fbpx
Wikipedia

Multiwinner voting

Multiwinner voting,[1] also called multiple-winner elections[2] or committee voting[3] or committee elections,[4] is an electoral system in which multiple candidates are elected. The number of elected candidates is usually fixed in advance. For example, it can be the number of seats in a country's parliament, or the required number of members in a committee.

There are many scenarios in which multiwinner voting is useful. They can be broadly classified into three classes, based on the main objective in electing the committee:[5]

  1. Excellence. Here, each voter is an expert, and each vote expresses his/her opinion about which candidate/s is "better" for a certain task. The goal is to find the "best" candidates. An example application is shortlisting: selecting, from a list of candidate employees, a small set of finalists, who will proceed to the final stage of evaluation (e.g. using an interview). Here, each candidate is evaluated independently of the other candidates. If two candidates are similar, then probably both will be elected (if they are both good), or both will be rejected (if both are bad).
  2. Diversity. Here, the elected candidates should be as different as possible. For example, suppose the candidates are possible locations for constructing a facility, such as a fire station. Most citizens naturally prefer a fire station in the city center. However, there is no need to have two fire-stations in the same place; it is better to diversify the selection and put the second station in a more remote location. In contrast to the "excellence" setting, if two candidates are similar, then probably exactly one of them will be elected. Another scenario in which diversity is important is when a search engine selects results for display, or when an airline selects movies for screening during a flight.
  3. Proportionality. Here, the elected candidates should represent in scientifically-balanced way the diverse opinion held by the population of voters, measured by the votes they cast, as much as possible. This is a common goal in parliamentary elections; see proportional representation.

Basic concepts edit

A major challenge in the study of multiwinner voting is finding reasonable adaptations of concepts from single-winner voting. These can be classified based on the voting type - approval voting vs. ranked voting.

Some election systems elect multiple members by competition held among individual candidates. Such systems are some variations of Multiple non-transferable voting and Single transferable voting.

In other systems, candidates are grouped in committees (slates) and voters cast votes for the committees (or slates). These committee-based systems are described here:

Approval voting for committees edit

Approval voting is a common method for single-winner elections and sometimes for multiwinner elections. In single-winner elections, each voter marks the candidate he approves, and the candidate with the most votes wins.

With multiwinner voting, there are many ways to decide which candidate should be elected. In some, each voter ranks the candidates; in others they cast X votes. As well, each voter may cast single or multiple votes.

Already in 1895, Thiele suggested a family of weight-based rules.[3][6] Each rule in the family is defined by a sequence of k weakly-positive weights, w1,...,wk (where k is the committee size). Each voter assigns, to each committee containing p candidates approved by the voter, a score equal to w1+...+wp. The committee with the highest total score is elected. Some common voting rules in Thiele's family are:

  • Multiple non-transferable vote (MNTV): the weight vector is (1,1,...,1). It is also called plurality-at-large approval-voting.
  • Approval-Chamberlin-Courant (ACC): the weight vector is (1,0,...,0). That is, each voter gives 1 point to a committee, iff it contains one of his approved candidates.
  • Proportional approval voting (PAV): the weight vector is the Harmonic progression (1, 1/2, 1/3, ...., 1/k).

There are rules based on other principles, such as minimax approval voting[7] and its generalizations,[8] Phragmen's voting rules.[9] and the Method of Equal Shares.[10][11]

Computing the winner with SNTV can be done in polynomial time, but with ACC it is NP-hard,[12] as well as with PAV.

Positional scoring rules for committees edit

Positional scoring rules are common in rank-based single-winner voting. Each voter ranks the candidates from best to worst, a pre-specified function assigns a score to each candidate based on his rank, and the candidate with the highest total score is elected.

