fbpx
Wikipedia

François Quesnay

François Quesnay (French: [fʁɑ̃swa kɛnɛ]; 4 June 1694 – 16 December 1774) was a French economist and physician of the Physiocratic school.[1] He is known for publishing the "Tableau économique" (Economic Table) in 1758, which provided the foundations of the ideas of the Physiocrats.[2] This was perhaps the first work attempting to describe the workings of the economy in an analytical way, and as such can be viewed as one of the first important contributions to economic thought. His Le Despotisme de la Chine, written in 1767, describes Chinese politics and society, and his own political support for enlightened despotism.[3]

François Quesnay
Born(1694-06-04)4 June 1694
Died16 December 1774(1774-12-16) (aged 80)
EraAge of Enlightenment
RegionWestern philosophy
SchoolPhysiocrats
Main interests
Political economy, sinology
Notable ideas
Laissez-faire

Life edit

Quesnay was born at Méré near Versailles, the son of an advocate and small landed proprietor. Apprenticed at the age of sixteen to a surgeon, he soon went to Paris, studied medicine and surgery there, and, having qualified as a master-surgeon, settled down to practice at Mantes. In 1737 he was appointed perpetual secretary of the academy of surgery founded by François Gigot de la Peyronie, and became surgeon in ordinary to King Louis XV. In 1744 he graduated as a doctor of medicine; he became physician in ordinary to the king, and afterwards his first consulting physician, and was installed in the Palace of Versailles. His apartments were on the entresol, whence the Réunions de l'entresol[clarification needed] received their name. Louis XV esteemed Quesnay highly, and used to call him his thinker. When he ennobled him he gave him for arms three flowers of the pansy[4] (derived from pensée, in French meaning thought), with the Latin motto Propter cogitationem mentis.[5]

He now devoted himself principally to economic studies, taking no part in the court intrigues which were perpetually going on around him. Around 1750 he became acquainted with Jacques C. M. V. de Gournay (1712–1759), who was also an earnest inquirer in the economic field; and round these two distinguished men was gradually formed the philosophic sect of the Économistes, or, as for distinction's sake they were afterwards called, the Physiocrates. The most remarkable men in this group of disciples were the elder Mirabeau (author of L'Ami des hommes, 1756–60, and Philosophie rurale, 1763), Nicolas Baudeau (Introduction a la philosophie économique, 1771), Guillaume-François Le Trosne (De l'ordre social, 1777), André Morellet (best known by his controversy with Galiani on the freedom of the grain trade during the Flour War), Lemercier de La Rivière, and du Pont de Nemours. Adam Smith, during his stay on the continent with the young Duke of Buccleuch in 1764–1766, spent some time in Paris, where he made the acquaintance of Quesnay and some of his followers; he paid a high tribute to their scientific services in his Wealth of Nations.[6][4]

Quesnay was married in 1718 to a woman named Marianne Woodsen, and had a son and a daughter; his grandson by the former was a member of the first Legislative Assembly. He died on 16 December 1774, having lived long enough to see his great pupil, Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, Baron de Laune, in office as minister of finance.[4]

Works edit

 
Tableau économique

His economic writings are collected in the 2nd vol. of the Principaux économistes, published by Guillaumin, Paris, with preface and notes by Eugène Daire; also his Oeuvres économiques et philosophiques were collected with an introduction and note by August Oncken (Frankfort, 1888); a facsimile reprint of the Tableau économique, from the original MS., was published by the British Economic Association (London, 1895). His other writings were the article "Évidence" in the Encyclopédie, and Recherches sur l'évidence des vérites geometriques, with a Projet de nouveaux éléments de géometrie, 1773. Quesnay's Eloge was pronounced in the Academy of Sciences by Grandjean de Fouchy (see the Recueil of that Academy, 1774, p. 134). See also F.J. Marmontel, Mémoires; Mémoires de Mme. du Hausset; H. Higgs, The Physiocrats (London, 1897).[4]

