistance Both Volcker and Greenspan proposed that the solution was adequate supervision including sufficient capital and other requirements 57 In 1998 and 1999 Greenspan testified to Congress in opposition to the Clinton Administration proposal to permit national bank subsidiaries to engage in expanded securities and other activities He argued such direct bank subsidiary activities would be financed by the sovereign credit of the United States through the federal safety net for banks despite the Treasury Department s assurance that firewalls between the bank and its operating subsidiary would prevent the expansion of the federal safety net 58 As described in commentator response to Section 20 and 32 repeal Gary Stern Arthur Wilmarth and others questioned whether either operating subsidiaries or separate holding company affiliates could be isolated from an affiliated bank in a financial crisis and feared that the too big to fail doctrine gave competitive benefits to banking firms entering the securities or insurance business through either structure 59 Greenspan did not deny that the government might act to manage an orderly liquidation of a large financial intermediary in a crisis but he suggested that only insured creditors would be fully repaid that shareholders would be unprotected and that uninsured creditors would receive less than full payment through a discount or haircut 60 Commentators pointed to the 1990 failure of Drexel Burnham Lambert as suggesting too big to fail considerations need not force a government rescue of creditors to a failing investment bank or other nonbank 61 although Greenspan had pointed to that experience as questioning the ability of firewalls to isolate one part of a financial firm from the rest 57 After the late 2000s financial crisis commentators noted that the Federal Reserve Board used its power to grant exemptions from Federal Reserve Act Section 23A part of the 1933 Banking Act and the principle statutory firewall between banks and their affiliates to permit banks to rescue various affiliates or bank sponsored participants in the shadow banking system as part of a general effort to restore liquidity in financial markets 62 Section 23A generally prevented banks from funding securities purchases by their affiliates before the financial crisis i e prevented the affiliates from using insured deposits to purchase risky investments by limiting the ability of depository institutions to transfer to affiliates the subsidy arising from the institutions access to the federal safety net but the Federal Reserve Board s exemptions allowed banks to transfer such investments from the shadow banking market to FDIC insured banks during the crisis 63 The Federal Reserve Board s General Counsel has defended these actions by arguing that all the Section 23A exemptions required that bank funding of affiliate or shadow banking investments be fully collateralized on a daily basis with qualifying collateral so that the bank was very much protected and that in the end the exemptions did not prove very useful 64 The ICB proposes to erect a barrier between the ring fenced bank and its wider corporate group that will permit banking regulators to isolate the ring fenced bank from the rest of the group in a matter of days and continue the provision of its services without providing solvency support 65 Limited purpose banking and narrow banking edit Laurence Kotlikoff was disappointed the ICB did not adopt the limited purpose banking he proposed to the ICB 66 67 This would require a bank to operate like a mutual fund in repaying deposits based on the current market value of the bank s assets Kotlikoff argues there will always be financial crises if banks lend deposits but are required to repay the full amount of those deposits on demand 68 Kotlikoff would only permit a bank restructured as a mutual fund to promise payment of deposits at par i e 1 for every 1 deposited if the bank i e mutual fund held 100 of all deposits in cash as a trustee 67 69 As Kotlikoff notes in 1987 Robert Litan proposed narrow banking 70 Litan suggested commercial banking firms be freed from Glass Steagall limits and other activity restrictions so long as they isolated FDIC insured deposits in a narrow bank that was only permitted to invest those deposits in safe securities approved by the FDIC 71 In 1995 Arthur Wilmarth proposed applying Litan s narrow bank proposal to U S banks global banks that had become heavily involved in capital markets activities through Section 20 affiliates derivatives and other activities 