fbpx
Wikipedia

Optimal tax

Optimal tax theory or the theory of optimal taxation is the study of designing and implementing a tax that maximises a social welfare function subject to economic constraints.[1] The social welfare function used is typically a function of individuals' utilities, most commonly some form of utilitarian function, so the tax system is chosen to maximise the aggregate of individual utilities. Tax revenue is required to fund the provision of public goods and other government services, as well as for redistribution from rich to poor individuals. However, most taxes distort individual behavior, because the activity that is taxed becomes relatively less desirable; for instance, taxes on labour income reduce the incentive to work.[2] The optimization problem involves minimizing the distortions caused by taxation, while achieving desired levels of redistribution and revenue.[3][4] Some taxes are thought to be less distorting, such as lump-sum taxes (where individuals cannot change their behaviour to reduce their tax burden) and Pigouvian taxes, where the market consumption of a good is inefficient, and a tax brings consumption closer to the efficient level.[5]

In the Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith observed that

“Good taxes meet four major criteria. They are (1) proportionate to incomes or abilities to pay (2) certain rather than arbitrary (3) payable at times and in ways convenient to the taxpayers and (4) cheap to administer and collect.” [6]

Tax revenue edit

Generating a sufficient amount of revenue to finance government is arguably the most important purpose of the tax system. Optimal taxation theory attempts to derive the system of taxation that will achieve the desired revenue and income distribution with the least inefficiency—that is, that interferes least with market participants making Pareto optimal exchanges—economic transactions that make both parties better off.[7]

Free Market economies use prices to allocate resources to produce the products society wants most. If demand exceeds supply, the price will rise as those who want the product most compete to buy it. The high price induces producers to make more, until supply is adequate to meet demand and the price comes down. If supply exceeds demand, the price falls as producers try to induce more people to buy the product. The low prices then induce producers to make something else, that consumers want more.

If the government imposes a tax however, the price the consumer pays is different from the price the producer receives because the government takes its cut. If demand is inelastic—if consumers will pay what they must to get the product at any price, consumers will pay the tax and government will appropriate some of their benefit from the transaction (and hopefully provide useful services like public education in exchange). If supply is inelastic—producers will sell the same amount regardless of price—producers will pay the tax and government will take some of their benefit from the transaction. Note that it does not matter which side actually writes the government's check, the market price will adjust to compensate (see Tax incidence).

However, if both supply and demand are elastic—producers will make less at a lower price and consumers will buy less at a higher price—then the equilibrium quantity will decrease. There may be a consumer willing to buy at a price for which a producer is willing to sell, but this Pareto optimal transaction does not occur because neither is willing to pay the government's cut. The consumer then buys something less desirable and the producer makes something less profitable (or simply produces less and enjoys more leisure), so that the economy is no longer producing the optimal mix of products. Moreover, the sale does not occur, so the government never collects the revenue that was the whole reason for the distortion. This is the deadweight loss—the government has not merely taken a cut of the benefits from the exchange, it has destroyed those benefits for all three.[7] These are the results optimal tax theorists seek to avoid.

Horizontal and vertical equity edit

Another criterion for an optimal tax is that it should be equitable. Equity in the context of taxation demands that the tax burden should be proportional to the taxpayer's ability to pay. This criteria can be further broken down into horizontal equity (imposing the same tax on two taxpayers with equal ability to pay) and vertical equity (imposing greater tax burdens on those with greater ability to pay). Of course, reasonable minds may differ as to whether two taxpayers, in fact, have equal ability to pay, and on how quickly the tax burden should rise with ability to pay (that is, how progressive the tax code should be).[8]

Of the hundreds of provisions in the US tax code, for example, only a handful actually impose a tax (26 USC Sections 1, 11, 55, 881, 882, 3301, and 3311 are the primary examples). Instead, most of those provisions help to define how much income a taxpayer has—that is, their ability to pay. Even after the code has answered all the technical questions and determined a taxpayer's taxable income, normative questions remain as to whether they have the same ability to pay. For example, the US tax code (26 U.S.C. Section 1(a)-(d)) imposes less tax on couples filing joint returns and on heads of households than it does on taxpayers that are single, and provides a credit reducing the tax bills of those supporting children (26 U.S.C. Section 24). This can be seen as an attempt at horizontal equity, reflecting a judgement that taxpayers supporting families have less ability to pay than taxpayers with the same income but no dependents.

Vertical equity raises an additional normative question: once we have agreed which taxpayers have the same ability to pay and which taxpayers have more, how much more should those with greater ability to pay be made to contribute? While that question has no definitive answer, tax policy must balance competing goals such as revenue raising, redistribution, and efficiency.

However, as with any tax, implementing higher taxes will negatively affect incentives and alter an individual's behavior. In his article "Effects of Taxes on Economic Behavior," Martin Feldstein discusses how economic behavior determined by taxes is important for estimating revenue, calculating efficiency and understanding the negative externalities in the short run. In his article, like much of his research on this topic, he chooses to focus primarily on how households are affected. Feldstein recognizes that high taxes deter people from actively engaging in the market, causing a lower production rate as well as a deadweight loss. Yet, because it is difficult to see tangible results of deadweight loss, policy makers largely ignore it. Feldstein expresses his frustration that policy makers have yet to grasp these concepts and therefore do not make policy that correct this wrong.[9]

The thrust of thinking among some economists is that taxes on consumption are always more efficient than taxes on income, arguing that the latter have a greater disincentive effect. One problem with this analysis is defining what constitutes consumption and what constitutes investment.[4] Another problem is that the impact will vary from country to country, depending on the design of the tax system and the relative levels of different tax rates. A more nuanced empirical analysis is required to evaluate this issue. For lower-income working people, who spend most of their income, taxes on consumption also have a significant disincentive effect; while higher-income people may be motivated more by prestige and professional achievement than by after-tax income. Any gain in economic efficiency from shifting taxes to consumption may be quite small, while the adverse effects on income distribution may be large.[10]

Lump-sum taxes edit

One type of tax that does not create a large excess burden is the lump-sum tax. A lump-sum tax is a fixed tax that must be paid by everyone and the amount a person is taxed remains constant regardless of income or owned assets. It does not create excess burden because these taxes do not alter economic decisions. Because the tax remains constant, an individual's incentives and a firm's incentives will not fluctuate, as opposed to a graduated income tax that taxes people more for earning more.

Lump-sum taxes can be either progressive or regressive, depending on what the lump sum is being applied to. A tax placed on car tags would be regressive because it would be the same for everyone regardless of the type of car the owner purchased and, at least in the United States, even the poor own cars. People earning lower incomes would then pay more as a percentage of their income than higher-income earners. A tax on the unimproved aspects of land tends to be a progressive tax, since the wealthier one is, the more land one tends to own and the poor typically do not own any land at all.

Lump-sum taxes are not politically expedient because they sometimes require a complete overhaul of the tax system. Lump-sum taxes are also unpopular when they are assessed per capita because they are regressive and make no allowance for a citizen's ability to pay.

A one-off, unexpected lump-sum levy which is proportional to wealth or income is also non-distorting. In this case, although wealth or income is penalised, the unexpected nature of the tax means that there is no disincentive to asset accumulation- as by definition those accumulating such assets are unaware that a portion of those assets will be taxed in the future.

