fbpx
Wikipedia

Expected shortfall

Expected shortfall (ES) is a risk measure—a concept used in the field of financial risk measurement to evaluate the market risk or credit risk of a portfolio. The "expected shortfall at q% level" is the expected return on the portfolio in the worst of cases. ES is an alternative to value at risk that is more sensitive to the shape of the tail of the loss distribution.

Expected shortfall is also called conditional value at risk (CVaR),[1] average value at risk (AVaR), expected tail loss (ETL), and superquantile.[2]

ES estimates the risk of an investment in a conservative way, focusing on the less profitable outcomes. For high values of it ignores the most profitable but unlikely possibilities, while for small values of it focuses on the worst losses. On the other hand, unlike the discounted maximum loss, even for lower values of the expected shortfall does not consider only the single most catastrophic outcome. A value of often used in practice is 5%.[citation needed]

Expected shortfall is considered a more useful risk measure than VaR because it is a coherent spectral measure of financial portfolio risk. It is calculated for a given quantile-level and is defined to be the mean loss of portfolio value given that a loss is occurring at or below the -quantile.

Formal definition edit

If   (an Lp) is the payoff of a portfolio at some future time and   then we define the expected shortfall as

 

where   is the value at risk. This can be equivalently written as

 

where   is the lower  -quantile and   is the indicator function.[3] Note, that the second term vanishes for random variables with continuous distribution functions.

The dual representation is

 

where   is the set of probability measures which are absolutely continuous to the physical measure   such that   almost surely.[4] Note that   is the Radon–Nikodym derivative of   with respect to  .

Expected shortfall can be generalized to a general class of coherent risk measures on   spaces (Lp space) with a corresponding dual characterization in the corresponding   dual space. The domain can be extended for more general Orlicz Hearts.[5]

If the underlying distribution for   is a continuous distribution then the expected shortfall is equivalent to the tail conditional expectation defined by  .[6]

Informally, and non-rigorously, this equation amounts to saying "in case of losses so severe that they occur only alpha percent of the time, what is our average loss".

Expected shortfall can also be written as a distortion risk measure given by the distortion function

 [7][8]

Examples edit

Example 1. If we believe our average loss on the worst 5% of the possible outcomes for our portfolio is EUR 1000, then we could say our expected shortfall is EUR 1000 for the 5% tail.

Example 2. Consider a portfolio that will have the following possible values at the end of the period:

probability
of event
ending value
of the portfolio
10% 0
30% 80
40% 100
20% 150

Now assume that we paid 100 at the beginning of the period for this portfolio. Then the profit in each case is (ending value−100) or:

probability
of event
profit
10% −100
30% −20
40% 0
20% 50

From this table let us calculate the expected shortfall   for a few values of  :

  expected shortfall  
5% 100
10% 100
20% 60
30% 46.6
40% 40
50% 32
60% 26.6
80% 20
90% 12.2
100% 6

To see how these values were calculated, consider the calculation of  , the expectation in the worst 5% of cases. These cases belong to (are a subset of) row 1 in the profit table, which have a profit of −100 (total loss of the 100 invested). The expected profit for these cases is −100.

Now consider the calculation of  , the expectation in the worst 20 out of 100 cases. These cases are as follows: 10 cases from row one, and 10 cases from row two (note that 10+10 equals the desired 20 cases). For row 1 there is a profit of −100, while for row 2 a profit of −20. Using the expected value formula we get

 

Similarly for any value of  . We select as many rows starting from the top as are necessary to give a cumulative probability of   and then calculate an expectation over those cases. In general, the last row selected may not be fully used (for example in calculating   we used only 10 of the 30 cases per 100 provided by row 2).

As a final example, calculate  . This is the expectation over all cases, or

 

The value at risk (VaR) is given below for comparison.

   
  −100
  −20
  0
  50

Properties edit

The expected shortfall   increases as   decreases.

The 100%-quantile expected shortfall   equals negative of the expected value of the portfolio.

For a given portfolio, the expected shortfall   is greater than or equal to the Value at Risk   at the same   level.

Optimization of expected shortfall edit

Expected shortfall, in its standard form, is known to lead to a generally non-convex optimization problem. However, it is possible to transform the problem into a linear program and find the global solution.[9] This property makes expected shortfall a cornerstone of alternatives to mean-variance portfolio optimization, which account for the higher moments (e.g., skewness and kurtosis) of a return distribution.

Suppose that we want to minimize the expected shortfall of a portfolio. The key contribution of Rockafellar and Uryasev in their 2000 paper is to introduce the auxiliary function   for the expected shortfall:

 
Where   and   is a loss function for a set of portfolio weights   to be applied to the returns. Rockafellar/Uryasev proved that   is convex with respect to   and is equivalent to the expected shortfall at the minimum point. To numerically compute the expected shortfall for a set of portfolio returns, it is necessary to generate   simulations of the portfolio constituents; this is often done using copulas. With these simulations in hand, the auxiliary function may be approximated by:
 
This is equivalent to the formulation:
 
Finally, choosing a linear loss function   turns the optimization problem into a linear program. Using standard methods, it is then easy to find the portfolio that minimizes expected shortfall.

Formulas for continuous probability distributions edit

Closed-form formulas exist for calculating the expected shortfall when the payoff of a portfolio   or a corresponding loss   follows a specific continuous distribution. In the former case, the expected shortfall corresponds to the opposite number of the left-tail conditional expectation below  :

 

Typical values of   in this case are 5% and 1%.

For engineering or actuarial applications it is more common to consider the distribution of losses  , the expected shortfall in this case corresponds to the right-tail conditional expectation above   and the typical values of   are 95% and 99%:

 

Since some formulas below were derived for the left-tail case and some for the right-tail case, the following reconciliations can be useful:

 

Normal distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows the normal (Gaussian) distribution with p.d.f.   then the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the standard normal p.d.f.,   is the standard normal c.d.f., so   is the standard normal quantile.[10]

If the loss of a portfolio   follows the normal distribution, the expected shortfall is equal to  .[11]

Generalized Student's t-distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows the generalized Student's t-distribution with p.d.f.   then the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the standard t-distribution p.d.f.,   is the standard t-distribution c.d.f., so   is the standard t-distribution quantile.[10]

If the loss of a portfolio   follows generalized Student's t-distribution, the expected shortfall is equal to  .[11]

Laplace distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows the Laplace distribution with the p.d.f.