72 Under Wilmarth s proposal which he repeated in 2001 after the GLBA became law 73 only banks that limited their activities to taking deposits and making commercial loans would be permitted to make commercial loans with FDIC insured deposits 74 Wilmarth expected only community banks specialized in making consumer and small business loans would continue to operate as such traditional banks 75 The large global banks would fund their lending through the capital markets just like investment banks and other shadow banking lenders 76 Narrow banking and wholesale financial institutions edit The Litan and Wilmarth proposals were very different from the Kotlikoff limited purpose banking proposal in that they would only limit the activities of companies that owned FDIC insured banks Whereas Kotlikoff would require a company to hold the full amount of its demand deposits in cash Litan and Wilmarth would permit companies to issue such demand deposits without restriction so long as the demand deposits were not FDIC insured Congress considered this type of proposal when it debated the repeal of Glass Steagall sections 20 and 32 In 1997 the Clinton Administration proposed that wholesale financial institutions known as woofies be authorized to be members of the Federal Reserve System but not banks under the Bank Holding Company Act because they would own non FDIC insured banks that would only take deposits of 100 000 or more 77 Whereas narrow banks would be FDIC insured but only invest in FDIC approved safe securities woofies would be free to lend purchase securities and make other investments because they would not hold any FDIC insured deposits The proposal was intended to permit securities firms to continue to maintain ownership of commercial firms while gaining access to the Federal Reserve s payment system and discount window so long as the firm did not take FDIC insured deposits 78 Woofies were not authorized by the GLBA because of a dispute between Senator Phil Gramm and the Clinton Administration over the application of the Community Reinvestment Act CRA to woofies In their October 1999 compromise on CRA provisions in the GLBA 79 the Clinton Administration agreed with Gramm that CRA would not apply to woofies so long as only a company that did not then own any FDIC insured depository institution would be permitted to qualify as a wholesale financial institution 80 The Clinton Administration wanted this restriction to prevent existing bank holding companies from disposing of their FDIC insured banks to qualify as woofies which could reduce the deposit base subject to CRA requirements 81 When Chase and J P Morgan lobbied to change the final legislation to permit them to become woofies they complained only Goldman Sachs and a few others could qualify as a woofie 80 81 When negotiators decided they could not resolve the dispute permission for woofies was eliminated from the final GLBA 80 81 Woofies were similar to the global bank structure suggested by Arthur Wilmarth because they would not use FDIC insured deposits to make commercial loans They would however be subject to Federal Reserve supervision unlike lenders in the unsupervised shadow banking system Because woofies would have had access to the Federal Reserve discount window and payments service critics including the Independent Bankers Association of America and Paul Volcker opposed woofies and a similar 1996 proposal by Representative James A Leach for providing unfair competition to banks 82 Although October 1999 press reports suggested bank holding companies were interested in becoming woofies 80 81 the New York Times reported in July 1999 that banking and securities firms had lost interest in becoming woofies 83 Shadow banking in financial reform proposals edit The ICB Report rejected narrow banking in part because it would lead to more credit and all credit during times of stress being provided by a less regulated sector 84 In 1993 Jane D Arista and Tom Schlesinger noted that the parallel banking system had grown because it did not incur the regulatory costs of commercial banks 85 They proposed to equalize the cost by establishing uniform regulation of banks and the lenders and investors in the parallel banking system 86 As with Kotlikoff s limited purpose banking proposal only investment pools funded 100 from equity interests would remain unregulated as banks 87 Although D Arista and Schlesinger acknowledged the regulation of banks and of the parallel banking system would end up only being comparable their goal was to eliminate so far as