Commodity taxes edit

Frank P. Ramsey (1927) developed a theory for optimal commodity sales taxes in his article "A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation". The problem is closely linked to the problem of socially optimal monopolistic pricing when profits are constrained to be positive, known as the Ramsey problem. He was the first to make a significant contribution to the theory of optimal taxation from an economic standpoint, and much of the literature that has followed reflects Ramsey's initial observations.

He wanted to confront the problem of how to adjust consumption tax rates, under specified constraints, so that the reduction of utility is at a minimum. In an attempt to reduce excess burden of consumption taxes, Ramsey proposed a theoretical solution that consumption tax on each good should be "proportional to the sum of the reciprocals of its supply and demand elasticities".[11] However, practically, it is problematic to constrain social planners to one form of taxation. It is better to enable them to consider all possible tax structures.[12][13]

Using Ramsey's rule as a basis for their papers, Peter Diamond and James Mirrlees propose an alternative to Ramsey's proposition by allowing the planner to consider numerous tax systems, and their model has prevailed in taxation theories. In their first paper, "Optimal Taxation and Public Production I: Production Efficiency" Diamond and Mirrlees consider the problem of imperfect information exchanged between taxpayers and the social planner.[14] According to their argument, an individual's ability to earn income differs. Though the planner can observe income, they cannot directly observe the individual's ability or effort to earn income, so that if the planner attempts to increase taxes on those with high ability to earn an income, the individual's incentives to earn a high-income decrease. They confront the government tradeoff between equality and efficiency that when higher taxes are imposed on those with the potential to earn higher wages, they are not incentivized to expend the extra effort to earn a greater income. They rely on what has been labeled the revelation principle where planners must implement a tax system that provides proper incentives for people to reveal their true wage-earning abilities.[14]

They continued this idea in the second installment of their paper "Optimal Taxation and Public Production II: Tax Rules", where they discuss marginal tax rate schedules for labor income.[15] If the policy maker implemented a tax increase in the marginal tax rate at a lower income, it discourages the individuals at that income from working hard. However, this same increase for high-income individuals does not distort their incentives because though it raises their average tax rate, their marginal tax rate remains the same. For example, giving $100 is worth more to a low-income earner than to a high-income earner. Diamond and Mirrlees came to the conclusion that the marginal tax rate for the top earner should be equal to zero and the optimal rate must be between zero and one. This provides the correct incentives for individuals to work at their optimal level.[15]

Developments in tax theory edit

William J. Baumol and David F. Bradford in their article "Optimal Departures from Marginal Cost Pricing" also discuss the price distortion taxes cause.[16] They examine the proposition that in order to reach the optimal point of allocating resources, prices that deviate from marginal cost are required. They recognize that with every tax, there is some sort of price distortion, so they state that any solution can only be the second-best option and any solution proposed is under that added constraint. However, their theory differs from other literature in this topic. First, it deals with quasi-optimal pricing, looking at four options for Pareto optimality with adjusted commodity prices. Second, they express their theory in more simplified terms which incurs a loss of realistic application. Third, it combines the three discussions: the welfare theory, the contributions of the regulations and public finance. They conclude that under constraints, the best possible theory to get close to optimality, which is not “best” at all, is the systematic division between prices and marginal costs.[16]

In his article entitled "Optimal Taxation in Theory", Gregory Mankiw reviews that current literature in theories on optimal taxation and analyzes the change in the tax theory over the past few decades. Like Diamond and Mirrlees, Mankiw recognizes the flaw in Ramsey's model that planners can raise revenue through taxes only on commodities but also points out the weakness of Mirrlees's proposition. Mankiw argues that Diamond's and Mirrlees's theory is extremely complex because of how difficult it is to keep track of individuals producing at their maximum levels.[12]

Mankiw provides a summary of eight lessons that represent the current thought in optimal taxation literature. They include, first, the idea considering horizontal and vertical equity, that social planners should base optimal tax schedules on income rates for labour, which marks the equality and efficiency trade-off. Second, the more income an individual makes, their marginal tax schedule could actually decrease because they are discouraged from working at their optimal production level. The solution is to, after individuals reach a certain income level, ensure that the marginal tax remains steady. Third, reaching an optimal tax level could mean flat taxes. Fourth, the increase in wage inequality is directly proportionate to the extent of income redistribution as revenue is distributed to low-income earners. Fifth, taxes should not only depend on income amounts, but also on personal characteristics such as a person's wage-earning capabilities. Sixth, goods produced should only be taxed as a final good and should be taxed uniformly, which leads to their seventh point that capital should also not be taxed because it is considered an input of production. Finally, policymakers should consider individuals’ income histories, which require reliance on different types of taxation to derive optimal taxation. Mankiw identifies that the tax policy has largely followed the theories laid out in tax literature because social planners believe that the flatter the tax, the better, there are declining top marginal rates in OECD countries and taxes on commodities are now uniform and usually only final goods are taxed.[12]

Joel Slemrod in his paper "Optimal Taxation and Optimal Tax System", argues that optimal tax theory, as it stood when Slemrod wrote this paper, was an insufficient guide to determine tax policies because policymakers had yet to find a way to implement a tax system that enticed individuals to work at their optimal level.[17] As a solution, Slemrod proposes the theory of optimal tax systems a phrase he uses to refer to the normative theory of taxation. Slemrod advocates this theory because not only does it take into account the preferences of individuals, but also the technology involved in tax collecting. A practical application of this, for example, is implementing value-added taxes, a tax on the purchase price of a good or service, to correct tax evasion. He argues that any future tax literature in normative theory needs to focus less on consumer preferences and more on tax-collecting technology and the areas of the economy that affect tax collection.[17]

Globalisation has also taken an important role in the development of taxes and tax systems. As referred previously, taxes have the purpose of fixing economic disparities among individuals, and that assortment of living standards and income generates competitiveness, especially among countries. The globalisation process has created new rules for companies and citizens to move across borders and, therefore, the tax systems they shall oblige to. Consequently, countries compete with each other on the taxation programme offered to both singular individuals and corporations, with the aim of becoming attractive to foreign agents, and simultaneously breed tax revenues to fund the government’s budget. Regarding the government’s budget and its strategy, it can also be a factor of attractiveness. Generally, countries with higher tax levels have also a tax structure tax differs from other countries,[18] which can be related to the share of the government's expenditure that is invested in the population. For example, Sweden has one of the highest tax revenues (% of GDP),[19] but invests almost 16% of the government expenditure in education.[20] According to an OECD report,[18] multiple countries have been changing their tax policies, being the normal procedure to cut the tax rate and broaden the tax base,[21] which improves efficiency. From the same report, some situations were pointed out regarding the importance of the choice of tax policies, such as the imposition of taxes on products and services and the way these are perceived when exported, and the progressiveness of the taxes that can affect the inflow of economic agents (especially high-income ones). Initially, the last point was almost always directed to firms, but nowadays more high skilled workers are concerned with the subject; as opposed to low-skilled workers that are less affected by globalisation since the tax bases are not so flexible.[18] Some studies show that there is a positive correlation between globalisation and capital taxes but, at the same time, that governments decrease the corporate taxes because of the globalisation phenomenon.[22] It may sound somewhat paradoxical, but the change in the tax rates makes individuals more aware of the tariffs that are practised in other countries, contributing then for the globalisation.

Income taxes edit

Another aspect of optimal taxation is determining income taxes, which can be regressive, flat, or progressive.