 

and the c.d.f.

 

then the expected shortfall is equal to   for  .[10]

If the loss of a portfolio   follows the Laplace distribution, the expected shortfall is equal to[11]

 

Logistic distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows the logistic distribution with p.d.f.   and the c.d.f.   then the expected shortfall is equal to  .[10]

If the loss of a portfolio   follows the logistic distribution, the expected shortfall is equal to  .[11]

Exponential distribution edit

If the loss of a portfolio   follows the exponential distribution with p.d.f.   and the c.d.f.   then the expected shortfall is equal to  .[11]

Pareto distribution edit

If the loss of a portfolio   follows the Pareto distribution with p.d.f.   and the c.d.f.   then the expected shortfall is equal to  .[11]

Generalized Pareto distribution (GPD) edit

If the loss of a portfolio   follows the GPD with p.d.f.

 

and the c.d.f.

 

then the expected shortfall is equal to

 

and the VaR is equal to[11]

 

Weibull distribution edit

If the loss of a portfolio   follows the Weibull distribution with p.d.f.   and the c.d.f.   then the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the upper incomplete gamma function.[11]

Generalized extreme value distribution (GEV) edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows the GEV with p.d.f.   and c.d.f.   then the expected shortfall is equal to   and the VaR is equal to  , where   is the upper incomplete gamma function,   is the logarithmic integral function.[12]

If the loss of a portfolio   follows the GEV, then the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the lower incomplete gamma function,   is the Euler-Mascheroni constant.[11]

Generalized hyperbolic secant (GHS) distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows the GHS distribution with p.d.f.  and the c.d.f.   then the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the dilogarithm and   is the imaginary unit.[12]

Johnson's SU-distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows Johnson's SU-distribution with the c.d.f.   then the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the c.d.f. of the standard normal distribution.[13]

Burr type XII distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows the Burr type XII distribution the p.d.f.   and the c.d.f.  , the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the hypergeometric function. Alternatively,  .[12]

Dagum distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows the Dagum distribution with p.d.f.   and the c.d.f.  , the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the hypergeometric function.[12]

Lognormal distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows lognormal distribution, i.e. the random variable   follows the normal distribution with p.d.f.  , then the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the standard normal c.d.f., so   is the standard normal quantile.[14]

Log-logistic distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows log-logistic distribution, i.e. the random variable   follows the logistic distribution with p.d.f.  , then the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the regularized incomplete beta function,  .

As the incomplete beta function is defined only for positive arguments, for a more generic case the expected shortfall can be expressed with the hypergeometric function:  .[14]

If the loss of a portfolio   follows log-logistic distribution with p.d.f.   and c.d.f.  , then the expected shortfall is equal to  , where   is the incomplete beta function.[11]

Log-Laplace distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows log-Laplace distribution, i.e. the random variable   follows the Laplace distribution the p.d.f.  , then the expected shortfall is equal to

 [14]

Log-generalized hyperbolic secant (log-GHS) distribution edit

If the payoff of a portfolio   follows log-GHS distribution, i.e. the random variable   follows the GHS distribution with p.d.f.  , then the expected shortfall is equal to

 

where   is the hypergeometric function.[14]

Dynamic expected shortfall edit

The conditional version of the expected shortfall at the time t is defined by

 

where  .[15][16]

This is not a time-consistent risk measure. The time-consistent version is given by

 

such that[17]

 

See also edit

Methods of statistical estimation of VaR and ES can be found in Embrechts et al.[18] and Novak.[19] When forecasting VaR and ES, or optimizing portfolios to minimize tail risk, it is important to account for asymmetric dependence and non-normalities in the distribution of stock returns such as auto-regression, asymmetric volatility, skewness, and kurtosis.[20]