possible the competitive advantages of the parallel or shadow banking market 88 Many commentators have argued that the failure to regulate the shadow banking market was a primary cause of the financial crisis 89 90 There is general agreement that the crisis emerged in the shadow banking markets not in the traditional banking market 91 As described in the article Decline of the Glass Steagall Act Helen Garten had identified the consumerization of banking regulation as producing a largely unregulated sophisticated wholesale market 92 which created the risk of the underproduction of regulation of that market 93 Laurence Kotlikoff s limited purpose banking proposal rejects bank regulation based on rules and supervision to ensure safety and soundness and replaces it with a prohibition on any company operating like a traditional bank All limited liability financial companies not only today s banks that receive money from the public for investment or lending and that issue promises to pay amounts in the future whether as insurance companies hedge funds securities firms or otherwise could only issue obligations to repay amounts equal to the value of their assets 67 94 All depositors in or lenders to such companies would become investors as in a mutual fund with the right to receive the full return on the investments made by the companies minus fees and obligated to bear the full loss on those investments 67 95 Thomas Hoenig rejects both limited purpose banking and the proposal to regulate shadow banking as part of the banking system Hoenig argues it is not necessary to regulate shadow banking system lenders as banks if those lenders are prohibited from issuing liabilities that function like bank demand deposits He suggests that requiring money market funds to redeem shares at the funds fluctuating daily net asset values would prevent those funds from functioning like bank checking accounts and that eliminating special Bankruptcy Code treatment for repurchase agreements would delay repayment of those transactions in a bankruptcy and thereby end their treatment as cash equivalents when the repo was funding illiquid long term securities By limiting the ability of shadow banks to compete with traditional banks in creating money like instruments Hoenig hopes to better assure that the safety net is not ultimately called upon to bail them i e shadow banks such as Bear Stearns and AIG during the financial crisis out in a crisis He proposes to deal with actual commercial banks by imposing Glass Steagall type boundaries so that banks that have access to the safety net should be restricted to certain core activities that the safety net was intended to protect making loans and taking deposits and related activities consistent with the presence of the safety net 96 Glass Steagall references in financial reform proposals edit Although the UK s ICB and the commentators presenting the proposals described above to modify banks or banking regulation address issues beyond the scope of the Glass Steagall separation of commercial and investment banking each specifically examines Glass Steagall The ICB stated Glass Steagall had been undermined in part by the development of derivatives 97 The ICB also argued that the development before 1999 of the world s leading investment banks out of the US despite Glass Steagall in place at the time should caution against assuming the activity restrictions it recommended in its ring fencing proposal would hinder UK investment banks from competing internationally 98 Boston University economist Laurence J Kotlikoff suggests commercial banks only became involved with CDOs SIVs and other risky products after Glass Steagall was repealed but he rejects Glass Steagall reinstatement after suggesting Paul Volcker favors it as a non starter because it would give the nonbank shadow bank investment bank industry a competitive advantage without requiring it to pay for the implicit lender of last resort protection it receives from the government 99 Robert Litan and Arthur Wilmarth presented their narrow bank proposals as a basis for eliminating Glass Steagall and other restrictions on bank affiliates 100 Writing in 1993 Jane D Artista and Tom Schlesinger noted that the ongoing integration of financial industry activities makes it increasingly difficult to separate banking and securities operations meaningfully but rejected Glass Steagall repeal because the separation of banking and securities functions is a proven least cost method of preventing the problems of one financial sector from spilling over