Labor income tax edit

The theory of optimal income tax on individual labor aims to find the optimal trade-off between the following three effects of increasing taxation:

  • The mechanical effect - an increase in tax-rate increases the government revenue, if no individuals changed their behaviour in response.
  • The behavioural effect - an increase in tax-rate discourages labour supply, and this leads to lower tax revenue as a result.
  • The welfare effect - an increase in tax-rate reduces the individual utility, and thus reduces social welfare.

Corporate income tax edit

Arnold Harberger researched optimal taxation for corporations. Corporation income taxes are based on corporate profits. In the Journal of Political Economy, Harberger wrote an article called "The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax" where he provided a theoretical framework to understand the effects of corporate income taxes and to determine the impact of such taxes in the United States.[23] He proposed a general-equilibrium model, in which he analyzed a two-sector economy (one corporate and the other not). In this model, Harberger concluded that the market will move toward a long-run equilibrium in which the after tax rate of return of all corporations would equalize, compensating for any impact of corporate income taxes. Thus, taxing profits would lower the overall rate of return and therefore the level of investment and output in the economy. Furthermore, he claimed that this model could apply to a broader range of conditions.[9][23]

Martin Feldstein disputed Harberger's assumptions. Feldstein argues that one of Harberger's shortcomings is that policy makers typically focused on the effects on personal income tax. Feldstein argued that policy makers should analyze corporate and personal taxation separately. He presented a method on how to reflect the net effect of the changes ro corporate tax rates on individual tax returns by focusing on the difference between real and nominal capital income. Feldstein noted the shortcomings of his model because of the lack of data to properly compare the two.[9]

William Fox and LeAnn Luna proposed another theory in a joint article called "State Corporate Tax Revenue Trends: Causes and Possible Solutions", in which they take on the role of this taxation. They purport to determine the effects on revenue and propose some ways to reverse the trend. They claim that because the effective corporate income tax rate fell by one-third over two decades, the effective tax rate decline was the result of a tax base that is eroding in relation to income and profits. This was because legislation narrowed the tax base.[24]

One option to reduce the negative investment effect of corporate taxes on the level of private investment (and hence increase investment) is the provision of an investment tax credit or accelerated depreciation. In these cases, the effective rate becomes a negative function of the reinvestment rate.

In recent years, the concept of a corporate tax system incorporating deductions for "normal" profits (where normal is defined in relation to the long-term interest rate and the risk premium) has gained attention as a tax system that could minimise these distortions without reducing total tax revenue. Such a taxation system would in effect levy a higher rate of tax on firms earning "superprofits" which will likely be unaffected even when taxed at a higher rate, as the post-tax return on capital is significantly higher than the threshold or "normal" level. Conversely, the effective tax rate on marginal projects (with returns closer to the "normal" level) will be reduced. One example of such a tax system is Australia's Minerals Resource Rent Tax.

When an investment tax credit or equity-based deduction is applied, the optimal effective rate of taxation is generally increased as the distortionary effect of a given level of taxation is diminished. If the unadjusted tax rate was optimal, the assumption is that the net marginal benefit of increased taxation is zero near the optimum rate (the marginal costs and benefits sum to zero). If the distortionary costs of capital taxation are then lowered by deductions or credits, then the net benefit of rate increases will become positive, implying the tax rate should be raised.

Sales tax edit

A third consideration for optimal taxation is sales tax, which is the additional price added to the base price of a paid by the consumer at the point when they purchase a good or service. Poterba in a second article called "Retail Price Reactions To Changes in State and Local Sales Taxes" tests the premise that sales taxes on the state and local level are fully shifted to the consumers.[25] He examines clothing prices before and after World War II. He recognizes that monetary policy is important to determine the response of nominal prices under a national sales tax and points to possible differences in taxes applied at the local level as to taxes applied at a national level. Poterba finds evidence reinforcing the idea that sales taxes are fully forward shifted, which raises the consumer prices to match the tax increase. His study coincides with the original hypothesis that retail sales taxes are fully shifted to retail prices.[25]

Donald Bruce, William Fox, and M. H. Tuttle also discuss tax revenues through sales tax in their article "Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics".[26] In this article, they look at how personal state revenues and sales tax bases elasticities change for the short and long term in an attempt to determine the difference between them. With this information, the authors believe that states can both enhance and customize their tax structures, which can be used for careful resource planning. They found that for state personal income tax bases as compared to sales taxes, the average long-term income elasticity is more than doubled and the short-term display disproportionate results higher than the long-term elasticities. The authors contend with the conventional literature by declaring that neither the personal income tax nor the sales tax is, at least, universally, the more volatile tax. Though, the authors concede that in certain situations, the sales tax is more volatile, and in the long term, personal income taxes are more elastic.[26]

Furthermore, in understanding this argument, it must also be considered, as Alan Auerbach, Jagadeesh Gokhale, and Laurence Kotlikoff do in "Generational Accounting: A Meaningful Way to Evaluate Fiscal Policy", what the implications to optimal taxation are for future generations.[27] They propose that generational accounting represents a new method for fiscal planning in the long-run, and that unlike the budget deficit, this generational accounting is not arbitrary. Instead, it is a remedy for how to approach the generation burden and effects of fiscal policy on a macroeconomic level. Ethically, it is a problem to have low taxes now, and therefore low revenue now, because it inevitably puts the burden of responsibility to pay for those expenditures on future generations. So through generational accounting, it is possible to analyze this and provide the necessary information for policy makers to change the policies needed to alter this trend. However, according to Auerbach, politicians are currently only relying on accounting and are not seeing the potential consequences that will ensue in future generations.[27]

The incidence of sales taxes on commodities also results in distortion if say food prepared in restaurants is taxed but supermarket-bought food prepared at home is not taxed at purchase. If a taxpayer needs to buy food at fast food restaurants because he/she is not wealthy enough to purchase extra leisure time (by working less) he/she pays the tax although a more prosperous person who enjoys playing at being a home chef is taxed more lightly. This differential taxation of commodities may cause inefficiency (by discouraging work in the market in favor of work in the household).

Capital income tax edit

The theory of optimal capital income tax considers the capital income as future consumption. Thus, the taxation of capital income corresponds to a differentiated consumption tax on present and future consumption, and results in the distortion of individuals' saving and consumption behavior as individuals substitute the more heavily taxed future consumption with current consumption. Due to these distortions, zero taxation of capital income might be optimal, a result postulated by the Atkinson–Stiglitz theorem (1976) and the Chamley–Judd zero capital income tax result (1985/1986). In contrast, subsequent work on optimal capital income taxation has elucidated the assumptions underlying the theoretical optimality of a zero capital income tax and advanced diverse arguments for a positive (or negative) optimal capital tax.

Capital taxes edit

Taxation of wealth or capital (i.e. stocks, assets) should not be confused with taxation of capital income or income from wealth (i.e. transfers, flows). Taxation of capital in any form: above all financial instruments, assets then property was proposed as most optimal by Thomas Piketty.[28] His proposition consist of progressive taxation of capital up to 5% yearly. Gregory Papanikos showed that even proportional taxation of capital may be considered as optimal. [29]

Land value taxation edit

One of the early propositions on taxing capital (according to the broader neoclassical definition of "capital") was to capture the full rental value of land. Political economist and social reformer Henry George most notably championed the idea of a land value tax in Progress and Poverty, as a levy on the value of unimproved or natural aspects of the land, primarily location; it disregards the improvements such as buildings and irrigation.[30] Land value taxation has no deadweight loss because the input of production being taxed (land) is fixed in supply; it cannot hide, shrink in value, or flee to other jurisdictions when taxed.