References edit

  1. ^ Rockafellar, R. Tyrrell; Uryasev, Stanislav (2000). "Optimization of conditional value-at-risk" (PDF). Journal of Risk. 2 (3): 21–42. doi:10.21314/JOR.2000.038. S2CID 854622.
  2. ^ Rockafellar, R. Tyrrell; Royset, Johannes (2010). "On Buffered Failure Probability in Design and Optimization of Structures" (PDF). Reliability Engineering and System Safety. 95 (5): 499–510. doi:10.1016/j.ress.2010.01.001. S2CID 1653873.
  3. ^ Carlo Acerbi; Dirk Tasche (2002). "Expected Shortfall: a natural coherent alternative to Value at Risk" (PDF). Economic Notes. 31 (2): 379–388. arXiv:cond-mat/0105191. doi:10.1111/1468-0300.00091. S2CID 10772757. Retrieved April 25, 2012.
  4. ^ Föllmer, H.; Schied, A. (2008). "Convex and coherent risk measures" (PDF). Retrieved October 4, 2011. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  5. ^ Patrick Cheridito; Tianhui Li (2008). "Dual characterization of properties of risk measures on Orlicz hearts". Mathematics and Financial Economics. 2: 2–29. doi:10.1007/s11579-008-0013-7. S2CID 121880657.
  6. ^ (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on July 19, 2011. Retrieved February 2, 2011.
  7. ^ Julia L. Wirch; Mary R. Hardy. (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on July 5, 2016. Retrieved March 10, 2012.
  8. ^ Balbás, A.; Garrido, J.; Mayoral, S. (2008). "Properties of Distortion Risk Measures" (PDF). Methodology and Computing in Applied Probability. 11 (3): 385. doi:10.1007/s11009-008-9089-z. hdl:10016/14071. S2CID 53327887.
  9. ^ Rockafellar, R. Tyrrell; Uryasev, Stanislav (2000). "Optimization of conditional value-at-risk" (PDF). Journal of Risk. 2 (3): 21–42. doi:10.21314/JOR.2000.038. S2CID 854622.
  10. ^ a b c d Khokhlov, Valentyn (2016). "Conditional Value-at-Risk for Elliptical Distributions". Evropský časopis Ekonomiky a Managementu. 2 (6): 70–79.
  11. ^ a b c d e f g h i j Norton, Matthew; Khokhlov, Valentyn; Uryasev, Stan (2018-11-27). "Calculating CVaR and bPOE for Common Probability Distributions With Application to Portfolio Optimization and Density Estimation". arXiv:1811.11301 [q-fin.RM].
  12. ^ a b c d Khokhlov, Valentyn (2018-06-21). "Conditional Value-at-Risk for Uncommon Distributions". doi:10.2139/ssrn.3200629. S2CID 219371851. SSRN 3200629. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  13. ^ Stucchi, Patrizia (2011-05-31). "Moment-Based CVaR Estimation: Quasi-Closed Formulas". doi:10.2139/ssrn.1855986. S2CID 124145569. SSRN 1855986. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  14. ^ a b c d Khokhlov, Valentyn (2018-06-17). "Conditional Value-at-Risk for Log-Distributions". SSRN 3197929.
  15. ^ Detlefsen, Kai; Scandolo, Giacomo (2005). "Conditional and dynamic convex risk measures" (PDF). Finance Stoch. 9 (4): 539–561. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.453.4944. doi:10.1007/s00780-005-0159-6. S2CID 10579202. Retrieved October 11, 2011.[dead link]
  16. ^ Acciaio, Beatrice; Penner, Irina (2011). (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on September 2, 2011. Retrieved October 11, 2011. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  17. ^ Cheridito, Patrick; Kupper, Michael (May 2010). (PDF). International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance. Archived from the original (PDF) on July 19, 2011. Retrieved February 4, 2011.
  18. ^ Embrechts P., Kluppelberg C. and Mikosch T., Modelling Extremal Events for Insurance and Finance. Springer (1997).
  19. ^ Novak S.Y., Extreme value methods with applications to finance. Chapman & Hall/CRC Press (2011). ISBN 978-1-4398-3574-6.
  20. ^ Low, R.K.Y.; Alcock, J.; Faff, R.; Brailsford, T. (2013). "Canonical vine copulas in the context of modern portfolio management: Are they worth it?" (PDF). Journal of Banking & Finance. 37 (8): 3085–3099. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2013.02.036. S2CID 154138333.

External links edit

  • Rockafellar, Uryasev: Optimization of conditional Value-at-Risk, 2000.
  • C. Acerbi and D. Tasche: On the Coherence of Expected Shortfall, 2002.
  • Rockafellar, Uryasev: Conditional Value-at-Risk for general loss distributions, 2002.
  • Phi-Alpha optimal portfolios and extreme risk management, Best of Wilmott, 2003
  • "Coherent measures of Risk", Philippe Artzner, Freddy Delbaen, Jean-Marc Eber, and David Heath