into the other which they stated was most recently demonstrated in the October 1987 market crash 101 During the Senate debate of the bill that became the Dodd Frank Act Thomas Hoenig wrote Senators Maria Cantwell and John McCain the co sponsors of legislation to reinstate Glass Steagall Sections 20 and 32 supporting a substantive debate on the unintended consequences of leaving investment banking commingled with commercial banking and reiterating that he had long supported reinstating Glass Steagall type laws to separate higher risk often more leveraged activities of investment banks from commercial banking As described above in post 2010 efforts to enact Glass Steagall inspired financial reform legislation Elizabeth Warren and other senators have joined Cantwell and McCain in their effort to legislate Glass Steagall inspired restrictions 102 Hoenig agreed with Paul Volcker however that financial market developments had caused underwriting corporate bonds the prohibition of which Volcker described as the purpose of Glass Steagall 37 and also underwriting of corporate equity revenue bonds and high quality asset backed securities to be natural extensions of commercial banking Instead of reinstating Glass Steagall prohibitions on such underwriting Hoenig proposed restoring the principles underlying the separation of commercial and investment banking firms 103 In Mainland Europe some scholars have suggested Glass Steagall should be a model for any in depth reform of bank regulation notably in France where SFAF and World Pensions Council WPC banking experts have argued that a new Glass Steagall Act should be viewed within the broader context of separation of powers in European Union law 104 This perspective has gained ground after the unraveling of the Libor scandal in July 2012 with mainstream opinion leaders such as the Financial Times editorialists calling for the adoption of an EU wide Glass Steagall II 105 On July 25 2012 former Citigroup Chairman and CEO Sandy Weill considered one of the driving forces behind the considerable financial deregulation and mega mergers of the 1990s surprised financial analysts in Europe and North America by calling for splitting up the commercial banks from the investment banks In effect he says bring back the Glass Steagall Act of 1933 which led to half a century free of financial crises 106 However Weill reversed his position a year later arguing that big banks don t have to be split if the right regulation is in place and instead that banks should decide on their own to split if they figure that s the best way that they can provide their services 107 See also edit nbsp Economics portalGramm Leach Bliley Act Securities regulation in the United StatesReferences edit a b c Robert Scheer 2010 01 06 McCain Gets It Obama Doesn t The Nation S 2866 Bill Summary amp Status CRS 2010a pp 1 and 13 15 MacArthur John R December 14 2011 President Obama Richly Deserves to Be Dumped The Providence Journal p 2 the administration steadfastly opposes the restoration of the Glass Steagall Act retrieved February 22 2012 Sloan Stephen Hopkins Cheyenne January 27 2010 Obama Plan Has Shades of Glass Steagall Act American Banker p 2 I would not support reinstating Glass Steagall and I don t actually believe that the end of Glass Steagall played a significant role in the cause of the crisis Geithner told the Joint Economic Committee in November retrieved February 22 2012 Financial Regulatory Reform Protecting Taxpayers and the Economy Hearing before the Joint Economic Committee Congress of the United States PDF Government Printing Office November 19 2009 p 19 retrieved February 22 2012 CRS 2010a pp 8 9 Cook Merrill July 20 2011 Support the Kaptur Jones Prudent Banking Act of 2011 H R 1489 Standard Examiner Ogden Utah p 2 retrieved February 22 2012 Bill Text 112th Congress 2011 2012 H R 1489 IH Congress gov Library of Congress retrieved February 22 2012 Bill Summary amp Status 112th Congress 2011 2012 H R 1489 CRS Summary Congress gov Library of Congress retrieved February 22 2012 Tom Harkin introduces Glass Steagall bill Daily Kos May 20 2013 Matthews Dylan 12 July 2013 Elizabeth Warren and John McCain want Glass Steagall back Should you The Washington Post Retrieved 15 September 2013 Warren Elizabeth 11 July 2013 Bill Summary amp Status 113th Congress 2013 2014 S 1282 Congress gov Library of Congress Retrieved 15 September 2013 Warren Elisabeth 11 July 2013 21st Century Glass Steagall Act of 2013 PDF Retrieved 15 September 2013 a b Warren Elizabeth 11 July 2013 Senators Warren McCain