Economic theory suggests that a pure land value tax which succeeds in avoiding taxation of improvements could actually have a negative deadweight loss (positive externality), due to productivity gains arising from efficient land use.[31][32] The taxation of locational values encourages socially optimal development on land in highly valued areas, like cities, since it reduces the incentive to speculate in land prices by leaving potentially productive locations vacant or underused.[33]

Despite its theoretical benefits, implementing land value taxes is difficult politically. However, land value tax is considered progressive, because the ownership of land values is more concentrated than other sources of revenue, such as personal income or spending.[34] George argued that because land is the fruit of nature (not labor) and the value of location is created by the community, the revenue from land should belong to the community.[35]

See also edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory; Weinzierl, Matthew; Yagan, Danny (2009). "Optimal Taxation in Theory and Practice". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 23 (4): 147–174. doi:10.1257/jep.23.4.147.
  2. ^ Keane, Michael P (December 2011). (PDF). Journal of Economic Literature. 49 (4): 961–1075. doi:10.1257/jel.49.4.961. ISSN 0022-0515. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2020-04-13. Retrieved 2019-12-14.
  3. ^ Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas J. Sargent (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, 2nd ed, MIT Press, ISBN 0-262-19451-1, p. 444.
  4. ^ a b Simkovic, Michael (23 February 2015). "Distortionary Taxation of Human Capital Acquisition Costs". Social Science Research Network. SSRN 2551567.
  5. ^ Mirrlees, James; Adam, Stuart. Tax by design : the Mirrlees review. pp. 31–32. ISBN 9780191617591. OCLC 761694695. {{cite book}}: |work= ignored (help)
  6. ^ Smith, Adam (2015). The Wealth of Nations: A Translation into Modern English. Industrial Systems Research. p. 429. ISBN 9780906321706.
  7. ^ a b Bruce, Donald; John Deskins; William Fox (2005). Auerbach, Alan (ed.). "On the Extent, Growth, and Consequences of State Business Tax Planning". Corporate Income Taxation in the 21st Century. Cambridge University Press.
  8. ^ Holcombe, Randall (2006). Public Sector Economics; The Role of Government in the American Economy. New Jersey: Pearson.
  9. ^ a b c Feldstein, Martin (2008). "Effects of Taxes on Economic Behavior" (PDF). NBER (13745).
  10. ^ Rhys Kesselman, Jonathan; Spiro, Peter S. (2014). "Challenges in Shifting Canadian Taxation Toward Consumption". Canadian Tax Journal. 62 (1): 1–39. SSRN 2372735.
  11. ^ Ramsey, Frank (1927). "A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation". Economic Journal. 37 (145): 47–61. doi:10.2307/2222721. JSTOR 2222721.
  12. ^ a b c Mankiw, Gregory; Matthew Weinzierl; Danny Yagan (2009). "Optimal Taxation in Theory". NBER (15071).
  13. ^ Sanchirico, Chris (2011) [Working paper posted 2009]. "Tax Eclecticism". Tax Law Review. 64: 149–228. SSRN 1491130.
  14. ^ a b Mirrlees, James; Peter Diamond (1971). "Optimal Taxation and Public Production I: Production Efficiency". American Economic Review. 61: 8–27.
  15. ^ a b Mirrlees, James; Peter Diamond (1971). "Optimal Taxation and Public Production II: Tax Rules". American Economic Review. 61: 261–278.
  16. ^ a b Baumol, William; David Bradford (1970). "Optimal Departures from Marginal Cost Pricing". The American Economic Review. 60: 265–283.
  17. ^ a b Slemrod, Joel (July 1989). "Optimal Taxation and Optimal Tax Systems". NBER. doi:10.3386/w3038.
  18. ^ a b c OECD (2010). "Tax Policy Reform and Economic Growth". OECD Tax Policy Studies. 20. doi:10.1787/9789264091085-en. ISBN 9789264091078.
  19. ^ "Tax revenue (% of GDP)". The World Bank - Data. The World Bank.
  20. ^ "Government expenditure on education, total (% of government expenditure)". The World Bank - Data. The World Bank.
  21. ^ "Base Broadening Definition". TaxEDU. Tax Foundation.
  22. ^ Lucas, Bretschger; Frank, Hettich (2002). "Globalisation, capital mobility and tax competition: theory and evidence for OECD countries". European Journal of Political Economy. 18 (4): 695–716. doi:10.1016/S0176-2680(02)00115-5. hdl:10419/48898.
  23. ^ a b Harberger, Arthur (1962). "The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax". Journal of Political Economy. 70 (3): 215–240. doi:10.1086/258636. S2CID 154336077.
  24. ^ Fox, William; LeAnn Luna (2002). "State Corporate Tax Revenue Trends: Causes and Possible Solutions". National Tax Journal. 55 (3): 491–508. doi:10.17310/ntj.2002.3.07. S2CID 55018225.
  25. ^ a b Poterba, James (1996). "Retail Price Reactions to Changes in State and Local Sales Taxes". National Tax Journal. 79 (49): 165–176. doi:10.1086/NTJ41789195. S2CID 154762393.
  26. ^ a b Bruce, Donald; William Fox; M. H. Tuttle (2006). "Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics". Southern Economic Journal. 73 (2): 315–341. doi:10.2307/20111894. JSTOR 20111894.
  27. ^ a b Auerbach, Alan; Jagadeesh Gokhale; Laurence Kotlkoff (1999). "Generational Accounting: A Meaningful Way to Evaluate Fiscal Policy". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 8: 73–94. doi:10.1257/jep.8.1.73.
  28. ^ Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, 2014)
  29. ^ Papanikos, Gregory (2015). "Taxing Wealth and Only Wealth in an Advanced Economy with an Oversized Informal Economy and Vast Tax Evasion: The Case of Greece" (PDF). Vierteljahrshefte zur Wirtschaftsforschung. 84 (3): 83–106. doi:10.3790/vjh.84.3.85. hdl:10419/150061.
  30. ^ George, Henry (1879). Progress and Poverty. New York: Page & Co.
  31. ^ Tideman, Nicolaus (1995). Taxing Land is Better Than Neutral: Land Taxes, Land Speculation and the Timing of Development. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Retrieved 17 June 2014.
  32. ^ Mattauch, Linus; Siegmeier, Jan; Edenhofer, Ottmar; Creutzig, Felix (2013), "Financing Public Capital through Land Rent Taxation: A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem", CESifo Working Paper, No. 4280.
  33. ^ Plassmann, Florenz (24 June 1997). "The Impact of Two-Rate Taxes on Construction in Pennsylvania". hdl:10919/30622. Retrieved 22 September 2020.
  34. ^ Gaffney, Mason (1971). (PDF). masongaffney.org/. Resources for the Future, Inc; Reprinted from the Proceedings of the Sixty-Fourth Annual Conference on Taxation sponsored by the National Tax Association. Archived from the original (PDF) on 15 March 2012. Retrieved 7 October 2013.
  35. ^ "Levying the land". The Economist. June 29, 2013. Retrieved 3 October 2013.