expected, shortfall, risk, measure, concept, used, field, financial, risk, measurement, evaluate, market, risk, credit, risk, portfolio, expected, shortfall, level, expected, return, portfolio, worst, displaystyle, cases, alternative, value, risk, that, more, . Expected shortfall ES is a risk measure a concept used in the field of financial risk measurement to evaluate the market risk or credit risk of a portfolio The expected shortfall at q level is the expected return on the portfolio in the worst q displaystyle q of cases ES is an alternative to value at risk that is more sensitive to the shape of the tail of the loss distribution Expected shortfall is also called conditional value at risk CVaR 1 average value at risk AVaR expected tail loss ETL and superquantile 2 ES estimates the risk of an investment in a conservative way focusing on the less profitable outcomes For high values of q displaystyle q it ignores the most profitable but unlikely possibilities while for small values of q displaystyle q it focuses on the worst losses On the other hand unlike the discounted maximum loss even for lower values of q displaystyle q the expected shortfall does not consider only the single most catastrophic outcome A value of q displaystyle q often used in practice is 5 citation needed Expected shortfall is considered a more useful risk measure than VaR because it is a coherent spectral measure of financial portfolio risk It is calculated for a given quantile level q displaystyle q and is defined to be the mean loss of portfolio value given that a loss is occurring at or below the q displaystyle q quantile Contents 1 Formal definition 2 Examples 3 Properties 4 Optimization of expected shortfall 5 Formulas for continuous probability distributions 5 1 Normal distribution 5 2 Generalized Student s t distribution 5 3 Laplace distribution 5 4 Logistic distribution 5 5 Exponential distribution 5 6 Pareto distribution 5 7 Generalized Pareto distribution GPD 5 8 Weibull distribution 5 9 Generalized extreme value distribution GEV 5 10 Generalized hyperbolic secant GHS distribution 5 11 Johnson s SU distribution 5 12 Burr type XII distribution 5 13 Dagum distribution 5 14 Lognormal distribution 5 15 Log logistic distribution 5 16 Log Laplace distribution 5 17 Log generalized hyperbolic secant log GHS distribution 6 Dynamic expected shortfall 7 See also 8 References 9 External linksFormal definition editIf X L p F displaystyle X in L p mathcal F nbsp an Lp is the payoff of a portfolio at some future time and 0 lt a lt 1 displaystyle 0 lt alpha lt 1 nbsp then we define the expected shortfall as ES a X 1 a 0 a VaR g X d g displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X frac 1 alpha int 0 alpha operatorname VaR gamma X d gamma nbsp where VaR g displaystyle operatorname VaR gamma nbsp is the value at risk This can be equivalently written as ES a X 1 a E X 1 X x a x a a P X x a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X frac 1 alpha left operatorname E X 1 X leq x alpha x alpha alpha P X leq x alpha right nbsp where x a inf x R P X x a VaR a X displaystyle x alpha inf x in mathbb R P X leq x geq alpha operatorname VaR alpha X nbsp is the lower a displaystyle alpha nbsp quantile and 1 A x 1 if x A 0 else displaystyle 1 A x begin cases 1 amp text if x in A 0 amp text else end cases nbsp is the indicator function 3 Note that the second term vanishes for random variables with continuous distribution functions The dual representation is ES a X inf Q Q a E Q X displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X inf Q in mathcal Q alpha E Q X nbsp where Q a displaystyle mathcal Q alpha nbsp is the set of probability measures which are absolutely continuous to the physical measure P displaystyle P nbsp such that d Q d P a 1 displaystyle frac dQ dP leq alpha 1 nbsp almost surely 4 Note that d Q d P displaystyle frac dQ dP nbsp is the Radon Nikodym derivative of Q displaystyle Q nbsp with respect to P displaystyle P nbsp Expected shortfall can be generalized to a general class of coherent risk measures on L p displaystyle L p nbsp spaces Lp space with a corresponding dual characterization in the corresponding L q displaystyle L q nbsp dual space The domain can be extended for more general Orlicz Hearts 5 If the underlying distribution for X displaystyle X nbsp is a continuous distribution then the expected shortfall is equivalent to the tail conditional expectation defined by TCE a X E X X VaR a X displaystyle operatorname TCE alpha X E X mid X leq operatorname VaR alpha X nbsp 6 Informally and non rigorously this equation amounts to saying in case of losses so severe that they occur only alpha percent of the time what is our average loss Expected shortfall can also be written as a distortion risk measure given by the distortion function g x x 1 a if 0 x lt 1 a 1 if 1 a x 1 displaystyle g x begin cases frac x 1 alpha amp text if 0 leq x lt 1 alpha 1 amp text if 1 alpha leq x leq 1 end cases quad nbsp 7 8 Examples editExample 1 If we believe our average loss on the worst 5 of the possible outcomes for our portfolio is EUR 1000 then we could say our expected shortfall is EUR 1000 for the 5 tail Example 2 Consider a portfolio that will have the following possible values at the end of the period probabilityof event ending valueof the portfolio10 030 8040 10020 150Now assume that we paid 100 at the beginning of the period for this portfolio Then the profit in each case is ending value 100 or probabilityof event profit10 10030 2040 020 50From this table let us calculate the expected shortfall ES q displaystyle operatorname ES q nbsp for a few values of q displaystyle q nbsp q displaystyle q nbsp expected shortfall ES q displaystyle operatorname ES q nbsp 5 10010 10020 6030 46 640 4050 3260 26 680 2090 12 2100 6To see how these values were calculated consider the calculation of ES 0 05 displaystyle operatorname ES 0 05 nbsp the expectation in the worst 5 of cases These cases belong to are a subset of row 1 in the profit table which have a profit of 100 total loss of the 100 invested The expected profit for these cases is 100 Now consider the calculation of ES 0 20 displaystyle operatorname ES 0 20 nbsp the expectation in the worst 20 out of 100 cases These cases are as follows 10 cases from row one and 10 cases from row two note that 10 10 equals the desired 20 cases For row 1 there is a profit of 100 while for row 2 a profit of 20 Using the expected value formula we get 10 100 100 10 100 20 20 100 60 displaystyle frac frac 10 100 100 frac 10 100 20 frac 20 100 60 nbsp