fbpx
Wikipedia

Fordney–McCumber Tariff

The Fordney–McCumber Tariff of 1922 was a law that raised American tariffs on many imported goods to protect factories and farms. The US Congress displayed a pro-business attitude in passing the tariff and in promoting foreign trade by providing huge loans to Europe. That, in turn, bought more US goods.[1] However, five years after the passage of the tariff, American trading partners had raised their own tariffs by a significant degree. France raised its tariffs on automobiles from 45% to 100%, Spain raised its tariffs on American goods by 40%, and Germany and Italy raised their tariffs on wheat.[2] According to the American Farm Bureau, farmers lost more than $300 million annually as a result of the tariff.[3]

Rep. Joseph W. Fordney of Michigan (left) and Sen. Porter J. McCumber of North Dakota (right).

Background edit

The first sector of the economy that was hit by a fall in postwar demand was agriculture. During World War I, the American agricultural industry had enjoyed prosperity through the raising of prices, which led to increased output that Americans used to supply Europe.

Farmers borrowed heavily to expand their acreage and had difficulty paying back the loans when prices fell. Some of the postwar problems for American agriculture come from the great surplus of farm goods, which could not be absorbed in the national market as European countries had recovered sufficiently from the war, with their markets no longer requiring large quantities of American agricultural products.

Gross farm income in 1919 amounted to $17.7 billion. By 1921, exports to Europe had plummeted, and farm income fell to $10.5 billion. Other sectors of the economy wanted to avoid a similar fate. The 1920 election put the conservative pro-business and pro-farm Republicans in control of both Congress and the White House.[4]

Hearings were held by Congress and led to the creation of several new tools of protection. One was the scientific tariff to equalize production costs among countries; no country could undercut the prices charged by American companies. The difference of production costs was calculated by the Tariff Commission.

Another was the American selling price; it allowed the President to calculate the duty, which was based on the price of the American price of a good, not the imported good.[5]

The bill also gave the President the power to raise or lower rates on products if that was recommended by the Tariff Commission.

In September 1922, the Fordney–McCumber Tariff bill (named after Joseph Fordney, the chair of the House Ways and Means Committee, and Porter McCumber, the chair of the Senate Finance Committee) was signed by President Warren Harding.[6] In the end, the tariff law raised the American ad valorem tariff rate to an average of about 38.5% for dutiable imports and an average of 14% overall. The tariff was defensive, rather than offensive, as it was determined by the cost of production and the market value.

Economic effects edit

For agriculture, the tariff raised the purchasing power of the farmers by 2–3%, but other industries raised the price of some farm equipment. In September 1926, economic statistics released by farming groups revealed the rising cost of farm machinery.

For example, the average cost of a harness rose from $46 in 1918 to $75 in 1926, the 14-inch plow rose from $14 to $28, mowing machines rose from $45 to $95, and farm wagons rose from $85 to $150.[7]

That triggered a tariff war against other European countries that traded with the United States. As US tariffs raised, those in other countries followed.

According to the American Farm Bureau, farmers lost more than $300 million annually as a result of the tariff.[3]

Reactions edit

The tariff was supported by the Republican Party and conservatives and was generally opposed by the Democratic Party, liberals, and progressives. One purpose of the tariff was to help those returning from World War I have greater job opportunities.

Trading partners complained immediately. European nations affected by the war sought access for their exports to the American market to make payments to the war loans from America. Democratic Representative Cordell Hull warned, "Our foreign markets depend both on the efficiency of our production and the tariffs of countries in which we would sell. Our own [high] tariffs are an important factor in each. They injure the former and invite the latter."

Five years after the passage of the tariff, American trading partners had raised their own tariffs by a significant degree. France raised its tariffs on automobiles from 45% to 100%, Spain raised its tariffs on American goods by 40%, and Germany and Italy raised their tariffs on wheat.[2]

In 1928, Henry Ford attacked the tariff and argued that the American automobile industry did not need protection since it dominated the domestic market. Its main interest was now to expand foreign sales.[8]

Some farmers opposed the tariff and blamed it for the agricultural depression. The American Farm Bureau Federation claimed that because of the tariff, the raised price of raw wool cost to farmers $27 million. Democratic Senator David I. Walsh challenged the tariff by arguing that the farmers were net exporters and so did not need protection. They depended on foreign markets to sell their surplus. Walsh pointed out that during the first year of the tariff, the cost of living climbed higher than any other year except during the war. He presented a survey of the Department of Labor in which all of the 32 cities that were assessed had seen an increase in the cost of living. For example, the food costs increased 16.5% in Chicago and 9.4% in New York. Clothing prices rose by 5.5% in Buffalo and 10.2% in Chicago.