References edit

  • Mayshar, J. (1990). "Measures of Excess Burden". Journal of Public Economics. 43 (3): 263–289. doi:10.1016/0047-2727(90)90001-x.
  • Ramsey, F. P. (1927). "A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation". The Economic Journal. 37 (145): 47–61. doi:10.2307/2222721. JSTOR 2222721.
  • J. Slemrod and S. Yitzhaki (1996) "The costs of taxation and the marginal efficiency cost of funds," International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, March 1996, 43, 1
  • N. H. Stern (1987). "Optimal taxation", The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 1, pp. 865–67.

optimal, theory, theory, optimal, taxation, study, designing, implementing, that, maximises, social, welfare, function, subject, economic, constraints, social, welfare, function, used, typically, function, individuals, utilities, most, commonly, some, form, ut. Optimal tax theory or the theory of optimal taxation is the study of designing and implementing a tax that maximises a social welfare function subject to economic constraints 1 The social welfare function used is typically a function of individuals utilities most commonly some form of utilitarian function so the tax system is chosen to maximise the aggregate of individual utilities Tax revenue is required to fund the provision of public goods and other government services as well as for redistribution from rich to poor individuals However most taxes distort individual behavior because the activity that is taxed becomes relatively less desirable for instance taxes on labour income reduce the incentive to work 2 The optimization problem involves minimizing the distortions caused by taxation while achieving desired levels of redistribution and revenue 3 4 Some taxes are thought to be less distorting such as lump sum taxes where individuals cannot change their behaviour to reduce their tax burden and Pigouvian taxes where the market consumption of a good is inefficient and a tax brings consumption closer to the efficient level 5 In the Wealth of Nations Adam Smith observed that Good taxes meet four major criteria They are 1 proportionate to incomes or abilities to pay 2 certain rather than arbitrary 3 payable at times and in ways convenient to the taxpayers and 4 cheap to administer and collect 6 Contents 1 Tax revenue 1 1 Horizontal and vertical equity 1 2 Lump sum taxes 2 Commodity taxes 3 Developments in tax theory 4 Income taxes 4 1 Labor income tax 4 2 Corporate income tax 4 3 Sales tax 4 4 Capital income tax 5 Capital taxes 5 1 Land value taxation 6 See also 7 Notes 8 ReferencesTax revenue editGenerating a sufficient amount of revenue to finance government is arguably the most important purpose of the tax system Optimal taxation theory attempts to derive the system of taxation that will achieve the desired revenue and income distribution with the least inefficiency that is that interferes least with market participants making Pareto optimal exchanges economic transactions that make both parties better off 7 Free Market economies use prices to allocate resources to produce the products society wants most If demand exceeds supply the price will rise as those who want the product most compete to buy it The high price induces producers to make more until supply is adequate to meet demand and the price comes down If supply exceeds demand the price falls as producers try to induce more people to buy the product The low prices then induce producers to make something else that consumers want more If the government imposes a tax however the price the consumer pays is different from the price the producer receives because the government takes its cut If demand is inelastic if consumers will pay what they must to get the product at any price consumers will pay the tax and government will appropriate some of their benefit from the transaction and hopefully provide useful services like public education in exchange If supply is inelastic producers will sell the same amount regardless of price producers will pay the tax and government will take some of their benefit from the transaction Note that it does not matter which side actually writes the government s check the market price will adjust to compensate see Tax incidence However if both supply and demand are elastic producers will make less at a lower price and consumers will buy less at a higher price then the equilibrium quantity will decrease There may be a consumer willing to buy at a price for which a producer is willing to sell but this Pareto optimal transaction does not occur because neither is willing to pay the government s cut The consumer then buys something less desirable and the producer makes something less profitable or simply produces less and enjoys more leisure so that the economy is no longer producing the optimal mix of products Moreover the sale does not occur so the government never collects the revenue that was the whole reason for the distortion This is the deadweight loss the government has not merely taken a cut of the benefits from the exchange it has destroyed those benefits for all three 7 These are the results optimal tax theorists seek to avoid Horizontal and vertical equity edit Another criterion for an optimal tax is that it should be equitable Equity in the context of taxation demands that the tax burden should be proportional to the taxpayer s ability to pay This criteria can be further broken down into horizontal equity imposing the same tax on two taxpayers with equal ability to pay and vertical equity imposing greater tax burdens on those with greater ability to pay Of course reasonable minds may differ as to whether two taxpayers in fact have equal ability to pay and on how quickly the tax burden should rise with ability to pay that is how progressive the tax code should be 8 Of the hundreds of provisions in the US tax code for example only a handful actually impose a tax 26 USC Sections 1 11 55 881 882 3301 and 3311 are the primary examples Instead most of those provisions help to define how much income a taxpayer has that is their ability to pay Even after the code has answered all the technical questions and determined a taxpayer s taxable income normative questions remain as to whether they have the same ability to pay For example the US tax code 26 U S C Section 1 a d imposes less tax on couples filing joint returns and on heads of households than it does on taxpayers that are single and provides a credit reducing the tax bills of those supporting children 26 U S C Section 24 This can be seen as an attempt at horizontal equity reflecting a judgement that taxpayers supporting families have less ability to pay than taxpayers with the same income but no dependents Vertical equity raises an additional normative question once we have agreed which taxpayers have the same ability to pay and which taxpayers have more how much more should those with greater ability to pay be made to contribute While that question has no definitive answer tax policy must balance competing goals such as revenue raising redistribution and efficiency However as with any tax implementing higher taxes will negatively affect incentives and alter an individual s behavior In his article Effects of Taxes on Economic Behavior Martin Feldstein discusses how economic behavior determined by taxes is important for estimating revenue calculating efficiency and understanding the negative externalities in the short run In his article like much of his research on this topic he chooses to focus primarily on how households are affected Feldstein recognizes that high taxes deter people from actively engaging in the market causing a lower production rate as well as a deadweight loss Yet because it is difficult to see tangible results of deadweight loss policy makers largely ignore it Feldstein expresses his frustration that policy makers have yet to grasp these concepts and therefore do not make policy that correct this wrong 9 The thrust of thinking among some economists is that taxes on consumption are always more efficient than taxes on income arguing that the latter have a greater disincentive effect One problem with this analysis is defining what constitutes consumption and what constitutes investment 4 Another problem is that the impact will vary from country to country depending on the design of the tax system and the relative levels of different tax rates A more nuanced empirical analysis is required to evaluate this issue For lower income working people who spend most of their income taxes on consumption also have a significant disincentive effect while higher income people may be motivated more by prestige and professional achievement than by after tax income Any gain in economic efficiency from shifting taxes to consumption may be quite small while the adverse effects on income distribution may be large 10 Lump sum taxes edit One type of tax that does not create a large excess burden is the lump sum tax A lump sum tax is a fixed tax that must be paid by everyone and the amount a person is taxed remains constant regardless of income or owned assets It does not create excess burden because these taxes do not alter economic decisions Because the tax remains constant an individual s incentives and a firm s incentives will not fluctuate as opposed to a graduated income tax that