Similarly for any value of q displaystyle q nbsp We select as many rows starting from the top as are necessary to give a cumulative probability of q displaystyle q nbsp and then calculate an expectation over those cases In general the last row selected may not be fully used for example in calculating ES 0 20 displaystyle operatorname ES 0 20 nbsp we used only 10 of the 30 cases per 100 provided by row 2 As a final example calculate ES 1 displaystyle operatorname ES 1 nbsp This is the expectation over all cases or 0 1 100 0 3 20 0 4 0 0 2 50 6 displaystyle 0 1 100 0 3 20 0 4 cdot 0 0 2 cdot 50 6 nbsp The value at risk VaR is given below for comparison q displaystyle q nbsp VaR q displaystyle operatorname VaR q nbsp 0 q lt 10 displaystyle 0 leq q lt 10 nbsp 10010 q lt 40 displaystyle 10 leq q lt 40 nbsp 2040 q lt 80 displaystyle 40 leq q lt 80 nbsp 080 q 100 displaystyle 80 leq q leq 100 nbsp 50Properties editThe expected shortfall ES q displaystyle operatorname ES q nbsp increases as q displaystyle q nbsp decreases The 100 quantile expected shortfall ES 1 displaystyle operatorname ES 1 nbsp equals negative of the expected value of the portfolio For a given portfolio the expected shortfall ES q displaystyle operatorname ES q nbsp is greater than or equal to the Value at Risk VaR q displaystyle operatorname VaR q nbsp at the same q displaystyle q nbsp level Optimization of expected shortfall editExpected shortfall in its standard form is known to lead to a generally non convex optimization problem However it is possible to transform the problem into a linear program and find the global solution 9 This property makes expected shortfall a cornerstone of alternatives to mean variance portfolio optimization which account for the higher moments e g skewness and kurtosis of a return distribution Suppose that we want to minimize the expected shortfall of a portfolio The key contribution of Rockafellar and Uryasev in their 2000 paper is to introduce the auxiliary function F a w g displaystyle F alpha w gamma nbsp for the expected shortfall F a w g g 1 1 a ℓ w x g ℓ w x g p x d x displaystyle F alpha w gamma gamma 1 over 1 alpha int ell w x geq gamma left ell w x gamma right p x dx nbsp Where g VaR a X displaystyle gamma operatorname VaR alpha X nbsp and ℓ w x displaystyle ell w x nbsp is a loss function for a set of portfolio weights w R p displaystyle w in mathbb R p nbsp to be applied to the returns Rockafellar Uryasev proved that F a w g displaystyle F alpha w gamma nbsp is convex with respect to g displaystyle gamma nbsp and is equivalent to the expected shortfall at the minimum point To numerically compute the expected shortfall for a set of portfolio returns it is necessary to generate J displaystyle J nbsp simulations of the portfolio constituents this is often done using copulas With these simulations in hand the auxiliary function may be approximated by F a w g g 1 1 a J j 1 J ℓ w x j g displaystyle widetilde F alpha w gamma gamma 1 over 1 alpha J sum j 1 J ell w x j gamma nbsp This is equivalent to the formulation min g z w g 1 1 a J j 1 J z j s t z j ℓ w x j g z j 0 displaystyle min gamma z w gamma 1 over 1 alpha J sum j 1 J z j quad text s t z j geq ell w x j gamma z j geq 0 nbsp Finally choosing a linear loss function ℓ w x j w T x j displaystyle ell w x j w T x j nbsp turns the optimization problem into a linear program Using standard methods it is then easy to find the portfolio that minimizes expected shortfall Formulas for continuous probability distributions editClosed form formulas exist for calculating the expected shortfall when the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp or a corresponding loss L X displaystyle L X nbsp follows a specific continuous distribution In the former case the expected shortfall corresponds to the opposite number of the left tail conditional expectation below VaR a X displaystyle operatorname VaR alpha X nbsp ES a X E X X VaR a X 1 a 0 a VaR g X d g 1 a VaR a X x f x d x displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X E X mid X leq operatorname VaR alpha X frac 1 alpha int 0 alpha operatorname VaR gamma X d gamma frac 1 alpha int infty operatorname VaR alpha X xf x dx nbsp Typical values of a textstyle alpha nbsp in this case are 5 and 1 For engineering or actuarial applications it is more common to consider the distribution of losses L X displaystyle L X nbsp the expected shortfall in this case corresponds to the right tail conditional expectation above VaR a L displaystyle operatorname VaR alpha L nbsp and the typical values of a displaystyle alpha nbsp are 95 and 99 ES a L E L L VaR a L 1 1 a a 1 VaR g L d g 1 1 a VaR a L y f y d y displaystyle operatorname ES alpha L operatorname E L mid L geq operatorname VaR alpha L frac 1 1 alpha int alpha 1 operatorname VaR gamma L d gamma frac 1 1 alpha int operatorname VaR alpha L infty yf y dy nbsp Since some formulas below were derived for the left tail case and some for the right tail case the following reconciliations can be useful ES a X 1 a E X 1 a a ES a L and ES a L 1 1 a E L a 1 a ES a X displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X frac 1 alpha operatorname E X frac 1 alpha alpha operatorname ES alpha L text and operatorname ES alpha L frac 1 1 alpha operatorname E L frac alpha 1 alpha operatorname ES alpha X nbsp Normal distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows the normal Gaussian distribution with p d f f x 1 2 p s e x m 2 2 s 2 displaystyle f x frac 1 sqrt 2 pi sigma e frac x mu 2 2 sigma 2 nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X m s f F 1 a a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X mu sigma frac varphi Phi 1 alpha alpha nbsp where f x 1 2 p e x 2 2 displaystyle varphi x frac 1 sqrt 2 pi e frac x 2 2 nbsp is the standard normal p d f F x displaystyle Phi x nbsp is the standard normal c d f so F 1 a displaystyle Phi 1 alpha nbsp is the standard normal quantile 10 If the loss of a portfolio L displaystyle L nbsp follows the normal distribution the expected shortfall is equal to ES a L m s f F 1 a 1 a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha L mu sigma frac varphi Phi 1 alpha 1 alpha nbsp 11 Generalized Student s t distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows the generalized Student s t distribution with p d f f x G n 1 2 G n 2 p n s 1 1 n x m s 2 n 1 2 displaystyle f x frac Gamma left frac nu 1 2 right Gamma left frac nu 2 right sqrt pi nu sigma left 1 frac 1 nu left frac x mu sigma right 2 right frac nu 1 2 nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X