In multiwinner voting held using these systems, we need to assign scores to committees rather than to individual candidates. There are various ways to do this, for example:[1]

  • Single non-transferable vote: each voter gives 1 point to a committee, if it contains his most preferred candidate. In other words: each voter votes for a single candidate in a contest that elects multiwinners, and the k candidates with the largest number of votes are elected. This generalizes First-past-the-post voting. It can be computed in polynomial time.
  • Multiple non-transferable vote (also called bloc voting): each voter gives 1 point to a committee for each open seat in his top k. In other words: each voter votes for k candidates where k seats are open, and the k candidates with the largest number of votes are elected.
  • k-Borda: each voter gives, to each committee member, his Borda count. Each voter ranks the candidates and the rankings are scored together. The k candidates with the highest total Borda score are elected.
  • Borda-Chamberlin-Courant (BCC): each voter gives, to each committee, the Borda count of his most preferred candidate in the committee.[13] Computing the winner with BCC is NP-hard.[12]

Condorcet committees edit

In single-winner voting, a Condorcet winner is a candidate who wins in every head-to-head election against each of the other candidates. A Condorcet method is a method that selects a Condorcet winner whenever it exists. There are several ways to adapt Condorcet's criterion to multiwinner voting:

  • The first adaptation was by Peter Fishburn:[14][15] a committee is a Condorcet committee iff it is preferred, by a majority of voters, to any other possible committee. Fishburn assumed that the voters rank committees by the number of members in their approval set (i.e., they have dichotomous preferences). Later works assumed that the voters rank committees by other criteria, such as by their Borda count. It is coNP-complete to check if a committee satisfies this criterion, and coNP-hard to decide if there exist a Condorcet committee.[16]
  • Another adaptation was by Gehrlein[17] and Ratliff:[18] a committee is a Condorcet set iff each candidate in it is preferred, by a majority of voters, to each candidate outside it. A multiwinner voting rule is sometimes called stable iff it selects a Condorcet set whenever it exists.[19] Some stable rules are:[20]
    • Multiwinner Copeland's method: each committee is scored by the "number of external defeats": the number of pairs (c,d) where c is in the committee, d is not, and c is preferred to d by a majority of the voters.
    • Multiwinner Minimax Condorcet method: each committee is scored by the "size of external opposition": the minimum, over all pairs (c,d), of the number of voters who prefer c.
    • Multiwinner variants of some other Condorcet rules.[21]
  • A third adaptation was by Elkind, Lang and Saffidine:[22] a Condorcet winning set is a set that, for each member d not in the set, some member c in the set is preferred to d by a majority. Based on this definition, they present a different multiwinner variant of the Minimax Condorcet method.

Other criteria edit

Computing Pareto-efficient committees is NP-hard in general.[23]

Excellence elections edit

Excellence means that the committee should contain the "best" candidates. Excellence-based voting rules are often called screening rules.[19] They are often used as a first step in a selection of a single best candidate, that is, a method for creating a shortlist. A basic property that should be satisfied by such a rule is committee monotonicity (also called house monotonicity, a variant of resource monotonicity): if some k candidates are elected by a rule, and then the committee size increases to k+1 and the rule is re-applied, then the first k candidates should still be elected. Some families of committee-monotone rules are:

  • Sequential rules:[19] using any single-winner voting rule, pick a single candidate and add it to the committee. Repeat the process k times.
  • Best-k rules:[1] using any scoring rule, assign a score to each candidate. Pick the k candidates with the highest scores.

The property of committee monotonicity is incompatible with the property of stability (a particular adaptation of Condorcet's criterion): there exists a single voting profile that admits a unique Condorcet set of size 2, and a unique Condorcet set of size 3, and they are disjoint (the set of size 2 is not contained in the set of size 3).[19]

On the other hand, there exists a family of positional scoring rules - the separable positional scoring rules - that are committee-monotone. These rules are also computable in polynomial time (if their underlying single-winner scoring functions are).[1] For example, k-Borda is separable while Multiple non-transferable vote is not.

Diversity elections edit

Diversity means that the committee should contain the top-ranked candidates of as many voters as possible. Formally, the following axioms are reasonable for diversity-centered applications:

  • Narrow-top criterion:[1] if there exists a committee of size k containing the top-ranked candidate of every voter, then it should be elected.
  • Top-member monotonicity:[24] if a committee is elected, and some voter shifts upwards the rank of his most-preferred winner, then the same committee should be elected.

Proportional elections edit

Proportionality means that each cohesive group of voters (that is: a group of voters with similar preferences) should be represented by a number of winners proportional to its size. Formally, if the committee is of size k, there are n voters, and some L*n/k voters rank the same L candidates at the top (or approve the same L candidates), then these L candidates should be elected. This principle is easy to implement when the voters vote for parties (in party-list systems), but it can also be adapted to approval voting or ranked voting; see justified representation.

