fbpx
Wikipedia

Excludability

In economics, a good, service or resource are broadly assigned two fundamental characteristics; a degree of excludability and a degree of rivalry. Excludability is defined as the degree to which a good, service or resource can be limited to only paying customers, or conversely, the degree to which a supplier, producer or other managing body (e.g. a government) can prevent "free" consumption of a good.

Air, whether it is clean or polluted, cannot exclude anyone from its use, and so it is considered a non-excludable "good". A good can be non-excludable regardless of how desirable it could be to be excluded from consuming it (such as smog or pollution in a city).

Excludability was originally proposed in 1954 by American economist Paul Samuelson where he formalised the concept now known as public goods, i.e. goods that are both non-rivalrous and non-excludable.[1] Samuelson additionally highlighted the market failure of the free-rider problem that can occur with non-excludable goods. Samuelson's theory of good classification was then further expanded upon by Richard Musgrave in 1959, Garrett Hardin in 1968 who expanded upon another key market inefficiency of non-excludeable goods; the tragedy of the commons.[2]

Excludability is not an inherent characteristic of a good. Therefore, excludability was further expanded upon by Elinor Ostrom in 1990 to be a continuous characteristic, as opposed to the discrete characteristic proposed by Samuelson (who presented excludability as either being present or absent).[1] Ostrom's theory proposed that excludability can be placed on a scale that would range from fully excludable (i.e. a good that could theoretically fully exclude non-paying consumers) to fully non-excludeable (a good that cannot exclude non-paying customers at all).[3] This scale allows producers and providers more in-depth information that can then be used to generate more efficient price equations (for public goods in particular), that would then maximize benefits and positive externalities for all consumers of the good[4]

Definition matrix edit

Examples edit

Excludable edit

 
Public transit (bus) farebox, Vancouver

The easiest characteristic of an excludable good is that the producer, supplier or managing body of the good, service or resource have been able to restrict consumption to only paying consumers, and excluded non-paying consumers. If a good has a price attached to it, whether it's a one time payment like in the case of clothing or cars, or an ongoing payment like a subscription fee for a magazine or a per-use fee like in the case of public transport, it can be considered to be excludable to some extent.

A common example is a movie in a cinema. Paying customers are given a ticket that would entitle them to a single showing of the movie, and this is checked and ensured by ushers, security and other employees of the cinema. This means that a viewing of the movie is excludable and non-paying consumers are unable to experience the movie.

Semi-Excludable edit

Ranging between being fully excludable and non-excludable is a continuous scale of excludability that Ostrom developed.[3] Within this scale are goods that either attempt to be excludable but cannot effective or efficiently enforce this excludability. One example concerns many forms of information such as music, movies, e-books and computer software. All of these goods have some price or payment involved in their consumption, but are also susceptible to piracy and copyright infringements. This can result in many non-paying consumers being able to experience and benefit from the goods of a single purchase or payment.

Non-Excludable edit

A good, service or resource that is unable to prevent or exclude non-paying consumers from experiencing or using it can be considered non-excludable. An architecturally pleasing building, such as Tower Bridge, creates an aesthetic non-excludable good, which can be enjoyed by anyone who happens to look at it. It is difficult to prevent people from gaining this benefit. A lighthouse acts as a navigation aid to ships at sea in a manner that is non-excludable since any ship out at sea can benefit from it.

Implications and inefficiency edit

Public goods will generally be underproduced and undersupplied in the absence of government subsidies, relative to a socially optimal level. This is because potential producers will not be able to realize a profit (since the good can be obtained for free) sufficient to justify the costs of production. In this way the provision of non-excludable goods is a classic example of a positive externality which leads to inefficiency. In extreme cases this can result in the good not being produced at all, or it being necessary for the government to organize its production and distribution.

A classic example of the inefficiency caused by non-excludability is the tragedy of the commons (which Hardin, the author, later corrected to the 'tragedy of the unmanaged commons' because it is based on the notion of an entirely rule-less resource) where a shared, non-excludable, resource becomes subject to over-use and over-consumption, which destroys the resource in the process.