m s n T 1 a 2 n 1 t T 1 a a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X mu sigma frac nu mathrm T 1 alpha 2 nu 1 frac tau mathrm T 1 alpha alpha nbsp where t x G n 1 2 G n 2 p n 1 x 2 n n 1 2 displaystyle tau x frac Gamma bigl frac nu 1 2 bigr Gamma bigl frac nu 2 bigr sqrt pi nu Bigl 1 frac x 2 nu Bigr frac nu 1 2 nbsp is the standard t distribution p d f T x displaystyle mathrm T x nbsp is the standard t distribution c d f so T 1 a displaystyle mathrm T 1 alpha nbsp is the standard t distribution quantile 10 If the loss of a portfolio L displaystyle L nbsp follows generalized Student s t distribution the expected shortfall is equal to ES a L m s n T 1 a 2 n 1 t T 1 a a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha L mu sigma frac nu mathrm T 1 alpha 2 nu 1 frac tau mathrm T 1 alpha alpha nbsp 11 Laplace distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows the Laplace distribution with the p d f f x 1 2 b e x m b displaystyle f x frac 1 2b e x mu b nbsp and the c d f F x 1 1 2 e x m b if x m 1 2 e x m b if x lt m displaystyle F x begin cases 1 frac 1 2 e x mu b amp text if x geq mu 4pt frac 1 2 e x mu b amp text if x lt mu end cases nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X m b 1 ln 2 a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X mu b 1 ln 2 alpha nbsp for a 0 5 displaystyle alpha leq 0 5 nbsp 10 If the loss of a portfolio L displaystyle L nbsp follows the Laplace distribution the expected shortfall is equal to 11 ES a L m b a 1 a 1 ln 2 a if a lt 0 5 m b 1 ln 2 1 a if a 0 5 displaystyle operatorname ES alpha L begin cases mu b frac alpha 1 alpha 1 ln 2 alpha amp text if alpha lt 0 5 4pt mu b 1 ln 2 1 alpha amp text if alpha geq 0 5 end cases nbsp Logistic distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows the logistic distribution with p d f f x 1 s e x m s 1 e x m s 2 displaystyle f x frac 1 s e frac x mu s left 1 e frac x mu s right 2 nbsp and the c d f F x 1 e x m s 1 displaystyle F x left 1 e frac x mu s right 1 nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X m s ln 1 a 1 1 a a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X mu s ln frac 1 alpha 1 frac 1 alpha alpha nbsp 10 If the loss of a portfolio L displaystyle L nbsp follows the logistic distribution the expected shortfall is equal to ES a L m s a ln a 1 a ln 1 a 1 a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha L mu s frac alpha ln alpha 1 alpha ln 1 alpha 1 alpha nbsp 11 Exponential distribution edit If the loss of a portfolio L displaystyle L nbsp follows the exponential distribution with p d f f x l e l x if x 0 0 if x lt 0 displaystyle f x begin cases lambda e lambda x amp text if x geq 0 0 amp text if x lt 0 end cases nbsp and the c d f F x 1 e l x if x 0 0 if x lt 0 displaystyle F x begin cases 1 e lambda x amp text if x geq 0 0 amp text if x lt 0 end cases nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a L ln 1 a 1 l displaystyle operatorname ES alpha L frac ln 1 alpha 1 lambda nbsp 11 Pareto distribution edit If the loss of a portfolio L displaystyle L nbsp follows the Pareto distribution with p d f f x a x m a x a 1 if x x m 0 if x lt x m displaystyle f x begin cases frac ax m a x a 1 amp text if x geq x m 0 amp text if x lt x m end cases nbsp and the c d f F x 1 x m x a if x x m 0 if x lt x m displaystyle F x begin cases 1 x m x a amp text if x geq x m 0 amp text if x lt x m end cases nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a L x m a 1 a 1 a a 1 displaystyle operatorname ES alpha L frac x m a 1 alpha 1 a a 1 nbsp 11 Generalized Pareto distribution GPD edit If the loss of a portfolio L displaystyle L nbsp follows the GPD with p d f f x 1 s 1 3 x m s 1 3 1 displaystyle f x frac 1 s left 1 frac xi x mu s right left frac 1 xi 1 right nbsp and the c d f F x 1 1 3 x m s 1 3 if 3 0 1 exp x m s if 3 0 displaystyle F x begin cases 1 left 1 frac xi x mu s right 1 xi amp text if xi neq 0 1 exp left frac x mu s right amp text if xi 0 end cases nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a L m s 1 a 3 1 3 1 a 3 1 3 if 3 0 m s 1 ln 1 a if 3 0 displaystyle operatorname ES alpha L begin cases mu s left frac 1 alpha xi 1 xi frac 1 alpha xi 1 xi right amp text if xi neq 0 mu s left 1 ln 1 alpha right amp text if xi 0 end cases nbsp and the VaR is equal to 11 VaR a L m s 1 a 3 1 3 if 3 0 m s ln 1 a if 3 0 displaystyle operatorname VaR alpha L begin cases mu s frac 1 alpha xi 1 xi amp text if xi neq 0 mu s ln 1 alpha amp text if xi 0 end cases nbsp Weibull distribution edit If the loss of a portfolio L displaystyle L nbsp follows the Weibull distribution with p d f f x k l x l k 1 e x l k if x 0 0 if x lt 0 displaystyle f x begin cases frac k lambda left frac x lambda right k 1 e x lambda k amp text if x geq 0 0 amp text if x lt 0 end cases nbsp and the c d f F x 1 e x l k if x 0 0 if x lt 0 displaystyle F x begin cases 1 e x lambda k amp text if x geq 0 0 amp text if x lt 0 end cases nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a L l 1 a G 1 1 k ln 1 a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha L frac lambda 1 alpha Gamma left 1 frac 1 k ln 1 alpha right nbsp where G s x displaystyle Gamma s x nbsp is the upper incomplete gamma function 11 Generalized extreme value distribution GEV edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows the GEV with p d f f x 1 s 1 3 x m s 1 3 1 exp 1 3 x m s 1 3 if 3 0 1 s e x m s e e x m s if 3 0 displaystyle f x begin cases frac 1 sigma left 1 xi frac x mu sigma right frac 1 xi 1 exp left left 1 xi frac x mu sigma right 1 xi right amp text if xi neq 0 frac 1 sigma e frac x mu sigma e e frac x mu sigma amp text if xi 0 end cases nbsp and c d f F x exp 1 3 x m s 1 3 if 3 0 exp e x m s if 3 0 displaystyle F x begin cases exp left left 1 xi frac x mu sigma right 1 xi right amp text if xi neq 0 exp left e frac x mu sigma right amp text if xi 0 end cases nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X m s a 3 G 1 3 ln a a if 3 0 m s a li a a ln ln a if 3 0 displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X begin cases mu frac sigma alpha xi big Gamma 1 xi ln alpha alpha big amp text if xi neq 0 mu frac sigma alpha big text li alpha alpha ln ln alpha big amp text if xi 0 end cases nbsp and the VaR is equal to VaR a X m s 3 ln a 3 1 if 3 0 m s ln ln a if 3 0 displaystyle operatorname VaR alpha X begin cases mu frac sigma xi left ln alpha xi 1 right amp text if xi neq 0 mu sigma ln ln alpha amp text if xi 0 end cases nbsp where G s x displaystyle Gamma s x nbsp is the upper incomplete gamma function l i x d x ln x