taxes people more for earning more Lump sum taxes can be either progressive or regressive depending on what the lump sum is being applied to A tax placed on car tags would be regressive because it would be the same for everyone regardless of the type of car the owner purchased and at least in the United States even the poor own cars People earning lower incomes would then pay more as a percentage of their income than higher income earners A tax on the unimproved aspects of land tends to be a progressive tax since the wealthier one is the more land one tends to own and the poor typically do not own any land at all Lump sum taxes are not politically expedient because they sometimes require a complete overhaul of the tax system Lump sum taxes are also unpopular when they are assessed per capita because they are regressive and make no allowance for a citizen s ability to pay A one off unexpected lump sum levy which is proportional to wealth or income is also non distorting In this case although wealth or income is penalised the unexpected nature of the tax means that there is no disincentive to asset accumulation as by definition those accumulating such assets are unaware that a portion of those assets will be taxed in the future Commodity taxes editFrank P Ramsey 1927 developed a theory for optimal commodity sales taxes in his article A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation The problem is closely linked to the problem of socially optimal monopolistic pricing when profits are constrained to be positive known as the Ramsey problem He was the first to make a significant contribution to the theory of optimal taxation from an economic standpoint and much of the literature that has followed reflects Ramsey s initial observations He wanted to confront the problem of how to adjust consumption tax rates under specified constraints so that the reduction of utility is at a minimum In an attempt to reduce excess burden of consumption taxes Ramsey proposed a theoretical solution that consumption tax on each good should be proportional to the sum of the reciprocals of its supply and demand elasticities 11 However practically it is problematic to constrain social planners to one form of taxation It is better to enable them to consider all possible tax structures 12 13 Using Ramsey s rule as a basis for their papers Peter Diamond and James Mirrlees propose an alternative to Ramsey s proposition by allowing the planner to consider numerous tax systems and their model has prevailed in taxation theories In their first paper Optimal Taxation and Public Production I Production Efficiency Diamond and Mirrlees consider the problem of imperfect information exchanged between taxpayers and the social planner 14 According to their argument an individual s ability to earn income differs Though the planner can observe income they cannot directly observe the individual s ability or effort to earn income so that if the planner attempts to increase taxes on those with high ability to earn an income the individual s incentives to earn a high income decrease They confront the government tradeoff between equality and efficiency that when higher taxes are imposed on those with the potential to earn higher wages they are not incentivized to expend the extra effort to earn a greater income They rely on what has been labeled the revelation principle where planners must implement a tax system that provides proper incentives for people to reveal their true wage earning abilities 14 They continued this idea in the second installment of their paper Optimal Taxation and Public Production II Tax Rules where they discuss marginal tax rate schedules for labor income 15 If the policy maker implemented a tax increase in the marginal tax rate at a lower income it discourages the individuals at that income from working hard However this same increase for high income individuals does not distort their incentives because though it raises their average tax rate their marginal tax rate remains the same For example giving 100 is worth more to a low income earner than to a high income earner Diamond and Mirrlees came to the conclusion that the marginal tax rate for the top earner should be equal to zero and the optimal rate must be between zero and one This provides the correct incentives for individuals to work at their optimal level 15 Developments in tax theory editWilliam J Baumol and David F Bradford in their article Optimal Departures from Marginal Cost Pricing also discuss the price distortion taxes cause 16 They examine the proposition that in order to reach the optimal point of allocating resources prices that deviate from marginal cost are required They recognize that with every tax there is some sort of price distortion so they state that any solution can only be the second best option and any solution proposed is under that added constraint However their theory differs from other literature in this topic First it deals with quasi optimal pricing looking at four options for Pareto optimality with adjusted commodity prices Second they express their theory in more simplified terms which incurs a loss of realistic application Third it combines the three discussions the welfare theory the contributions of the regulations and public finance They conclude that under constraints the best possible theory to get close to optimality which is not best at all is the systematic division between prices and marginal costs 16 In his article entitled Optimal Taxation in Theory Gregory Mankiw reviews that current literature in theories on optimal taxation and analyzes the change in the tax theory over the past few decades Like Diamond and Mirrlees Mankiw recognizes the flaw in Ramsey s model that planners can raise revenue through taxes only on commodities but also points out the weakness of Mirrlees s proposition Mankiw argues that Diamond s and Mirrlees s theory is extremely complex because of how difficult it is to keep track of individuals producing at their maximum levels 12 Mankiw provides a summary of eight lessons that represent the current thought in optimal taxation literature They include first the idea considering horizontal and vertical equity that social planners should base optimal tax schedules on income rates for labour which marks the equality and efficiency trade off Second the more income an individual makes their marginal tax schedule could actually decrease because they are discouraged from working at their optimal production level The solution is to after individuals reach a certain income level ensure that the marginal tax remains steady Third reaching an optimal tax level could mean flat taxes Fourth the increase in wage inequality is directly proportionate to the extent of income redistribution as revenue is distributed to low income earners Fifth taxes should not only depend on income amounts but also on personal characteristics such as a person s wage earning capabilities Sixth goods produced should only be taxed as a final good and should be taxed uniformly which leads to their seventh point that capital should also not be taxed because it is considered an input of production Finally policymakers should consider individuals income histories which require reliance on different types of taxation to derive optimal taxation Mankiw identifies that the tax policy has largely followed the theories laid out in tax literature because social planners believe that the flatter the tax the better there are declining top marginal rates in OECD countries and taxes on commodities are now uniform and usually only final goods are taxed 12 Joel Slemrod in his paper Optimal Taxation and Optimal Tax System argues that optimal tax theory as it stood when Slemrod wrote this paper was an insufficient guide to determine tax policies because policymakers had yet to find a way to implement a tax system that enticed individuals to work at their optimal level 17 As a solution Slemrod proposes the theory of optimal tax systems a phrase he uses to refer to the normative theory of taxation Slemrod advocates this theory because not only does it take into account the preferences of individuals but also the technology involved in tax collecting A practical application of this for example is implementing value added taxes a tax on the purchase price of a good or service to correct tax evasion He argues that any future tax literature in normative theory needs to focus less on consumer preferences and more on tax collecting technology and the areas of the economy that affect tax collection 17 Globalisation has also taken an important role in the development of taxes and tax systems As referred previously taxes have the purpose of fixing economic disparities among individuals and that assortment of living standards and income generates competitiveness especially among countries The globalisation process has created new rules for companies and citizens to move across borders and therefore the tax systems they shall oblige to Consequently countries compete with each other on the taxation programme offered to both singular individuals and corporations with the aim of becoming attractive to foreign agents and simultaneously breed tax revenues to fund the government s budget Regarding the government s budget and its strategy it can also be a