Economics edit

 
Tableau economique, 1965

In 1758 he published the Tableau économique (Economic Table), which provided the foundations of the ideas of the Physiocrats. This was perhaps the first work to attempt to describe the workings of the economy in an analytical way, and as such can be viewed as one of the first important contributions to economic thought.[7]

The publications in which Quesnay expounded his system were the following: two articles, on "Fermiers" (Farmers) and on "Grains", in the Encyclopédie of Diderot and Jean le Rond d'Alembert (1756, 1757);[8][4] a discourse on the law of nature in the Physiocratie of Dupont de Nemours (1768); Maximes générales de gouvernement economique d'un royaume agricole (1758), and the simultaneously published Tableau économique avec son explication, ou extrait des économies royales de Sully (with the celebrated motto, Pauvres paysans, pauvre royaume; pauvre royaume, pauvre roi); Dialogue sur le commerce et les travaux des artisans; and other minor pieces.[4]

The Tableau économique, though on account of its dryness and abstract form it met with little general favor, may be considered the principal manifesto of the school. It was regarded by the followers of Quesnay as entitled to a place amongst the foremost products of human wisdom, and is named by the elder Mirabeau, in a passage quoted by Adam Smith,[6] as one of the three great inventions which have contributed most to the stability of political societies, the other two being those of writing and of money. Its object was to exhibit by means of certain formulas the way in which the products of agriculture, which is the only source of wealth, would in a state of perfect liberty be distributed among the several classes of the community (namely, the productive classes of the proprietors and cultivators of land, and the unproductive class composed of manufacturers and merchants), and to represent by other formulas the modes of distribution which take place under systems of Governmental restraint and regulation, with the evil results arising to the whole society from different degrees of such violations of the natural order. It follows from Quesnay's theoretic views that the one thing deserving the solicitude of the practical economist and the statesman is the increase of the net product; and he infers also what Smith afterwards affirmed, on not quite the same ground, that the interest of the landowner is strictly and indissolubly connected with the general interest of the society. A small edition de luxe of this work, with other pieces, was printed in 1758 in the Palace of Versailles under the king's immediate supervision, some of the sheets, it is said, having been pulled by the royal hand. Already in 1767 the book had disappeared from circulation, and no copy of it is now procurable; but, the substance of it has been preserved in the Ami des hommes of Mirabeau, and the Physiocratie of Dupont de Nemours.[4]

Orientalism and China edit

Quesnay is known for his writings on Chinese politics and society. His book Le Despotisme de la Chine, written in 1767, describes his views of the Chinese imperial system.[3] He was supportive of the meritocratic concept of giving scholars political power, without the cumbersome aristocracy that characterized French politics, and the importance of agriculture to the welfare of a nation. Gregory Blue writes that Quesnay "praised China as a constitutional despotism and openly advocated the adoption of Chinese institutions, including a standardized system of taxation and universal education." Blue speculates that this may have influenced the 1793 establishment of the Permanent Settlement in Bengal by the British Empire.[9] Quesnay's interests in Orientalism has also been a source of criticism. Carol Blum, in her book Strength in Numbers on 18th century France, labels Quesnay an "apologist for Oriental despotism."[10]

Because of his admiration of Confucianism, Quesnay's followers bestowed him with the title "Confucius of Europe."[11] Quesnay's infatuation for Chinese culture, as described by Jesuits, led him to persuade the son of Louis XV to mirror the "plowing of sacred land" by the Chinese emperor to symbolize the link between government and agriculture.[12]