Republican Frank W. Murphy, the head of the Minnesota Farm Bureau, also claimed that the problem was not in the world price of farm products but in the things that farmers had to buy.

See also edit

Citations edit

  1. ^ Dollar 1973.
  2. ^ a b Rothgeb, 2001, pp. 32–33
  3. ^ a b Kaplan, Edward S. American Trade Policy, 1923–1995, 1996, pp. 2–8
  4. ^ John D. Hicks, Republican Ascendancy, 1921–1933 (1963), ch. 1
  5. ^ United States. Congress. Senate. Committee on Finance (1922). American valuation; Dyes embargo. U.S. Government Printing Office. p. 218.
  6. ^ Rothgeb, 2001, 30–32
  7. ^ Edward S. Kaplan "American Trade Policy, 1923–1995." 1996, pp. 8–10
  8. ^ Kaplan, Edward S. American Trade Policy, 1923–1995, 1996, p. 13

General and cited sources edit

  • Berglund, Abraham (1923). "The Tariff Act of 1922". American Economic Review. 13 (1): 14–33. JSTOR 1804045.
  • Dollar, Charles M. (1973). "The South and the Fordney–McCumber Tariff of 1922: A Study in Regional Politics". Journal of Southern History. 39 (1): 45–66. doi:10.2307/2206791. JSTOR 2206791.
  • Hayford, Marc; Pasurka, Carl A. Jr. (1992). "The Political Economy of the Fordney–McCumber and Smoot–Hawley Tariff Acts". Explorations in Economic History. 29 (1): 30–50. doi:10.1016/0014-4983(92)90031-Q.
  • Kaplan, Edward S. and Thomas W. Ryley (1994). Prelude to Trade Wars: American Tariff Policy, 1890–1922, the standard scholarly history online
  • Kaplan, Edward S. (March 16, 2008). "The Fordney–McCumber Tariff of 1922". Robert Whaples, ed. EH.Net Encyclopedia.
  • Kaplan, Edward S. (1996). American Trade Policy, 1923–1995. Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Press. ISBN 0-313-29480-1.
  • Rothgeb, John (2001). U.S. Trade Policy. Washington D.C.: CQ Press. ISBN 1-56802-522-X.
  • Taussig, F. W. (1922). "The Tariff Act of 1922". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 37 (1): 1–28. doi:10.2307/1885907. JSTOR 1885907.

