fbpx
Wikipedia

Outcome (game theory)

In game theory, the outcome of a game is the ultimate result of a strategic interaction with one or more people, dependant on the choices made by all participants in a certain exchange. It represents the final payoff resulting from a set of actions that individuals can take within the context of the game. Outcomes are pivotal in determining the payoffs and expected utility for parties involved.[1] Game theorists commonly study how the outcome of a game is determined and what factors affect it.

In game theory, a strategy is a set of actions that a player can take in response to the actions of others. Each player’s strategy is based on their expectation of what the other players are likely to do, often explained in terms of probability.[2] Outcomes are dependent on the combination of strategies chosen by involved players and can be represented in a number of ways; one common way is a payoff matrix showing the individual payoffs for each players with a combination of strategies, as seen in the payoff matrix example below. Outcomes can be expressed in terms of monetary value or utility to a specific person. Additionally, a game tree can be used to deduce the actions leading to an outcome by displaying possible sequences of actions and the outcomes associated.[3]

Payoff Matrix Example

Strategies of Player A

Strategies of Player B
1 2
1 A1, B1 A1, B2
2 A2, B1 A2, B2

A commonly used theorem in relation to outcomes is the Nash equilibrium. This theorem is a combination of strategies in which no player can improve their payoff or outcome by changing their strategy, given the strategies of the other players. In other words, a Nash equilibrium is a set of strategies in which each player is doing the best possible, assuming what the others are doing to receive the most optimal outcome for themselves.[4] It is important to note that not all games have a unique nash equilibrium and if they do, it may not be the most desirable outcome.[5] Additionally, the desired outcomes is greatly affected by individuals chosen strategies, and their beliefs on what they believe other players will do under the assumption that players will make the most rational decision for themselves.[6] A common example of the nash equilibrium and undesirable outcomes is the Prisoner’s Dilemma game.[7]

Choosing among outcomes edit

Many different concepts exist to express how players might interact. An optimal interaction may be one in which no player's payoff can be made greater, without making any other player's payoff lesser. Such a payoff is described as Pareto efficient, and the set of such payoffs is called the Pareto frontier.

Many economists study the ways in which payoffs are in some sort of economic equilibrium. One example of such an equilibrium is the Nash equilibrium, where each player plays a strategy such that their payoff is maximized given the strategy of the other players.

Players are persons who make logical economic decisions. It is assumed that human people make all of their economic decisions based only on the idea that they are irrational. A player's rewards (utilities, profits, income, or subjective advantages) are assumed to be maximised.[8] The purpose of game-theoretic analysis, when applied to a rational approach, is to provide recommendations on how to make choices against other rational players. First, it reduces the possible outcomes; logical action is more predictable than irrational. Second, it provides a criterion for assessing an economic system's efficiency.

In a Prisoner's Dilemma game between two players, player one and player two can choose the utilities that are the best response to maximise their outcomes. "A best response to a coplayer’s strategy is a strategy that yields the highest payoff against that particular strategy".[9] A matrix is used to present the payoff of both players in the game. For example, the best response of player one is the highest payoff for player one’s move, and vice versa. For player one, they will pick the payoffs from the column strategies. For player two, they will choose their moves based on the two row strategies. Assuming both players do not know the opponents strategies.[10] It is a dominant strategy for the first player to choose a payoff of 5 rather than a payoff of 3 because strategy D is a better response than strategy C.

Applications edit

Outcome optimisation in game theory has many real world applications that can help predict actions and economic behaviours by other players.[11] Examples of this include stock trades and investments, cost of goods in business, corporate behaviour and even social sciences.[citation needed]

Equilibria are not always Pareto efficient, and a number of game theorists design ways to enforce Pareto efficient play, or play that satisfies some other sort of social optimality. The theory of this is called implementation theory.

References edit

  1. ^ Osbourne, Martin (2000-11-05). An Introduction to Game Theory (PDF). (Draft). pp. 157–161.
  2. ^ "Nash Equilibrium: How It Works in Game Theory, Examples, Plus Prisoner's Dilemma". Investopedia. Retrieved 2023-04-23.
  3. ^ "ICS 180, April 17, 1997". www.ics.uci.edu. Retrieved 2023-04-24.
  4. ^ "Nash Equilibrium". Corporate Finance Institute. Retrieved 2023-04-23.
  5. ^ Myerson, Roger B. (1999). "Nash Equilibrium and the History of Economic Theory". Journal of Economic Literature. 37 (3): 1067–1082. doi:10.1257/jel.37.3.1067. ISSN 0022-0515. JSTOR 2564872.
  6. ^ Wiszniewska-Matyszkiel, Agnieszka (2016-08-01). "Belief distorted Nash equilibria: introduction of a new kind of equilibrium in dynamic games with distorted information". Annals of Operations Research. 243 (1): 147–177. doi:10.1007/s10479-015-1920-7. ISSN 1572-9338. S2CID 254235057.
  7. ^ "What Is the Prisoner's Dilemma and How Does It Work?". Investopedia. Retrieved 2023-04-23.
  8. ^ Burguillo, Juan C. (2018). Self-organizing coalitions for managing complexity : agent-based simulation of evolutionary game theory models using dynamic social networks for interdisciplinary applications. Cham, Switzerland. ISBN 978-3-319-69896-0.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  9. ^ Encyclopedia of statistics in behavioral science. Hoboken, N.J.: John Wiley & Sons. 2005. ISBN 978-0-470-86080-9.
  10. ^ Prisner, E. (2014). Game theory : through examples. [Washington, District of Columbia]. ISBN 978-1-61444-115-1.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  11. ^ "Game Theory and its Applications". INDUSTRIAL ENGINEERING AND OPERATION RESEARCH. 2019-10-31. Retrieved 2023-04-24.