On Taxation

Quesnay acknowledged three economic classes in France: the "proprietary" class consisting of only landowners, the "productive" class of agricultural workers, and the "sterile" class of merchants. Quesnay saw no benefit to the sterile class and believed the productive to be all important. Quesnay viewed France's agriculture as backward and unproductive compared to Britain during the time he was residing in the Palace of Versailles [13] . Despite residing in the Palace, Quesnay believed agriculture was the heart of the economy and of special importance to him. Quesnay argued that taxes placed on cultivators are only harmful to society as these taxes will reduce the incentive for agricultural production. Taxing proprietors (property holders) does not destroy the means of production meaning there is no decline in output. Quesnay wanted proprietors to bear the full burden of the tax in the country as taxing cultivators is a negative consequence for everyone. Removing incentive from cultivators reduces agricultural production and the agricultural surplus Quesnay believed to be the heart of the economy [14]. Quesnay also opposed indirect taxes in contrast to direct taxes. These "indirect taxes" are placed on the French public by proprietors whose greed demands immunity from taxation. Direct taxes on proprietors has no impact on reproduction and economic decline [14]. Reducing indirect taxes and increasing direct taxes gives the French a surplus of agriculture and the funding the country needs. However, this opinion was not very popular among the wealthy of which Quesnay spent time regularly with. He spent some of his time fearing for his life in the Palace.

See also edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ Cutler J. Cleveland, "Biophysical economics", Encyclopedia of Earth, Last updated: 14 September 2006.
  2. ^ See the biographical note in the Collected Works of Karl Marx and Frederick Engels: Volume 31 (International Publishers: New York, 1989) p. 605.
  3. ^ a b Ina Baghdiantz McCabe (15 July 2008). Orientalism in Early Modern France: Eurasian Trade, Exoticism and the Ancien Regime. Berg Publishers. pp. 271–72. ISBN 978-1-84520-374-0.
  4. ^ a b c d e f g   One or more of the preceding sentences incorporates text from a publication now in the public domainChisholm, Hugh, ed. (1911). "Quesnay, François". Encyclopædia Britannica. Vol. 22 (11th ed.). Cambridge University Press. pp. 742–743.
  5. ^ "Nouvelles Ephemerides, Économiques, Seconde Partie, Analyses, Et Critiques Raisonnées. N° Premier. Éloge Historique De M. Quesnay, Contenant L'Analyse De Ses Ouvrages, Par M. Le Cte D'A***". Taieb.net. Retrieved 16 August 2012.
  6. ^ a b Smith, Adam, 1937, The Wealth of Nations, N. Y.: Random House, p. 643; first published 1776.
  7. ^ Phillip Anthony O'Hara (1999). Encyclopedia of Political Economy. Psychology Press. p. 848. ISBN 978-0-415-18718-3. Retrieved 21 July 2012.
  8. ^ Kafker, Frank A.; Chouillet, Jacques (1990). "Kafker, Frank A.: Notices sur les auteurs des 17 volumes de « discours » de l'Encyclopédie (suite et fin). Recherches sur Diderot et sur l'Encyclopédie Année (1990) Volume 8 Numéro 8 p. 112". Recherches Sur Diderot et Sur l'Encyclopédie. 8 (1): 101–121.
  9. ^ E. S. Shaffer (30 November 2000). Comparative Criticism: Volume 22, East and West: Comparative Perspectives. Cambridge University Press. pp. 239–40. ISBN 978-0-521-79072-7.
  10. ^ Carol Blum (5 February 2002). Strength in Numbers: Population, Reproduction, and Power in Eighteenth-Century France. JHU Press. p. 16. ISBN 978-0-8018-6810-8.
  11. ^ Murray N. Rothbard (2006). Economic Thought Before Adam Smith. Ludwig von Mises Institute. p. 366. ISBN 978-0-945466-48-2.
  12. ^ Geoffrey C. Gunn (2003). First Globalization: The Eurasian Exchange, 1500 to 1800. Rowman & Littlefield. p. 148. ISBN 978-0-7425-2662-4.

References edit

  • Hobson, John M. (2004), The Eastern Origins of Western Civilization, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 0-521-54724-5.