fordney, mccumber, tariff, 1922, that, raised, american, tariffs, many, imported, goods, protect, factories, farms, congress, displayed, business, attitude, passing, tariff, promoting, foreign, trade, providing, huge, loans, europe, that, turn, bought, more, g. The Fordney McCumber Tariff of 1922 was a law that raised American tariffs on many imported goods to protect factories and farms The US Congress displayed a pro business attitude in passing the tariff and in promoting foreign trade by providing huge loans to Europe That in turn bought more US goods 1 However five years after the passage of the tariff American trading partners had raised their own tariffs by a significant degree France raised its tariffs on automobiles from 45 to 100 Spain raised its tariffs on American goods by 40 and Germany and Italy raised their tariffs on wheat 2 According to the American Farm Bureau farmers lost more than 300 million annually as a result of the tariff 3 Rep Joseph W Fordney of Michigan left and Sen Porter J McCumber of North Dakota right Contents 1 Background 2 Economic effects 3 Reactions 4 See also 5 Citations 6 General and cited sourcesBackground editThe first sector of the economy that was hit by a fall in postwar demand was agriculture During World War I the American agricultural industry had enjoyed prosperity through the raising of prices which led to increased output that Americans used to supply Europe Farmers borrowed heavily to expand their acreage and had difficulty paying back the loans when prices fell Some of the postwar problems for American agriculture come from the great surplus of farm goods which could not be absorbed in the national market as European countries had recovered sufficiently from the war with their markets no longer requiring large quantities of American agricultural products Gross farm income in 1919 amounted to 17 7 billion By 1921 exports to Europe had plummeted and farm income fell to 10 5 billion Other sectors of the economy wanted to avoid a similar fate The 1920 election put the conservative pro business and pro farm Republicans in control of both Congress and the White House 4 Hearings were held by Congress and led to the creation of several new tools of protection One was the scientific tariff to equalize production costs among countries no country could undercut the prices charged by American companies The difference of production costs was calculated by the Tariff Commission Another was the American selling price it allowed the President to calculate the duty which was based on the price of the American price of a good not the imported good 5 The bill also gave the President the power to raise or lower rates on products if that was recommended by the Tariff Commission In September 1922 the Fordney McCumber Tariff bill named after Joseph Fordney the chair of the House Ways and Means Committee and Porter McCumber the chair of the Senate Finance Committee was signed by President Warren Harding 6 In the end the tariff law raised the American ad valorem tariff rate to an average of about 38 5 for dutiable imports and an average of 14 overall The tariff was defensive rather than offensive as it was determined by the cost of production and the market value Economic effects editFor agriculture the tariff raised the purchasing power of the farmers by 2 3 but other industries raised the price of some farm equipment In September 1926 economic statistics released by farming groups revealed the rising cost of farm machinery For example the average cost of a harness rose from 46 in 1918 to 75 in 1926 the 14 inch plow rose from 14 to 28 mowing machines rose from 45 to 95 and farm wagons rose from 85 to 150 7 That triggered a tariff war against other European countries that traded with the United States As US tariffs raised those in other countries followed According to the American Farm Bureau farmers lost more than 300 million annually as a result of the tariff 3 Reactions editThe tariff was supported by the Republican Party and conservatives and was generally opposed by the Democratic Party liberals and progressives One purpose of the tariff was to help those returning from World War I have greater job opportunities Trading partners complained immediately European nations affected by the war sought access for their exports to the American market to make payments to the war loans from America Democratic Representative Cordell Hull warned Our foreign markets depend both on the efficiency of our production and the tariffs of countries in which we would sell Our own high tariffs are an important factor in each They injure the former and invite the latter Five years after the passage of the tariff American trading partners had raised their own tariffs by a significant degree France raised its tariffs on automobiles from 45 to 100 Spain raised its tariffs on American goods by 40 and Germany and Italy raised their tariffs on wheat 2 In 1928 Henry Ford attacked the tariff and argued that the American automobile industry did not need protection since it dominated the domestic market Its main interest was now to expand foreign sales 8 Some farmers opposed the tariff and blamed it for the agricultural depression The American Farm Bureau Federation claimed that because of the tariff the raised price of raw wool cost to farmers 27 million Democratic Senator David I Walsh challenged the tariff by arguing that the farmers were net exporters and so did not need protection They depended on foreign markets to sell their surplus Walsh pointed out that during the first year of the tariff the cost of living climbed higher than any other year except during the war He presented a survey of the Department of Labor in which all of the 32 cities that were assessed had seen an increase in the cost of living For example the food costs increased 16 5 in Chicago and 9 4 in New York Clothing prices rose by 5 5 in Buffalo and 10 2 in Chicago Republican Frank W Murphy the head of the Minnesota Farm Bureau also claimed that the problem was not in the world price of farm products but in the things that farmers had to buy See also editUnderwood Tariff of 1913 Emergency Tariff of 1921 Smoot Hawley Tariff Act of 1930 Reciprocal Tariff Act of 1934 International trade ProtectionismCitations edit Dollar 1973 a b Rothgeb 2001 pp 32 33 a b Kaplan Edward S American Trade Policy 1923 1995 1996 pp 2 8 John D Hicks Republican Ascendancy 1921 1933 1963 ch 1 United States Congress Senate Committee on Finance 1922 American valuation Dyes embargo U S Government Printing Office p 218 Rothgeb 2001 30 32 Edward S Kaplan American Trade Policy 1923 1995 1996 pp 8 10 Kaplan Edward S American Trade Policy 1923 1995 1996 p 13General and cited sources editBerglund Abraham 1923 The Tariff Act of 1922 American Economic Review 13 1 14 33 JSTOR 1804045 Dollar Charles M 1973 The South and the Fordney McCumber Tariff of 1922 A Study in Regional Politics Journal of Southern History 39 1 45 66 doi 10 2307 2206791 JSTOR 2206791 Hayford Marc Pasurka Carl A Jr 1992 The Political Economy of the Fordney McCumber and Smoot Hawley Tariff Acts Explorations in Economic History 29 1 30 50 doi 10 1016 0014 4983 92 90031 Q Kaplan Edward S and Thomas W Ryley 1994 Prelude to Trade Wars American Tariff Policy 1890 1922 the standard scholarly history online Kaplan Edward S March 16 2008 The Fordney McCumber Tariff of 1922 Robert Whaples ed EH Net Encyclopedia Kaplan Edward S 1996 American Trade Policy 1923 1995 Westport Connecticut Greenwood Press ISBN 0 313 29480 1 Rothgeb John 2001 U S Trade Policy Washington D C CQ Press ISBN 1 56802 522 X Taussig F W 1922 The Tariff Act of 1922 Quarterly Journal of Economics 37 1 1 28 doi 10 2307 1885907 JSTOR 1885907 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Fordney McCumber Tariff amp oldid 1205961089, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.