displaystyle mathrm li x int frac dx ln x nbsp is the logarithmic integral function 12 If the loss of a portfolio L displaystyle L nbsp follows the GEV then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X m s 1 a 3 g 1 3 ln a 1 a if 3 0 m s 1 a y li a a ln ln a if 3 0 displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X begin cases mu frac sigma 1 alpha xi bigl gamma 1 xi ln alpha 1 alpha bigr amp text if xi neq 0 mu frac sigma 1 alpha bigl y text li alpha alpha ln ln alpha bigr amp text if xi 0 end cases nbsp where g s x displaystyle gamma s x nbsp is the lower incomplete gamma function y displaystyle y nbsp is the Euler Mascheroni constant 11 Generalized hyperbolic secant GHS distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows the GHS distribution with p d f f x 1 2 s sech p 2 x m s displaystyle f x frac 1 2 sigma operatorname sech left frac pi 2 frac x mu sigma right nbsp and the c d f F x 2 p arctan exp p 2 x m s displaystyle F x frac 2 pi arctan left exp left frac pi 2 frac x mu sigma right right nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X m 2 s p ln tan p a 2 2 s p 2 a i Li 2 i tan p a 2 Li 2 i tan p a 2 displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X mu frac 2 sigma pi ln left tan frac pi alpha 2 right frac 2 sigma pi 2 alpha i left operatorname Li 2 left i tan frac pi alpha 2 right operatorname Li 2 left i tan frac pi alpha 2 right right nbsp where Li 2 displaystyle operatorname Li 2 nbsp is the dilogarithm and i 1 displaystyle i sqrt 1 nbsp is the imaginary unit 12 Johnson s SU distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows Johnson s SU distribution with the c d f F x F g d sinh 1 x 3 l displaystyle F x Phi left gamma delta sinh 1 left frac x xi lambda right right nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X 3 l 2 a exp 1 2 g d 2 d 2 F F 1 a 1 d exp 1 2 g d 2 d 2 F F 1 a 1 d displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X xi frac lambda 2 alpha left exp left frac 1 2 gamma delta 2 delta 2 right Phi left Phi 1 alpha frac 1 delta right exp left frac 1 2 gamma delta 2 delta 2 right Phi left Phi 1 alpha frac 1 delta right right nbsp where F displaystyle Phi nbsp is the c d f of the standard normal distribution 13 Burr type XII distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows the Burr type XII distribution the p d f f x c k b x g b c 1 1 x g b c k 1 displaystyle f x frac ck beta left frac x gamma beta right c 1 left 1 left frac x gamma beta right c right k 1 nbsp and the c d f F x 1 1 x g b c k displaystyle F x 1 left 1 left frac x gamma beta right c right k nbsp the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X g b a 1 a 1 k 1 1 c a 1 2 F 1 1 c k 1 1 c 1 1 a 1 k displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X gamma frac beta alpha left 1 alpha 1 k 1 right 1 c left alpha 1 2 F 1 left frac 1 c k 1 frac 1 c 1 1 alpha 1 k right right nbsp where 2 F 1 displaystyle 2 F 1 nbsp is the hypergeometric function Alternatively ES a X g b a c k c 1 1 a 1 k 1 1 1 c 2 F 1 1 1 c k 1 2 1 c 1 1 a 1 k displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X gamma frac beta alpha frac ck c 1 left 1 alpha 1 k 1 right 1 frac 1 c 2 F 1 left 1 frac 1 c k 1 2 frac 1 c 1 1 alpha 1 k right nbsp 12 Dagum distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows the Dagum distribution with p d f f x c k b x g b c k 1 1 x g b c k 1 displaystyle f x frac ck beta left frac x gamma beta right ck 1 left 1 left frac x gamma beta right c right k 1 nbsp and the c d f F x 1 x g b c k displaystyle F x left 1 left frac x gamma beta right c right k nbsp the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X g b a c k c k 1 a 1 k 1 k 1 c 2 F 1 k 1 k 1 c k 1 1 c 1 a 1 k 1 displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X gamma frac beta alpha frac ck ck 1 left alpha 1 k 1 right k frac 1 c 2 F 1 left k 1 k frac 1 c k 1 frac 1 c frac 1 alpha 1 k 1 right nbsp where 2 F 1 displaystyle 2 F 1 nbsp is the hypergeometric function 12 Lognormal distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows lognormal distribution i e the random variable ln 1 X displaystyle ln 1 X nbsp follows the normal distribution with p d f f x 1 2 p s e x m 2 2 s 2 displaystyle f x frac 1 sqrt 2 pi sigma e frac x mu 2 2 sigma 2 nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X 1 exp m s 2 2 F F 1 a s a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X 1 exp left mu frac sigma 2 2 right frac Phi left Phi 1 alpha sigma right alpha nbsp where F x displaystyle Phi x nbsp is the standard normal c d f so F 1 a displaystyle Phi 1 alpha nbsp is the standard normal quantile 14 Log logistic distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows log logistic distribution i e the random variable ln 1 X displaystyle ln 1 X nbsp follows the logistic distribution with p d f f x 1 s e x m s 1 e x m s 2 displaystyle f x frac 1 s e frac x mu s left 1 e frac x mu s right 2 nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X 1 e m a I a 1 s 1 s p s sin p s displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X 1 frac e mu alpha I alpha 1 s 1 s frac pi s sin pi s nbsp where I a displaystyle I alpha nbsp is the regularized incomplete beta function I a a b B a a b B a b displaystyle I alpha a b frac mathrm B alpha a b mathrm B a b nbsp As the incomplete beta function is defined only for positive arguments for a more generic case the expected shortfall can be expressed with the hypergeometric function ES a X 1 e m a s s 1 2 F 1 s s 1 s 2 a displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X 1 frac e mu alpha s s 1 2 F 1 s s 1 s 2 alpha nbsp 14 If the loss of a portfolio L displaystyle L nbsp follows log logistic distribution with p d f f x b a x a b 1 1 x a b 2 displaystyle f x frac frac b a x a b 1 1 x a b 2 nbsp and c d f F x 1 1 x a b displaystyle F x frac 1 1 x a b nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a L a 1 a p b csc p b B a 1 b 1 1 1 b displaystyle operatorname ES alpha L frac a 1 alpha left frac pi b csc left frac pi b right mathrm B alpha left frac 1 b 1 1 frac 1 b right right nbsp where B a displaystyle B alpha nbsp is the incomplete beta function 11 Log Laplace distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows log Laplace distribution i e the random variable ln 1 X displaystyle ln 1 X nbsp follows the Laplace distribution the p d f f x 1 2 b e x m b displaystyle f x frac 1 2b e frac x mu b nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X 1 e m 2 a b b 1 if a 0 5 1 e m 2 b a b 1 1 a 1 b 1 if a gt 0 5 displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X