Cantwell and King Introduce 21st Century Glass Steagall Act Retrieved 15 September 2013 Carter Zach 11 July 2013 Glass Steagall Act Would Be Revived In New Bill From Elizabeth Warren Bipartisan Coalition The Huffington Post Retrieved 15 September 2013 Warren Elizabeth 13 July 2013 21st Century Glass Steagall Act Fact Sheet PDF www warren senate gov Retrieved 15 September 2013 Warren Elizabeth S A Billt PDF www warren senate gov Retrieved 17 October 2013 Starkey Jonathan Delaware lawmakers among opponents to resurrecting bank law Delaware Online Gannett 21 Jul 2013 Chapman and Cutler LLP 2010 Whitehead 2011 p 47 Whitehead 2011 p 48 Chapman and Cutler LLP 2010 p 1 Watson Bruce October 12 2011 Volcker Rule Made Simple Banks Can t Gamble With Our Money Probably Daily Finance retrieved February 20 2012 a b Glass Steagall lite The Economist January 22 2010 retrieved February 20 2012 Copeland Laurence January 25 2010 Glass Steagall Lite brewed by Volcker served by Obama The Great Debate UK Reuters archived from the original on 2010 01 28 retrieved July 18 2023 a b Fein 2011 4 04 C p 4 30 and 7 06 A pp 7 90 to 7 91 Capatides 1992 p 201 C amp B 1999 p 12 Supervisory guidance relating to a change to permissible securities activities of state member banks SR 01 13 Washington D C Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System p 1 May 14 2001 retrieved February 16 2012 Whitehead 2011 p 50 Fein 2011 7 06 A p 7 90 CRS 2010a p 5 Whitehead 2011 pp 48 49 Rowe David March 2006 Regulatory arbitrage back to basics PDF Risk Magazine p 66 retrieved February 20 2012 Caresana Annalisa January 2009 Regulatory capital for banks trading activities set to increase to eliminate regulatory arbitrage between trading book and banking book Technical Update Adkins Matchett amp Toy retrieved February 20 2012 Norris Floyd October 14 2011 Bank Rules That Serve Two Masters New York Times p B1 retrieved February 20 2012 Merkley Jeff Levin Carl 2011 The Dodd Frank Act Restrictions on Proprietary Trading and Conflicts of Interest New Tools to Address Evolving Threats PDF Harvard Journal of Legislation 48 2 530 and 538 539 retrieved February 25 2012 Wilmarth 2002 p 374 Wilmarth 2002 p 374 fn 665 de Senerpont Domas Olaf December 7 1995 Bank Trading Losses Minimal and Risks Limited U S Says American Banker p 24 Fein 2011 7 06 A p 7 91 Staff Paper Released On Trading Activities At Commercial Banks NR 95 134 PDF Press release Office of the Comptroller of the Currency Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation and Federal Reserve Board December 6 1999 Retrieved February 19 2012 Dixon Kim Witkowski Karey March 30 2010 Volcker Proprietary trading not central to crisis Reuters retrieved February 19 2012 Volcker Paul March 30 2010 Essential Elements of Financial Reform Transcript of speech delivered at the Peterson Institute retrieved February 19 2012 Reinicke 1995 pp 71 for opposition to underwriting corporate bonds 74 and 76 Volcker Paul January 16 1984 Statement before the Committee on Banking Housing and Urban Affairs United States Senate PDF pp 2 3 and 7 8 retrieved October 16 2014 Garrson Robert M May 9 1991 Volcker Public Must Re Fund Bank Insurance American Banker Canan Martha M April 6 1995 Leach Pushes Back Debate on Bank Reform to May 9 Bond Buyer Volcker 1997a I have argued this morning the logic and practical desirability of finally eliminating Glass Steagall restrictions Volcker Paul September 10 1998 Boost for Banking Washington Post p A21 Op Ed a b Conference Proceedings 19th Annual Hyman P Minsky Conference on the State of the U S and World Economies After the Crisis Planning a New Financial Structure PDF Levy Economics Institute of Bard College April 14 16 2010 p 113 retrieved February 20 2012 CRS 2010b pp 5 7 Fein 2011 8 01 and 8 02 D p 8 3 to 8 5 CRS 2010b p 9 fn 60 Fein 2011 8 03 D p 8 12 Lockner and Hansche 2000 p 37 CRS 2010b pp 6 8 Fein 2011 7 08 G pp 7 119 to 7 126 and 8 04 p 8 15 ICB 2011 Hutton Will August 31 2011 Banking reform ringfencing is the only solution The Guardian retrieved February 21 2012 Goff Sharlene August 31 2011 Just the facts the Vickers Report Financial Times retrieved February 21 2012 Samuel Juliet November 4 2011 King EU could veto Vickers City A M retrieved February 21 2012 Pignal Stanley Barker Alex November 22 2011 Barnier panel to study break up of EU banks Financial Times retrieved February 21 2012 Binham Caroline May 26 2016 BoE sets out capital rules for ringfenced banks The Financial Times Retrieved 25 February 2017 Expert report suggests Europe s banks ring fence