factor of attractiveness Generally countries with higher tax levels have also a tax structure tax differs from other countries 18 which can be related to the share of the government s expenditure that is invested in the population For example Sweden has one of the highest tax revenues of GDP 19 but invests almost 16 of the government expenditure in education 20 According to an OECD report 18 multiple countries have been changing their tax policies being the normal procedure to cut the tax rate and broaden the tax base 21 which improves efficiency From the same report some situations were pointed out regarding the importance of the choice of tax policies such as the imposition of taxes on products and services and the way these are perceived when exported and the progressiveness of the taxes that can affect the inflow of economic agents especially high income ones Initially the last point was almost always directed to firms but nowadays more high skilled workers are concerned with the subject as opposed to low skilled workers that are less affected by globalisation since the tax bases are not so flexible 18 Some studies show that there is a positive correlation between globalisation and capital taxes but at the same time that governments decrease the corporate taxes because of the globalisation phenomenon 22 It may sound somewhat paradoxical but the change in the tax rates makes individuals more aware of the tariffs that are practised in other countries contributing then for the globalisation Income taxes editAnother aspect of optimal taxation is determining income taxes which can be regressive flat or progressive Labor income tax edit Main article Optimal labor income taxation The theory of optimal income tax on individual labor aims to find the optimal trade off between the following three effects of increasing taxation The mechanical effect an increase in tax rate increases the government revenue if no individuals changed their behaviour in response The behavioural effect an increase in tax rate discourages labour supply and this leads to lower tax revenue as a result The welfare effect an increase in tax rate reduces the individual utility and thus reduces social welfare Corporate income tax edit The examples and perspective in this section may not represent a worldwide view of the subject You may improve this section discuss the issue on the talk page or create a new section as appropriate December 2017 Learn how and when to remove this template message Arnold Harberger researched optimal taxation for corporations Corporation income taxes are based on corporate profits In the Journal of Political Economy Harberger wrote an article called The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax where he provided a theoretical framework to understand the effects of corporate income taxes and to determine the impact of such taxes in the United States 23 He proposed a general equilibrium model in which he analyzed a two sector economy one corporate and the other not In this model Harberger concluded that the market will move toward a long run equilibrium in which the after tax rate of return of all corporations would equalize compensating for any impact of corporate income taxes Thus taxing profits would lower the overall rate of return and therefore the level of investment and output in the economy Furthermore he claimed that this model could apply to a broader range of conditions 9 23 Martin Feldstein disputed Harberger s assumptions Feldstein argues that one of Harberger s shortcomings is that policy makers typically focused on the effects on personal income tax Feldstein argued that policy makers should analyze corporate and personal taxation separately He presented a method on how to reflect the net effect of the changes ro corporate tax rates on individual tax returns by focusing on the difference between real and nominal capital income Feldstein noted the shortcomings of his model because of the lack of data to properly compare the two 9 William Fox and LeAnn Luna proposed another theory in a joint article called State Corporate Tax Revenue Trends Causes and Possible Solutions in which they take on the role of this taxation They purport to determine the effects on revenue and propose some ways to reverse the trend They claim that because the effective corporate income tax rate fell by one third over two decades the effective tax rate decline was the result of a tax base that is eroding in relation to income and profits This was because legislation narrowed the tax base 24 One option to reduce the negative investment effect of corporate taxes on the level of private investment and hence increase investment is the provision of an investment tax credit or accelerated depreciation In these cases the effective rate becomes a negative function of the reinvestment rate In recent years the concept of a corporate tax system incorporating deductions for normal profits where normal is defined in relation to the long term interest rate and the risk premium has gained attention as a tax system that could minimise these distortions without reducing total tax revenue Such a taxation system would in effect levy a higher rate of tax on firms earning superprofits which will likely be unaffected even when taxed at a higher rate as the post tax return on capital is significantly higher than the threshold or normal level Conversely the effective tax rate on marginal projects with returns closer to the normal level will be reduced One example of such a tax system is Australia s Minerals Resource Rent Tax When an investment tax credit or equity based deduction is applied the optimal effective rate of taxation is generally increased as the distortionary effect of a given level of taxation is diminished If the unadjusted tax rate was optimal the assumption is that the net marginal benefit of increased taxation is zero near the optimum rate the marginal costs and benefits sum to zero If the distortionary costs of capital taxation are then lowered by deductions or credits then the net benefit of rate increases will become positive implying the tax rate should be raised Sales tax edit A third consideration for optimal taxation is sales tax which is the additional price added to the base price of a paid by the consumer at the point when they purchase a good or service Poterba in a second article called Retail Price Reactions To Changes in State and Local Sales Taxes tests the premise that sales taxes on the state and local level are fully shifted to the consumers 25 He examines clothing prices before and after World War II He recognizes that monetary policy is important to determine the response of nominal prices under a national sales tax and points to possible differences in taxes applied at the local level as to taxes applied at a national level Poterba finds evidence reinforcing the idea that sales taxes are fully forward shifted which raises the consumer prices to match the tax increase His study coincides with the original hypothesis that retail sales taxes are fully shifted to retail prices 25 Donald Bruce William Fox and M H Tuttle also discuss tax revenues through sales tax in their article Tax Base Elasticities A Multi State Analysis of Long Run and Short Run Dynamics 26 In this article they look at how personal state revenues and sales tax bases elasticities change for the short and long term in an attempt to determine the difference between them With this information the authors believe that states can both enhance and customize their tax structures which can be used for careful resource planning They found that for state personal income tax bases as compared to sales taxes the average long term income elasticity is more than doubled and the short term display disproportionate results higher than the long term elasticities The authors contend with the conventional literature by declaring that neither the personal income tax nor the sales tax is at least universally the more volatile tax Though the authors concede that in certain situations the sales tax is more volatile and in the long term personal income taxes are more elastic 26 Furthermore in understanding this argument it must also be considered as Alan Auerbach Jagadeesh Gokhale and Laurence Kotlikoff do in Generational Accounting A Meaningful Way to Evaluate Fiscal Policy what the implications to optimal taxation are for future generations 27 They propose that generational accounting represents a new method for fiscal planning in the long run and that unlike the budget deficit this generational accounting is not arbitrary Instead it is a remedy for how to approach the generation burden and effects of fiscal policy on a macroeconomic level Ethically it is a problem to have low taxes now and therefore low revenue now because it inevitably puts the burden of responsibility to pay for those expenditures on future generations So through generational accounting it is possible to analyze this and provide the necessary information for policy makers to change the policies needed to alter this trend However according to Auerbach politicians are currently only relying on accounting and are not seeing the potential consequences that will ensue in future generations 27 The incidence of sales taxes on commodities also results in distortion if say food