Economic theory edit

Brito and Oakland (1980) study the private, profit-maximizing provision of excludable public goods in a formal economic model.[5] They take into account that the agents have private information about their valuations of the public good. Yet, Brito and Oakland only consider posted-price mechanisms, i.e. there are ad-hoc constraints on the class of contracts. Also taking distribution costs and congestion effects into account, Schmitz (1997) studies a related problem, but he allows for general mechanisms.[6] Moreover, he also characterizes the second-best allocation rule, which is welfare-maximizing under the constraint of nonnegative profits. Using the incomplete contracts theory, Francesconi and Muthoo (2011) explore whether public or private ownership is more desirable when non-contractible investments have to be made in order to provide a (partly) excludable public good.[7]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b Samuelson, Paul (Nov 1954). "The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 36 (4): 387–389. doi:10.2307/1925895. JSTOR 1925895.
  2. ^ Hardin, Garrett (1968-12-13). "The Tragedy of the Commons". Science. 162 (3859): 1243–1248. Bibcode:1968Sci...162.1243H. doi:10.1126/science.162.3859.1243. ISSN 0036-8075. PMID 5699198.
  3. ^ a b Ostrom, Elinor (2010-06-01). "Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems". American Economic Review. 100 (3): 641–672. doi:10.1257/aer.100.3.641. ISSN 0002-8282. S2CID 2371158.
  4. ^ Blomquist, Sören; Christiansen, Vidar (2005-01-01). "The Role of Prices for Excludable Public Goods". International Tax and Public Finance. 12 (1): 61–79. doi:10.1007/s10797-005-6395-z. ISSN 1573-6970. S2CID 16804457.
  5. ^ Brito, Dagobert L.; Oakland, William H. (1980). "On the Monopolistic Provision of Excludable Public Goods". The American Economic Review. 70 (4): 691–704. JSTOR 1803565.
  6. ^ Schmitz, Patrick W. (1997). "Monopolistic Provision of Excludable Public Goods under Private Information". Public Finance. 52 (1): 89–101.
  7. ^ Francesconi, Marco; Muthoo, Abhinay (2011). "Control Rights in Complex Partnerships" (PDF). Journal of the European Economic Association. 9 (3): 551–589. doi:10.1111/j.1542-4774.2011.01017.x. ISSN 1542-4766.