investment banking from retail banking Washington Post Associated Press October 2 2012 retrieved October 9 2012 dead link Final Report PDF High level Expert Group on reforming the structure of the EU banking sector October 2 2012 retrieved October 9 2012 Leonardo Gambacorta Adrian van Rixtel April 2013 BIS Working Papers No 412 Structural bank regulation inititatives approaches and implictions PDF Bank for International Settlements retrieved October 15 2013 Fisher Keith R 1992 Reweaving the Safety Net Bank Diversification into Securities and Insurance Activities Wake Forest Law Review 27 1 231 247 retrieved February 25 2012 Banking Reform Deformed editorial New York Times p A26 October 31 1991 Murphy Brian D Haring Sherri S 1997 Removal of Three Section 20 Firewalls Enhances Opportunities for One Stop Shopping in the Financial Services Industry McGuire Woods LLP retrieved February 13 2012 Rodelli 1998 pp 321 326 Phil FRB 1999 pp 1 2 Wagner 2000 pp 335 337 and 382 424 Fein 2011 1 04 B pp 1 21 to 1 22 Shull and White 1998 pp 1 8 10 and 14 17 Shull and White 1998 p 8 England Catherine 1991 Governing Banking s Future Markets vs Regulation Boston Kluwer Academic p 65 ISBN 9780792391609 retrieved February 22 2012 Wilmarth 2001 p 22 fn 37 a b c d Shull and White 1998 pp 8 9 for Greenspan in 1990 Testimony by Alan Greenspan Chairman Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System before the Committee on Banking Housing amp Urban Affairs United States Senate July 12 1990 PDF July 12 1990 pp 14 15 retrieved October 16 2014 Rodelli 1998 p 316 fn 35 for Volcker in 1995 Volcker 1997b pp 3 4 Firewalls Fein 2011 1 04 B p 1 22 Wells Rob April 29 1999 Fed Chief Discourages New Bank Powers Says Pending Bill Would Give Unfair Advantage Bloomberg News Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan before the Committee on Banking Housing and Urban Affairs U S Senate June 17 1998 H R 10 the Financial Services Act of 1998 Federal Reserve Board June 17 1998 pp 10 13 Operating Subsidiaries vs Holding Companies retrieved February 22 2012 Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan before the Subcommittee on Finance and Hazardous Materials Committee on Commerce U S House of Representatives H R 10 and financial modernization Federal Reserve Board April 28 1999 pp 1 6 Operating Subsidiaries retrieved February 22 2012 Stern 2000 Stern and Feldman 2004 p 77 Wilmarth 2001 p 22 Wilmarth 2002 pp 224 225 Stern 2000 p 9 Remarks of Chairman Alan Greenspan at the 36th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Banking evolution Federal Reserve Board May 4 2000 p 3 retrieved February 23 2012 Wilmarth 1995 p 82 Omarova 2011 pp 1725 1756 Omarova 2011 pp 1689 1690 1728 and 1734 Alvarez Scott March 23 2010 FCIC Interview of Scott Alvarez and Kieran Fallon PDF Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission pp 62 67 retrieved October 9 2012 ICB 2011 pp 235 236 Why the Vickers Report failed the UK and the World Economists Forum Financial Times September 20 2011 retrieved February 6 2012 a b c d Kotlikoff Laurence January 28 2011 Open letter to Sir John Vickers on his banking reform speech Economists Forum Financial Times retrieved February 6 2012 Kotlikoff 2010 pp 84 89 Kotlikoff 2010 pp 123 124 and 131 132 Kotlikoff 2010 p 132 Litan 1987 pp 70 71 and 164 178 Wilmarth 1995 pp 77 87 Wilmarth 2001 pp 73 81 Wilmarth 1995 pp 81 83 Wilmarth 2001 pp 80 81 Wilmarth 1995 pp 82 3 Wilmarth 2001 pp 79 80 Wilmarth 1995 pp 86 87 Wilmarth 2001 pp 80 81 Pottinger Matt June 4 1997 Rubin Pitches Plan on Bank Deregulation Chicago Tribune p 1 Hawke Jr John D June 3 1997 Text as Prepared for Delivery Treasury Undersecretary For Domestic Finance John D Hawke House Banking and Financial Services p 3 Wholesale Financial Institutions retrieved February 21 2012 Taylor Andrew May 24 1997 BANKING Under Treasury Plan Congress to Decide Tough Issues CQ Weekly Washington D C 1190 Levitt 1998 A Competitive Two Way Street Wayne Leslie July 7 1999 Push for Wholesale Banks stalls in Overhaul of Law New York Times p 2 retrieved February 21 2012 Phil FRB 1999 pp 1 2 Parks Daniel J October 23 1999 BANKING Financial Services Bill in the Final Stretch CQ Weekly Washington D C 2498 2503 a b c d Day Kathleen October 28 1999 Wholesale Banks Cut from Overhaul Bill Washington Post p E 02 a b c d Anason Dean October 28 1999 Capital Briefs Wholesale Banking Cut from Reform Bill American Banker p 2 Statement of The Independent Bankers Association of America before the Committee on Banking and Financial Services U S House of Representatives