External links edit

  • Works by or about François Quesnay at Internet Archive
  • Le Despotisme de la Chine (1767) by François Quesnay, hosted on the University of Massachusetts website
  • François Quesnay (1694–1774). Library of Economics and Liberty (2nd ed.). Liberty Fund. 2008. {{cite book}}: |work= ignored (help)
  • François Quesnay (June 1766). "Analyse de la formule arithmétique du tableau économiqueu de la distribution des dépenses annuelles d'une Nation agricole". Journal de l'Agriculture, du Commerce et des Finances. 2 (3): 11–41.

françois, quesnay, french, fʁɑ, kɛnɛ, june, 1694, december, 1774, french, economist, physician, physiocratic, school, known, publishing, tableau, économique, economic, table, 1758, which, provided, foundations, ideas, physiocrats, this, perhaps, first, work, a. Francois Quesnay French fʁɑ swa kɛnɛ 4 June 1694 16 December 1774 was a French economist and physician of the Physiocratic school 1 He is known for publishing the Tableau economique Economic Table in 1758 which provided the foundations of the ideas of the Physiocrats 2 This was perhaps the first work attempting to describe the workings of the economy in an analytical way and as such can be viewed as one of the first important contributions to economic thought His Le Despotisme de la Chine written in 1767 describes Chinese politics and society and his own political support for enlightened despotism 3 Francois QuesnayBorn 1694 06 04 4 June 1694Mere near VersaillesDied16 December 1774 1774 12 16 aged 80 VersaillesEraAge of EnlightenmentRegionWestern philosophy French philosophySchoolPhysiocratsMain interestsPolitical economy sinologyNotable ideasLaissez faire Contents 1 Life 2 Works 2 1 Economics 2 2 Orientalism and China 3 See also 4 Notes 5 References 6 External linksLife editQuesnay was born at Mere near Versailles the son of an advocate and small landed proprietor Apprenticed at the age of sixteen to a surgeon he soon went to Paris studied medicine and surgery there and having qualified as a master surgeon settled down to practice at Mantes In 1737 he was appointed perpetual secretary of the academy of surgery founded by Francois Gigot de la Peyronie and became surgeon in ordinary to King Louis XV In 1744 he graduated as a doctor of medicine he became physician in ordinary to the king and afterwards his first consulting physician and was installed in the Palace of Versailles His apartments were on the entresol whence the Reunions de l entresol clarification needed received their name Louis XV esteemed Quesnay highly and used to call him his thinker When he ennobled him he gave him for arms three flowers of the pansy 4 derived from pensee in French meaning thought with the Latin motto Propter cogitationem mentis 5 He now devoted himself principally to economic studies taking no part in the court intrigues which were perpetually going on around him Around 1750 he became acquainted with Jacques C M V de Gournay 1712 1759 who was also an earnest inquirer in the economic field and round these two distinguished men was gradually formed the philosophic sect of the Economistes or as for distinction s sake they were afterwards called the Physiocrates The most remarkable men in this group of disciples were the elder Mirabeau author of L Ami des hommes 1756 60 and Philosophie rurale 1763 Nicolas Baudeau Introduction a la philosophie economique 1771 Guillaume Francois Le Trosne De l ordre social 1777 Andre Morellet best known by his controversy with Galiani on the freedom of the grain trade during the Flour War Lemercier de La Riviere and du Pont de Nemours Adam Smith during his stay on the continent with the young Duke of Buccleuch in 1764 1766 spent some time in Paris where he made the acquaintance of Quesnay and some of his followers he paid a high tribute to their scientific services in his Wealth of Nations 6 4 Quesnay was married in 1718 to a woman named Marianne Woodsen and had a son and a daughter his grandson by the former was a member of the first Legislative Assembly He died on 16 December 1774 having lived long enough to see his great pupil Anne Robert Jacques Turgot Baron de Laune in office as minister of finance 4 Works edit nbsp Tableau economiqueHis economic writings are collected in the 2nd vol of the Principaux economistes published by Guillaumin Paris with preface and notes by Eugene Daire also his Oeuvres economiques et philosophiques were collected with an introduction and note by August Oncken Frankfort 1888 a facsimile reprint of the Tableau economique from the original MS was published