outcome, game, theory, this, article, needs, additional, citations, verification, please, help, improve, this, article, adding, citations, reliable, sources, unsourced, material, challenged, removed, find, sources, outcome, game, theory, news, newspapers, book. This article needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Outcome game theory news newspapers books scholar JSTOR May 2008 Learn how and when to remove this message For other uses of Outcome see Outcome disambiguation In game theory the outcome of a game is the ultimate result of a strategic interaction with one or more people dependant on the choices made by all participants in a certain exchange It represents the final payoff resulting from a set of actions that individuals can take within the context of the game Outcomes are pivotal in determining the payoffs and expected utility for parties involved 1 Game theorists commonly study how the outcome of a game is determined and what factors affect it In game theory a strategy is a set of actions that a player can take in response to the actions of others Each player s strategy is based on their expectation of what the other players are likely to do often explained in terms of probability 2 Outcomes are dependent on the combination of strategies chosen by involved players and can be represented in a number of ways one common way is a payoff matrix showing the individual payoffs for each players with a combination of strategies as seen in the payoff matrix example below Outcomes can be expressed in terms of monetary value or utility to a specific person Additionally a game tree can be used to deduce the actions leading to an outcome by displaying possible sequences of actions and the outcomes associated 3 Payoff Matrix Example Strategies of Player A Strategies of Player B 1 2 1 A1 B1 A1 B2 2 A2 B1 A2 B2 A commonly used theorem in relation to outcomes is the Nash equilibrium This theorem is a combination of strategies in which no player can improve their payoff or outcome by changing their strategy given the strategies of the other players In other words a Nash equilibrium is a set of strategies in which each player is doing the best possible assuming what the others are doing to receive the most optimal outcome for themselves 4 It is important to note that not all games have a unique nash equilibrium and if they do it may not be the most desirable outcome 5 Additionally the desired outcomes is greatly affected by individuals chosen strategies and their beliefs on what they believe other players will do under the assumption that players will make the most rational decision for themselves 6 A common example of the nash equilibrium and undesirable outcomes is the Prisoner s Dilemma game 7 Choosing among outcomes editMany different concepts exist to express how players might interact An optimal interaction may be one in which no player s payoff can be made greater without making any other player s payoff lesser Such a payoff is described as Pareto efficient and the set of such payoffs is called the Pareto frontier Many economists study the ways in which payoffs are in some sort of economic equilibrium One example of such an equilibrium is the Nash equilibrium where each player plays a strategy such that their payoff is maximized given the strategy of the other players Players are persons who make logical economic decisions It is assumed that human people make all of their economic decisions based only on the idea that they are irrational A player s rewards utilities profits income or subjective advantages are assumed to be maximised 8 The purpose of game theoretic analysis when applied to a rational approach is to provide recommendations on how to make choices against other rational players First it reduces the possible outcomes logical action is more predictable than irrational Second it provides a criterion for assessing an economic system s efficiency In a Prisoner s Dilemma game between two players player one and player two can choose the utilities that are the best response to maximise their outcomes A best response to a coplayer s strategy is a strategy that yields the highest payoff against that particular strategy 9 A matrix is used to present the payoff of both players in the game For example the best response of player one is the highest payoff for player one s move and vice versa For player one they will pick the payoffs from the column strategies For player two they will choose their moves based on the two row strategies Assuming both players do not know the opponents strategies 10 It is a dominant strategy for the first player to choose a payoff of 5 rather than a payoff of 3 because strategy D is a better response than strategy C Applications editOutcome optimisation in game theory has many real world applications that can help predict actions and economic behaviours by other players 11 Examples of this include stock trades and investments cost of goods in business corporate behaviour and even social sciences citation needed Equilibria are not always Pareto efficient and a number of game theorists design ways to enforce Pareto efficient play or play that satisfies some other sort of social optimality The theory of this is called implementation theory References edit Osbourne Martin 2000 11 05 An Introduction to Game Theory PDF Draft pp 157 161 Nash Equilibrium How It Works in Game Theory Examples Plus Prisoner s Dilemma Investopedia Retrieved 2023 04 23 ICS 180 April 17 1997 www ics uci edu Retrieved 2023 04 24 Nash Equilibrium Corporate Finance Institute Retrieved 2023 04 23 Myerson Roger B 1999 Nash Equilibrium and the History of Economic Theory Journal of Economic Literature 37 3 1067 1082 doi 10 1257 jel 37 3 1067 ISSN 0022 0515 JSTOR 2564872 Wiszniewska Matyszkiel Agnieszka 2016 08 01 Belief distorted Nash equilibria introduction of a new kind of equilibrium in dynamic games with distorted information Annals of Operations Research 243 1 147 177 doi 10 1007 s10479 015 1920 7 ISSN 1572 9338 S2CID 254235057 What Is the Prisoner s Dilemma and How Does It Work Investopedia Retrieved 2023 04 23 Burguillo Juan C 2018 Self organizing coalitions for managing complexity agent based simulation of evolutionary game theory models using dynamic social networks for interdisciplinary applications Cham Switzerland ISBN 978 3 319 69896 0 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint location missing publisher link Encyclopedia of statistics in behavioral science Hoboken N J John Wiley amp Sons 2005 ISBN 978 0 470 86080 9 Prisner E 2014 Game theory through examples Washington District of Columbia ISBN 978 1 61444 115 1 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint location missing publisher link Game Theory and its Applications INDUSTRIAL ENGINEERING AND OPERATION RESEARCH 2019 10 31 Retrieved 2023 04 24 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Outcome game theory amp oldid 1222716364, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.