on Financial Restructuring Press release The Committee on Financial Services May 7 1997 p 5 Wholesale Financial Institutions Retrieved February 22 2012 de Senerpont Domas Olaf April 6 1995 Volcker Plays Down Usefulness of Firewalls in Remarks to Panel American Banker p 2 Why should this particular class of institution be free of federal deposit insurance when it will be competing side by side with banks that have to pay deposit insurance premiums Wayne Leslie July 7 1999 Push for Wholesale Banks stalls in Overhaul of Law New York Times p 2 retrieved February 21 2012 ICB 2011 Chapter 3 21 p 44 D Arista and Schlesinger 1993 pp 11 14 D Arista and Schlesinger 1993 p 32 38 D Arista and Schlesinger 1993 p 34 D Arista and Schlesinger 1993 pp 36 37 Date Raj Konczal Michael March 2011 Out of the Shadows Creating a 21st Century Glass Steagall Make Markets Be Markets PDF Roosevelt Institute p 61 retrieved February 6 2012 Date and Konczal 2011 p 61 FCIC 2011 pp xvii xx 27 37 255 414 and 469 Gorton Gary Metrick Andrew October 18 2010 Regulating the Shadow Banking System pp 15 16 SSRN 1676947 FCIC 2011 pp 245 275 343 427 446 and 478 Garten 1999 p 293 Garten 1999 pp 304 307 Kotlikoff 2010 pp 122 124 Kotlikoff 2010 pp 126 and 131 154 Hoenig Thomas June 27 2011 Do SIFIs Have a Future PDF Keynote remarks to Dodd Frank One Year On Pew Financial Reform Project and New York University Stern School of Business Conference Washington D C Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City pp 5 and 7 8 retrieved February 22 2012 ICB 2011 p 36 fn 1 ICB 2011 p 146 Kotlikoff 2010 p 151 Litan 1987 pp 164 178 Wilmarth 1995 pp 80 82 D Arista and Schlesinger 1993 pp 6 7 Warren Joins McCain to Push New Glass Steagall Law for Banks Bloomberg Hoenig Thomas May 10 2010 Letter to The Honorable Senator Maria Cantwell and The Honorable Senator John McCain PDF Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City retrieved February 22 2012 M Nicolas J Firzli quoted by Marie Lepesant June 11 2012 Le Modele des Banques Francaises en Question Le Parisien Aujourd hui en France Retrieved 12 June 2012 Editorial Page July 3 2012 Restoring trust after Diamond Financial Times Retrieved 15 July 2012 quoting FT Editorial Page Denning Steve July 25 2012 Rethinking Capitalism Sandy Weill Says Bring Back Glass Steagall Forbes Retrieved 25 July 2012 Quoting interview on CNBC s Squawk Box Belvidere Matthew J September 10 2013 Big banks don t need to be split up Sandy Weill CNBC com Retrieved 19 October 2013 Works cited edit Carpenter David H Murphy M Maureen 2010a Permissible Securities Activities of Commercial Banks Under the Glass Steagall Act GSA and the Gramm Leach Bliley Act GLBA PDF Congressional Research Service Report no R41181 archived from the original PDF on August 4 2012 retrieved February 10 2012 Carpenter David H Murphy M Maureen 2010b The Volcker Rule Proposals to Limit Speculative Proprietary Trading by Banks PDF Congressional Research Service Report no R41298 retrieved February 10 2012 Covington amp Burling November 12 1999 Financial Modernization The Gramm Leach Bliley Act Summary PDF American Bankers Association retrieved February 24 2012 Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission 2011 The Financial Crisis Inquiry Report Final Report of the National Commission on the Causes of the Financial and Economic Crisis in the United States PDF archived from the original PDF on January 12 2012 retrieved February 24 2012 Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia 1999 Recent Developments Financial Services Reform Enacted PDF Banking Legislation amp Policy 18 4 1 4 retrieved February 24 2012 Independent Commission on Banking September 2011 Final Report Recommendations PDF pp 1 354 archived from the original PDF on March 18 2012 retrieved February 24 2012 Volcker Paul A February 25 1997 Statement before the Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit United States House of Representatives The Committee on Financial Services United States House of Representatives archived from the original on October 17 2012 retrieved February 25 2012 Volcker Paul A May 14 1997 Statement before the Committee on Banking and Financial Services United States House of Representativesv The Committee on Financial Services United States House of Representatives archived from the original on October 17 2012 retrieved February 25 2012 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Glass Steagall in post financial crisis reform debate amp oldid 1200438417, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.