by the British Economic Association London 1895 His other writings were the article Evidence in the Encyclopedie and Recherches sur l evidence des verites geometriques with a Projet de nouveaux elements de geometrie 1773 Quesnay s Eloge was pronounced in the Academy of Sciences by Grandjean de Fouchy see the Recueil of that Academy 1774 p 134 See also F J Marmontel Memoires Memoires de Mme du Hausset H Higgs The Physiocrats London 1897 4 Economics edit nbsp Tableau economique 1965In 1758 he published the Tableau economique Economic Table which provided the foundations of the ideas of the Physiocrats This was perhaps the first work to attempt to describe the workings of the economy in an analytical way and as such can be viewed as one of the first important contributions to economic thought 7 The publications in which Quesnay expounded his system were the following two articles on Fermiers Farmers and on Grains in the Encyclopedie of Diderot and Jean le Rond d Alembert 1756 1757 8 4 a discourse on the law of nature in the Physiocratie of Dupont de Nemours 1768 Maximes generales de gouvernement economique d un royaume agricole 1758 and the simultaneously published Tableau economique avec son explication ou extrait des economies royales de Sully with the celebrated motto Pauvres paysans pauvre royaume pauvre royaume pauvre roi Dialogue sur le commerce et les travaux des artisans and other minor pieces 4 The Tableau economique though on account of its dryness and abstract form it met with little general favor may be considered the principal manifesto of the school It was regarded by the followers of Quesnay as entitled to a place amongst the foremost products of human wisdom and is named by the elder Mirabeau in a passage quoted by Adam Smith 6 as one of the three great inventions which have contributed most to the stability of political societies the other two being those of writing and of money Its object was to exhibit by means of certain formulas the way in which the products of agriculture which is the only source of wealth would in a state of perfect liberty be distributed among the several classes of the community namely the productive classes of the proprietors and cultivators of land and the unproductive class composed of manufacturers and merchants and to represent by other formulas the modes of distribution which take place under systems of Governmental restraint and regulation with the evil results arising to the whole society from different degrees of such violations of the natural order It follows from Quesnay s theoretic views that the one thing deserving the solicitude of the practical economist and the statesman is the increase of the net product and he infers also what Smith afterwards affirmed on not quite the same ground that the interest of the landowner is strictly and indissolubly connected with the general interest of the society A small edition de luxe of this work with other pieces was printed in 1758 in the Palace of Versailles under the king s immediate supervision some of the sheets it is said having been pulled by the royal hand Already in 1767 the book had disappeared from circulation and no copy of it is now procurable but the substance of it has been preserved in the Ami des hommes of Mirabeau and the Physiocratie of Dupont de Nemours 4 Orientalism and China edit Quesnay is known for his writings on Chinese politics and society His book Le Despotisme de la Chine written in 1767 describes his views of the Chinese imperial system 3 He was supportive of the meritocratic concept of giving scholars political power without the cumbersome aristocracy that characterized French politics and the importance of agriculture to the welfare of a nation Gregory Blue writes that Quesnay praised China as a constitutional despotism and openly advocated the adoption of Chinese institutions including a standardized system of taxation and universal education Blue speculates that this may have influenced the 1793 establishment of the Permanent Settlement in Bengal by the British Empire 9 Quesnay s interests in Orientalism has also been a source of criticism Carol Blum in her book Strength in Numbers on 18th century France labels Quesnay an apologist for Oriental despotism 10 Because of his admiration of Confucianism Quesnay s followers bestowed him with the title Confucius of Europe 11 Quesnay s infatuation for Chinese culture as described by Jesuits led him to persuade the son of Louis XV to mirror the plowing of sacred land by the Chinese emperor to symbolize the link between government