Further reading edit

excludability, this, article, needs, additional, citations, verification, please, help, improve, this, article, adding, citations, reliable, sources, unsourced, material, challenged, removed, find, sources, news, newspapers, books, scholar, jstor, june, 2018, . This article needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Excludability news newspapers books scholar JSTOR June 2018 Learn how and when to remove this template message In economics a good service or resource are broadly assigned two fundamental characteristics a degree of excludability and a degree of rivalry Excludability is defined as the degree to which a good service or resource can be limited to only paying customers or conversely the degree to which a supplier producer or other managing body e g a government can prevent free consumption of a good Air whether it is clean or polluted cannot exclude anyone from its use and so it is considered a non excludable good A good can be non excludable regardless of how desirable it could be to be excluded from consuming it such as smog or pollution in a city Excludability was originally proposed in 1954 by American economist Paul Samuelson where he formalised the concept now known as public goods i e goods that are both non rivalrous and non excludable 1 Samuelson additionally highlighted the market failure of the free rider problem that can occur with non excludable goods Samuelson s theory of good classification was then further expanded upon by Richard Musgrave in 1959 Garrett Hardin in 1968 who expanded upon another key market inefficiency of non excludeable goods the tragedy of the commons 2 Excludability is not an inherent characteristic of a good Therefore excludability was further expanded upon by Elinor Ostrom in 1990 to be a continuous characteristic as opposed to the discrete characteristic proposed by Samuelson who presented excludability as either being present or absent 1 Ostrom s theory proposed that excludability can be placed on a scale that would range from fully excludable i e a good that could theoretically fully exclude non paying consumers to fully non excludeable a good that cannot exclude non paying customers at all 3 This scale allows producers and providers more in depth information that can then be used to generate more efficient price equations for public goods in particular that would then maximize benefits and positive externalities for all consumers of the good 4 Contents 1 Definition matrix 2 Examples 2 1 Excludable 2 2 Semi Excludable 2 3 Non Excludable 3 Implications and inefficiency 4 Economic theory 5 See also 6 References 7 Further readingDefinition matrix editMain article Goods Goods classified by exclusivity and competitivenessExamples editExcludable edit nbsp Public transit bus farebox VancouverThe easiest characteristic of an excludable good is that the producer supplier or managing body of the good service or resource have been able to restrict consumption to only paying consumers and excluded non paying consumers If a good has a price attached to it whether it s a one time payment like in the case of clothing or cars or an ongoing payment like a subscription fee for a magazine or a per use fee like in the case of public transport it can be considered to be excludable to some extent A common example is a movie in a cinema Paying customers are given a ticket that would entitle them to a single showing of the movie and this is checked and ensured by ushers security and other employees of the cinema This means that a viewing of the movie is excludable and non paying consumers are unable to experience the movie Semi Excludable edit Ranging between being fully excludable and non excludable is a continuous scale of excludability that Ostrom developed 3 Within this scale are goods that either attempt to be excludable but cannot effective or efficiently enforce this excludability One example concerns many forms of information such as music movies e books and computer software All of these goods have some price or payment involved in their consumption but are also susceptible to piracy and copyright infringements This can result in many non paying consumers being able to experience and benefit from the goods of a single purchase or payment Non Excludable edit A good service or resource that is unable to prevent or exclude non paying consumers from experiencing or using it can be considered non excludable An architecturally pleasing building such as Tower Bridge creates an aesthetic non excludable good which can be enjoyed by anyone who happens to look at it It is difficult to prevent people from gaining this benefit A lighthouse acts as a navigation aid to ships at sea in a manner that is non excludable since any ship out at sea can benefit from it Implications and inefficiency editPublic goods will generally be underproduced and undersupplied in the absence of government subsidies relative to a socially optimal level This is because potential producers will not be able to realize a profit since the good can be obtained for free sufficient to justify the costs of production In this way the provision of non excludable goods is a classic example of a positive externality which leads to inefficiency In extreme cases this can result in the good not being produced at all or it being necessary for the government to organize its production and distribution A classic example of the inefficiency caused by non excludability is the tragedy of the commons which Hardin the author later corrected to the tragedy of the unmanaged commons because it is based on the notion of an entirely rule less resource where a shared non excludable resource becomes subject to over use and over consumption which destroys the resource in the process Economic theory editBrito and Oakland 1980 study the private profit maximizing provision of excludable public goods in a formal economic model 5 They take into account that the agents have private information about their valuations of the public good Yet Brito and Oakland only consider posted price mechanisms i e there are ad hoc constraints on the class of contracts Also taking distribution costs and congestion effects into account Schmitz 1997 studies a related problem but he allows for general mechanisms 6 Moreover he also characterizes the second best allocation rule which is welfare maximizing under the constraint of nonnegative profits Using the incomplete contracts theory Francesconi and Muthoo 2011 explore whether public or private ownership is more desirable when non contractible investments have to be made in order to provide a partly excludable public good 7 See also editRivalry Free rider problem Tragedy of the CommonsReferences edit a b Samuelson Paul Nov 1954 The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure The Review of Economics and Statistics 36 4 387 389 doi 10 2307 1925895 JSTOR 1925895 Hardin Garrett 1968 12 13 The Tragedy of the Commons Science 162 3859 1243 1248 Bibcode 1968Sci 162 1243H doi 10 1126 science 162 3859 1243 ISSN 0036 8075 PMID 5699198 a b Ostrom Elinor 2010 06 01 Beyond Markets and States Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems American Economic Review 100 3 641 672 doi 10 1257 aer 100 3 641 ISSN 0002 8282 S2CID 2371158 Blomquist Soren Christiansen Vidar 2005 01 01 The Role of Prices for Excludable Public Goods International Tax and Public Finance 12 1 61 79 doi 10 1007 s10797 005 6395 z ISSN 1573 6970 S2CID 16804457 Brito Dagobert L Oakland William H 1980 On the Monopolistic Provision of Excludable Public Goods The American Economic Review 70 4 691 704 JSTOR 1803565 Schmitz Patrick W 1997 Monopolistic Provision of Excludable Public Goods under Private Information Public Finance 52 1 89 101 Francesconi Marco Muthoo Abhinay 2011 Control Rights in Complex Partnerships PDF Journal of the European Economic Association 9 3 551 589 doi 10 1111 j 1542 4774 2011 01017 x ISSN 1542 4766 Further reading editExcludability in Joseph E Stiglitz Knowledge as a Global Public Good World Bank Last accessed 29 May 2007 Copy at the Internet Archive Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Excludability amp oldid 1179949350, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.