fbpx
Wikipedia

Wilson doctrine (economics)

In economic theory, the Wilson doctrine (or Wilson critique) stipulates that game theory should not rely excessively on common knowledge assumptions. Most prominently, it is interpreted as a request for institutional designs to be "detail-free".[1] That is, mechanism designers should offer solutions that do not depend on market details (such as distributions or functional forms of payoff relevant signals) because they may be unknown to practitioners or are subject to intractable change. The name is due to Nobel laureate Robert Wilson, who argued:[2]

Game theory has a great advantage in explicitly analyzing the consequences of trading rules that presumably are really common knowledge; it is deficient to the extent it assumes other features to be common knowledge, such as one agent's probability assessment about another’s preferences or information. I foresee the progress of game theory as depending on successive reductions in the base of common knowledge required to conduct useful analyses of practical problems. Only by repeated weakening of common knowledge assumptions will the theory approximate reality.

While the above quote is often seen as the Wilson doctrine, mechanism design researchers derive an insistence on detail-free mechanisms from it. For instance, Partha Dasgupta and Eric Maskin,[3] as well as Mark Satterthwaite and Steven Williams,[4] attribute this insistence to Wilson. This interpretation might also go back to another paper by Wilson in which he praises the double auction because it "does not rely on features of the agents' common knowledge, such as their probability assessment".[5] While Wilson himself agrees with the spirit of demanding detail-free mechanisms, he is surprised to be credited for it.[6] In line with the above quote, Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris see the doctrine as a reminder of John Harsanyi's insight that common knowledge assumptions can be made explicit (and then relaxed) by enriching the type space with beliefs.[7] This interpretation gave rise to their notion of robust mechanism design.[8] An alternative approach to robust mechanism design assumes non-probabilistic uncertainty. For instance, Gabriel Carroll has a series of papers in which the principal evaluates outcomes on a worst-case basis.[6]

References edit

  1. ^ Bergemann, Dirk; Välimäki, Juuso (2006). "Information in Mechanism Design". In Blundell, Richard; Newey, Whitney K.; Persson, Torsten (eds.). Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Ninth World Congress. Vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. p. 206. ISBN 978-1-139-05226-9.
  2. ^ Wilson, Robert (1987-06-26), "Game-theoretic analyses of trading processes", Advances in Economic Theory, Cambridge University Press, pp. 33–70, doi:10.1017/ccol0521340446.002, ISBN 978-0-521-38925-9, retrieved 2021-06-04
  3. ^ Dasgupta, P.; Maskin, E. (2000-05-01). "Efficient Auctions". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 115 (2): 341–388. doi:10.1162/003355300554755. ISSN 0033-5533.
  4. ^ Satterthwaite, Mark A.; Williams, Steven R. (2002). "The Optimality of a Simple Market Mechanism". Econometrica. 70 (5): 1841–1863. doi:10.1111/1468-0262.00355. hdl:10419/221612. ISSN 0012-9682.
  5. ^ Wilson, Robert (1985). "Incentive Efficiency of Double Auctions". Econometrica. 53 (5): 1101–1115. doi:10.2307/1911013. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 1911013.
  6. ^ a b Carroll, Gabriel (2019-08-02). "Robustness in Mechanism Design and Contracting". Annual Review of Economics. 11 (1): 139–166. doi:10.1146/annurev-economics-080218-025616. ISSN 1941-1383. S2CID 21675002.
  7. ^ Bergemann, Dirk (2013). "An Introduction to Robust Mechanism Design". Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics. 8 (3): 169–230. doi:10.1561/0700000057. ISSN 1547-9846.
  8. ^ Bergemann, Dirk (2012). Robust mechanism design : the role of private information and higher order beliefs. Stephen Morris. Singapore: World Scientific Pub. ISBN 978-981-4374-59-0. OCLC 794263001.


wilson, doctrine, economics, economic, theory, wilson, doctrine, wilson, critique, stipulates, that, game, theory, should, rely, excessively, common, knowledge, assumptions, most, prominently, interpreted, request, institutional, designs, detail, free, that, m. In economic theory the Wilson doctrine or Wilson critique stipulates that game theory should not rely excessively on common knowledge assumptions Most prominently it is interpreted as a request for institutional designs to be detail free 1 That is mechanism designers should offer solutions that do not depend on market details such as distributions or functional forms of payoff relevant signals because they may be unknown to practitioners or are subject to intractable change The name is due to Nobel laureate Robert Wilson who argued 2 Game theory has a great advantage in explicitly analyzing the consequences of trading rules that presumably are really common knowledge it is deficient to the extent it assumes other features to be common knowledge such as one agent s probability assessment about another s preferences or information I foresee the progress of game theory as depending on successive reductions in the base of common knowledge required to conduct useful analyses of practical problems Only by repeated weakening of common knowledge assumptions will the theory approximate reality While the above quote is often seen as the Wilson doctrine mechanism design researchers derive an insistence on detail free mechanisms from it For instance Partha Dasgupta and Eric Maskin 3 as well as Mark Satterthwaite and Steven Williams 4 attribute this insistence to Wilson This interpretation might also go back to another paper by Wilson in which he praises the double auction because it does not rely on features of the agents common knowledge such as their probability assessment 5 While Wilson himself agrees with the spirit of demanding detail free mechanisms he is surprised to be credited for it 6 In line with the above quote Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris see the doctrine as a reminder of John Harsanyi s insight that common knowledge assumptions can be made explicit and then relaxed by enriching the type space with beliefs 7 This interpretation gave rise to their notion of robust mechanism design 8 An alternative approach to robust mechanism design assumes non probabilistic uncertainty For instance Gabriel Carroll has a series of papers in which the principal evaluates outcomes on a worst case basis 6 References edit Bergemann Dirk Valimaki Juuso 2006 Information in Mechanism Design In Blundell Richard Newey Whitney K Persson Torsten eds Advances in Economics and Econometrics Theory and Applications Ninth World Congress Vol 1 Cambridge Cambridge University Press p 206 ISBN 978 1 139 05226 9 Wilson Robert 1987 06 26 Game theoretic analyses of trading processes Advances in Economic Theory Cambridge University Press pp 33 70 doi 10 1017 ccol0521340446 002 ISBN 978 0 521 38925 9 retrieved 2021 06 04 Dasgupta P Maskin E 2000 05 01 Efficient Auctions The Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 2 341 388 doi 10 1162 003355300554755 ISSN 0033 5533 Satterthwaite Mark A Williams Steven R 2002 The Optimality of a Simple Market Mechanism Econometrica 70 5 1841 1863 doi 10 1111 1468 0262 00355 hdl 10419 221612 ISSN 0012 9682 Wilson Robert 1985 Incentive Efficiency of Double Auctions Econometrica 53 5 1101 1115 doi 10 2307 1911013 ISSN 0012 9682 JSTOR 1911013 a b Carroll Gabriel 2019 08 02 Robustness in Mechanism Design and Contracting Annual Review of Economics 11 1 139 166 doi 10 1146 annurev economics 080218 025616 ISSN 1941 1383 S2CID 21675002 Bergemann Dirk 2013 An Introduction to Robust Mechanism Design Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics 8 3 169 230 doi 10 1561 0700000057 ISSN 1547 9846 Bergemann Dirk 2012 Robust mechanism design the role of private information and higher order beliefs Stephen Morris Singapore World Scientific Pub ISBN 978 981 4374 59 0 OCLC 794263001 nbsp This game theory article is a stub You can help Wikipedia by expanding it vte Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Wilson doctrine economics amp oldid 1195814752, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.