and agriculture 12 On TaxationQuesnay acknowledged three economic classes in France the proprietary class consisting of only landowners the productive class of agricultural workers and the sterile class of merchants Quesnay saw no benefit to the sterile class and believed the productive to be all important Quesnay viewed France s agriculture as backward and unproductive compared to Britain during the time he was residing in the Palace of Versailles 13 Despite residing in the Palace Quesnay believed agriculture was the heart of the economy and of special importance to him Quesnay argued that taxes placed on cultivators are only harmful to society as these taxes will reduce the incentive for agricultural production Taxing proprietors property holders does not destroy the means of production meaning there is no decline in output Quesnay wanted proprietors to bear the full burden of the tax in the country as taxing cultivators is a negative consequence for everyone Removing incentive from cultivators reduces agricultural production and the agricultural surplus Quesnay believed to be the heart of the economy 14 Quesnay also opposed indirect taxes in contrast to direct taxes These indirect taxes are placed on the French public by proprietors whose greed demands immunity from taxation Direct taxes on proprietors has no impact on reproduction and economic decline 14 Reducing indirect taxes and increasing direct taxes gives the French a surplus of agriculture and the funding the country needs However this opinion was not very popular among the wealthy of which Quesnay spent time regularly with He spent some of his time fearing for his life in the Palace See also editContributions to liberal theory History of economic thought Liberalism Ronald L Meek Circular flow of incomeNotes edit Cutler J Cleveland Biophysical economics Encyclopedia of Earth Last updated 14 September 2006 See the biographical note in the Collected Works of Karl Marx and Frederick Engels Volume 31 International Publishers New York 1989 p 605 a b Ina Baghdiantz McCabe 15 July 2008 Orientalism in Early Modern France Eurasian Trade Exoticism and the Ancien Regime Berg Publishers pp 271 72 ISBN 978 1 84520 374 0 a b c d e f g nbsp One or more of the preceding sentences incorporates text from a publication now in the public domain Chisholm Hugh ed 1911 Quesnay Francois Encyclopaedia Britannica Vol 22 11th ed Cambridge University Press pp 742 743 Nouvelles Ephemerides Economiques Seconde Partie Analyses Et Critiques Raisonnees N Premier Eloge Historique De M Quesnay Contenant L Analyse De Ses Ouvrages Par M Le Cte D A Taieb net Retrieved 16 August 2012 a b Smith Adam 1937 The Wealth of Nations N Y Random House p 643 first published 1776 Phillip Anthony O Hara 1999 Encyclopedia of Political Economy Psychology Press p 848 ISBN 978 0 415 18718 3 Retrieved 21 July 2012 Kafker Frank A Chouillet Jacques 1990 Kafker Frank A Notices sur les auteurs des 17 volumes de discours de l Encyclopedie suite et fin Recherches sur Diderot et sur l Encyclopedie Annee 1990 Volume 8 Numero 8 p 112 Recherches Sur Diderot et Sur l Encyclopedie 8 1 101 121 E S Shaffer 30 November 2000 Comparative Criticism Volume 22 East and West Comparative Perspectives Cambridge University Press pp 239 40 ISBN 978 0 521 79072 7 Carol Blum 5 February 2002 Strength in Numbers Population Reproduction and Power in Eighteenth Century France JHU Press p 16 ISBN 978 0 8018 6810 8 Murray N Rothbard 2006 Economic Thought Before Adam Smith Ludwig von Mises Institute p 366 ISBN 978 0 945466 48 2 Geoffrey C Gunn 2003 First Globalization The Eurasian Exchange 1500 to 1800 Rowman amp Littlefield p 148 ISBN 978 0 7425 2662 4 References editHobson John M 2004 The Eastern Origins of Western Civilization Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 54724 5 External links edit nbsp Wikiquote has quotations related to Francois Quesnay Works by or about Francois Quesnay at Internet Archive Le Despotisme de la Chine 1767 by Francois Quesnay hosted on the University of Massachusetts website Francois Quesnay 1694 1774 Library of Economics and Liberty 2nd ed Liberty Fund 2008 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a work ignored help Francois Quesnay June 1766 Analyse de la formule arithmetique du tableau economiqueu de la distribution des depenses annuelles d une Nation agricole Journal de l Agriculture du Commerce et des Finances 2 3 11 41 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Francois Quesnay amp oldid 1185026331, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.