begin cases 1 frac e mu 2 alpha b b 1 amp text if alpha leq 0 5 1 frac e mu 2 b alpha b 1 left 1 alpha 1 b 1 right amp text if alpha gt 0 5 end cases nbsp 14 Log generalized hyperbolic secant log GHS distribution edit If the payoff of a portfolio X displaystyle X nbsp follows log GHS distribution i e the random variable ln 1 X displaystyle ln 1 X nbsp follows the GHS distribution with p d f f x 1 2 s sech p 2 x m s displaystyle f x frac 1 2 sigma operatorname sech left frac pi 2 frac x mu sigma right nbsp then the expected shortfall is equal to ES a X 1 1 a s p 2 tan p a 2 exp p m 2 s 2 s p tan p a 2 2 F 1 1 1 2 s p 3 2 s p tan p a 2 2 displaystyle operatorname ES alpha X 1 frac 1 alpha sigma pi 2 left tan frac pi alpha 2 exp frac pi mu 2 sigma right 2 sigma pi tan frac pi alpha 2 2 F 1 left 1 frac 1 2 frac sigma pi frac 3 2 frac sigma pi tan left frac pi alpha 2 right 2 right nbsp where 2 F 1 displaystyle 2 F 1 nbsp is the hypergeometric function 14 Dynamic expected shortfall editThe conditional version of the expected shortfall at the time t is defined by ES a t X e s s sup Q Q a t E Q X F t displaystyle operatorname ES alpha t X operatorname ess sup Q in mathcal Q alpha t E Q X mid mathcal F t nbsp where Q a t Q P F t d Q d P a t 1 a s displaystyle mathcal Q alpha t left Q P vert mathcal F t frac dQ dP leq alpha t 1 text a s right nbsp 15 16 This is not a time consistent risk measure The time consistent version is given by r a t X e s s sup Q Q a t E Q X F t displaystyle rho alpha t X operatorname ess sup Q in tilde mathcal Q alpha t E Q X mid mathcal F t nbsp such that 17 Q a t Q P E d Q d P F t 1 a t 1 E d Q d P F t t t a s displaystyle tilde mathcal Q alpha t left Q ll P operatorname E left frac dQ dP mid mathcal F tau 1 right leq alpha t 1 operatorname E left frac dQ dP mid mathcal F tau right forall tau geq t text a s right nbsp See also editCoherent risk measure EMP for stochastic programming solution technology for optimization problems involving ES and VaR Entropic value at risk Value at riskMethods of statistical estimation of VaR and ES can be found in Embrechts et al 18 and Novak 19 When forecasting VaR and ES or optimizing portfolios to minimize tail risk it is important to account for asymmetric dependence and non normalities in the distribution of stock returns such as auto regression asymmetric volatility skewness and kurtosis 20 References edit Rockafellar R Tyrrell Uryasev Stanislav 2000 Optimization of conditional value at risk PDF Journal of Risk 2 3 21 42 doi 10 21314 JOR 2000 038 S2CID 854622 Rockafellar R Tyrrell Royset Johannes 2010 On Buffered Failure Probability in Design and Optimization of Structures PDF Reliability Engineering and System Safety 95 5 499 510 doi 10 1016 j ress 2010 01 001 S2CID 1653873 Carlo Acerbi Dirk Tasche 2002 Expected Shortfall a natural coherent alternative to Value at Risk PDF Economic Notes 31 2 379 388 arXiv cond mat 0105191 doi 10 1111 1468 0300 00091 S2CID 10772757 Retrieved April 25 2012 Follmer H Schied A 2008 Convex and coherent risk measures PDF Retrieved October 4 2011 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Patrick Cheridito Tianhui Li 2008 Dual characterization of properties of risk measures on Orlicz hearts Mathematics and Financial Economics 2 2 29 doi 10 1007 s11579 008 0013 7 S2CID 121880657 Average Value at Risk PDF Archived from the original PDF on July 19 2011 Retrieved February 2 2011 Julia L Wirch Mary R Hardy Distortion Risk Measures Coherence and Stochastic Dominance PDF Archived from the original PDF on July 5 2016 Retrieved March 10 2012 Balbas A Garrido J Mayoral S 2008 Properties of Distortion Risk Measures PDF Methodology and Computing in Applied Probability 11 3 385 doi 10 1007 s11009 008 9089 z hdl 10016 14071 S2CID 53327887 Rockafellar R Tyrrell Uryasev Stanislav 2000 Optimization of conditional value at risk PDF Journal of Risk 2 3 21 42 doi 10 21314 JOR 2000 038 S2CID 854622 a b c d Khokhlov Valentyn 2016 Conditional Value at Risk for Elliptical Distributions Evropsky casopis Ekonomiky a Managementu 2 6 70 79 a b c d e f g h i j Norton Matthew Khokhlov Valentyn Uryasev Stan 2018 11 27 Calculating CVaR and bPOE for Common Probability Distributions With Application to Portfolio Optimization and Density Estimation arXiv 1811 11301 q fin RM a b c d Khokhlov Valentyn 2018 06 21 Conditional Value at Risk for Uncommon Distributions doi 10 2139 ssrn 3200629 S2CID 219371851 SSRN 3200629 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Stucchi Patrizia 2011 05 31 Moment Based CVaR Estimation Quasi Closed Formulas doi 10 2139 ssrn 1855986 S2CID 124145569 SSRN 1855986 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help a b c d Khokhlov Valentyn 2018 06 17 Conditional Value at Risk for Log Distributions SSRN 3197929 Detlefsen Kai Scandolo Giacomo 2005 Conditional and dynamic convex risk measures PDF Finance Stoch 9 4 539 561 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 453 4944 doi 10 1007 s00780 005 0159 6 S2CID 10579202 Retrieved October 11 2011 dead link Acciaio Beatrice Penner Irina 2011 Dynamic convex risk measures PDF Archived from the original PDF on September 2 2011 Retrieved October 11 2011 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Cheridito Patrick Kupper Michael May 2010 Composition of time consistent dynamic monetary risk measures in discrete time PDF International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance Archived from the original PDF on July 19 2011 Retrieved February 4 2011 Embrechts P Kluppelberg C and Mikosch T Modelling Extremal Events for Insurance and Finance Springer 1997 Novak S Y Extreme value methods with applications to finance Chapman amp Hall CRC Press 2011 ISBN 978 1 4398 3574 6 Low R K Y Alcock J Faff R Brailsford T 2013 Canonical vine copulas in the context of modern portfolio management Are they worth it PDF Journal of Banking amp Finance 37 8 3085 3099 doi 10 1016 j jbankfin 2013 02 036 S2CID 154138333 External links editRockafellar Uryasev Optimization of conditional Value at Risk 2000 C Acerbi and D Tasche On the Coherence of Expected Shortfall 2002 Rockafellar Uryasev Conditional Value at Risk for general loss distributions 2002 Acerbi Spectral measures of risk 2005 Phi Alpha optimal portfolios and extreme risk management Best of Wilmott 2003 Coherent measures of Risk Philippe Artzner Freddy Delbaen Jean Marc Eber and David Heath Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Expected shortfall amp oldid 1191488388, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.