prepared in restaurants is taxed but supermarket bought food prepared at home is not taxed at purchase If a taxpayer needs to buy food at fast food restaurants because he she is not wealthy enough to purchase extra leisure time by working less he she pays the tax although a more prosperous person who enjoys playing at being a home chef is taxed more lightly This differential taxation of commodities may cause inefficiency by discouraging work in the market in favor of work in the household Capital income tax edit Main article Optimal capital income taxation The theory of optimal capital income tax considers the capital income as future consumption Thus the taxation of capital income corresponds to a differentiated consumption tax on present and future consumption and results in the distortion of individuals saving and consumption behavior as individuals substitute the more heavily taxed future consumption with current consumption Due to these distortions zero taxation of capital income might be optimal a result postulated by the Atkinson Stiglitz theorem 1976 and the Chamley Judd zero capital income tax result 1985 1986 In contrast subsequent work on optimal capital income taxation has elucidated the assumptions underlying the theoretical optimality of a zero capital income tax and advanced diverse arguments for a positive or negative optimal capital tax Capital taxes editTaxation of wealth or capital i e stocks assets should not be confused with taxation of capital income or income from wealth i e transfers flows Taxation of capital in any form above all financial instruments assets then property was proposed as most optimal by Thomas Piketty 28 His proposition consist of progressive taxation of capital up to 5 yearly Gregory Papanikos showed that even proportional taxation of capital may be considered as optimal 29 Land value taxation edit One of the early propositions on taxing capital according to the broader neoclassical definition of capital was to capture the full rental value of land Political economist and social reformer Henry George most notably championed the idea of a land value tax in Progress and Poverty as a levy on the value of unimproved or natural aspects of the land primarily location it disregards the improvements such as buildings and irrigation 30 Land value taxation has no deadweight loss because the input of production being taxed land is fixed in supply it cannot hide shrink in value or flee to other jurisdictions when taxed Economic theory suggests that a pure land value tax which succeeds in avoiding taxation of improvements could actually have a negative deadweight loss positive externality due to productivity gains arising from efficient land use 31 32 The taxation of locational values encourages socially optimal development on land in highly valued areas like cities since it reduces the incentive to speculate in land prices by leaving potentially productive locations vacant or underused 33 Despite its theoretical benefits implementing land value taxes is difficult politically However land value tax is considered progressive because the ownership of land values is more concentrated than other sources of revenue such as personal income or spending 34 George argued that because land is the fruit of nature not labor and the value of location is created by the community the revenue from land should belong to the community 35 See also editAd valorem tax Excess burden of taxation Hall Rabushka flat tax Land value tax Optimum tariff Pigovian tax Progressive tax Proportional tax Single tax Taxable income elasticity Tax equity Tax incidence Tax reform Tax shiftNotes edit Mankiw N Gregory Weinzierl Matthew Yagan Danny 2009 Optimal Taxation in Theory and Practice Journal of Economic Perspectives 23 4 147 174 doi 10 1257 jep 23 4 147 Keane Michael P December 2011 Labor Supply and Taxes A Survey PDF Journal of Economic Literature 49 4 961 1075 doi 10 1257 jel 49 4 961 ISSN 0022 0515 Archived from the original PDF on 2020 04 13 Retrieved 2019 12 14 Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas J Sargent 2000 Recursive Macroeconomic Theory 2nd ed MIT Press ISBN 0 262 19451 1 p 444 a b Simkovic Michael 23 February 2015 Distortionary Taxation of Human Capital Acquisition Costs Social Science Research Network SSRN 2551567 Mirrlees James Adam Stuart Tax by design the Mirrlees review pp 31 32 ISBN 9780191617591 OCLC 761694695 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a work ignored help Smith Adam 2015 The Wealth of Nations A Translation into Modern English Industrial Systems Research p 429 ISBN 9780906321706 a b Bruce Donald John Deskins William Fox 2005 Auerbach Alan ed On the Extent Growth and Consequences of State Business Tax Planning Corporate Income Taxation in the 21st Century Cambridge University Press Holcombe Randall 2006 Public Sector Economics The Role of Government in the American Economy New Jersey Pearson a b c Feldstein Martin 2008 Effects of Taxes on Economic Behavior PDF NBER 13745 Rhys Kesselman Jonathan Spiro Peter S 2014 Challenges in Shifting Canadian Taxation Toward Consumption Canadian Tax Journal 62 1 1 39 SSRN 2372735 Ramsey Frank 1927 A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation Economic Journal 37 145 47 61 doi 10 2307 2222721 JSTOR 2222721 a b c Mankiw Gregory Matthew Weinzierl Danny Yagan 2009 Optimal Taxation in Theory NBER 15071 Sanchirico Chris 2011 Working paper posted 2009 Tax Eclecticism Tax Law Review 64 149 228 SSRN 1491130 a b Mirrlees James Peter Diamond 1971 Optimal Taxation and Public Production I Production Efficiency American Economic Review 61 8 27 a b Mirrlees James Peter Diamond 1971 Optimal Taxation and Public Production II Tax Rules American Economic Review 61 261 278 a b Baumol William David Bradford 1970 Optimal Departures from Marginal Cost Pricing The American Economic Review 60 265 283 a b Slemrod Joel July 1989 Optimal Taxation and Optimal Tax Systems NBER doi 10 3386 w3038 a b c OECD 2010 Tax Policy Reform and Economic Growth OECD Tax Policy Studies 20 doi 10 1787 9789264091085 en ISBN 9789264091078 Tax revenue of GDP The World Bank Data The World Bank Government expenditure on education total of government expenditure The World Bank Data The World Bank Base Broadening Definition TaxEDU Tax Foundation Lucas Bretschger Frank Hettich 2002 Globalisation capital mobility and tax competition theory and evidence for OECD countries European Journal of Political Economy 18 4 695 716 doi 10 1016 S0176 2680 02 00115 5 hdl 10419 48898 a b Harberger Arthur 1962 The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax Journal of Political Economy 70 3 215 240 doi 10 1086 258636 S2CID 154336077 Fox William LeAnn Luna 2002 State Corporate Tax Revenue Trends Causes and Possible Solutions National Tax Journal 55 3 491 508 doi 10 17310 ntj 2002 3 07 S2CID 55018225 a b Poterba James 1996 Retail Price Reactions to Changes in State and Local Sales Taxes National Tax Journal 79 49 165 176 doi 10 1086 NTJ41789195 S2CID 154762393 a b Bruce Donald William Fox M H Tuttle 2006 Tax Base Elasticities A Multi State Analysis of Long Run and Short Run Dynamics Southern Economic Journal 73 2 315 341 doi 10 2307 20111894 JSTOR 20111894 a b Auerbach Alan Jagadeesh Gokhale Laurence Kotlkoff 1999 Generational Accounting A Meaningful Way to Evaluate Fiscal Policy Journal of Economic Perspectives 8 73 94 doi 10 1257 jep 8 1 73 Capital in the Twenty First Century Cambridge MA Belknap Press 2014 Papanikos Gregory 2015 Taxing Wealth and Only Wealth in an Advanced Economy with an Oversized Informal Economy and Vast Tax Evasion The Case of Greece PDF Vierteljahrshefte zur Wirtschaftsforschung 84 3 83 106 doi 10 3790 vjh 84 3 85 hdl 10419 150061 George Henry 1879 Progress and Poverty New York Page amp Co Tideman Nicolaus 1995 Taxing Land is Better Than Neutral Land Taxes Land Speculation and the Timing of Development Lincoln Institute of Land Policy Retrieved 17 June 2014 Mattauch Linus Siegmeier Jan Edenhofer Ottmar Creutzig Felix 2013 Financing Public Capital through Land Rent Taxation A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem CESifo Working Paper No 4280 Plassmann Florenz 24 June 1997 The Impact of Two Rate Taxes on Construction in Pennsylvania hdl 10919 30622 Retrieved 22 September 2020 Gaffney Mason 1971 The property tax is a progressive tax PDF masongaffney org Resources for the Future Inc Reprinted from the Proceedings of the Sixty Fourth Annual Conference on Taxation sponsored by the National Tax Association Archived from the original PDF on 15 March 2012 Retrieved 7 October 2013 Levying the land The Economist June 29 2013 Retrieved 3 October 2013 References editMayshar J 1990 Measures of Excess Burden Journal of Public Economics 43 3 263 289 doi 10 1016 0047 2727 90 90001 x Ramsey F P 1927 A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation The Economic Journal 37 145 47 61 doi 10 2307 2222721 JSTOR 2222721 J Slemrod and S Yitzhaki 1996 The costs of taxation and the marginal efficiency cost of funds International Monetary Fund Staff Papers March 1996 43 1 N H Stern 1987 Optimal taxation The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics v 1 pp 865 67 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Optimal tax amp oldid 1183617745, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.