Further reading edit

  • Finding a Collective Set of Items: From Proportional Multirepresentation to Group Recommendation.[25]
  • Budgeted Social Choice: From Consensus to Personalized Decision Making.[26]
  • Achieving fully proportional representation: Approximability results.[27]

See also edit

  • Participatory budgeting - can be seen as an extension of multiwinner voting in which each candidate has a "cost". In multiwinner voting, the price of each candidate is 1, and the budget is k.

References edit

  1. ^ a b c d e Elkind, Edith; Faliszewski, Piotr; Skowron, Piotr; Slinko, Arkadii (2017-03-01). "Properties of multiwinner voting rules". Social Choice and Welfare. 48 (3): 599–632. doi:10.1007/s00355-017-1026-z. ISSN 1432-217X. PMC 7089675. PMID 32226187.
  2. ^ "RangeVoting.org - Glossary". rangevoting.org. Retrieved 2021-06-25.
  3. ^ a b Aziz, Haris; Brill, Markus; Conitzer, Vincent; Elkind, Edith; Freeman, Rupert; Walsh, Toby (2017). "Justified representation in approval-based committee voting". Social Choice and Welfare. 48 (2): 461–485. doi:10.1007/s00355-016-1019-3. S2CID 8564247.
  4. ^ Bock, Hans-Hermann; Day, William H.E.; McMorris, F.R. (1998-05-01). "Consensus rules for committee elections". Mathematical Social Sciences. 35 (3): 219–232. doi:10.1016/S0165-4896(97)00033-4. ISSN 0165-4896.
  5. ^ Piotr Faliszewski, Piotr Skowron, Arkadii Slinko, Nimrod Talmon (2017-10-26). "Multiwinner Voting: A New Challenge for Social Choice Theory". In Endriss, Ulle (ed.). Trends in Computational Social Choice. Lulu.com. ISBN 978-1-326-91209-3.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  6. ^ Sánchez-Fernández, Luis; Elkind, Edith; Lackner, Martin; Fernández, Norberto; Fisteus, Jesús; Val, Pablo Basanta; Skowron, Piotr (2017-02-10). "Proportional Justified Representation". Proceedings of the AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence. 31 (1). doi:10.1609/aaai.v31i1.10611. hdl:10016/26166. ISSN 2374-3468. S2CID 17538641.
  7. ^ Brams, Steven J.; Kilgour, D. Marc; Sanver, M. Remzi (2007-09-01). "A minimax procedure for electing committees". Public Choice. 132 (3): 401–420. doi:10.1007/s11127-007-9165-x. ISSN 1573-7101. S2CID 46632580.
  8. ^ Amanatidis, Georgios; Barrot, Nathanaël; Lang, Jérôme; Markakis, Evangelos; Ries, Bernard (2015-05-04). "Multiple Referenda and Multiwinner Elections Using Hamming Distances: Complexity and Manipulability". Proceedings of the 2015 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems. AAMAS '15. Istanbul, Turkey: International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems: 715–723. ISBN 978-1-4503-3413-6.
  9. ^ Brill, Markus; Freeman, Rupert; Janson, Svante; Lackner, Martin (2017-02-10). "Phragmén's Voting Methods and Justified Representation". Proceedings of the AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence. 31 (1). doi:10.1609/aaai.v31i1.10598. ISSN 2374-3468. S2CID 2290202.
  10. ^ Peters, Dominik; Skowron, Piotr (2020). "Proportionality and the Limits of Welfarism". Proceedings of the 21st ACM Conference on Economics and Computation. EC'20. pp. 793–794. arXiv:1911.11747. doi:10.1145/3391403.3399465. ISBN 9781450379755. S2CID 208291203.
  11. ^ Pierczyński, Grzegorz; Peters, Dominik; Skowron, Piotr (2020). "Proportional Participatory Budgeting with Additive Utilities". Proceedings of the 2021 Conference on Neural Information Processing Systems. NeurIPS'21. arXiv:2008.13276.
  12. ^ a b Procaccia, Ariel D.; Rosenschein, Jeffrey S.; Zohar, Aviv (2007-04-19). "On the complexity of achieving proportional representation". Social Choice and Welfare. 30 (3): 353–362. doi:10.1007/s00355-007-0235-2. S2CID 18126521.
  13. ^ Chamberlin, John R.; Courant, Paul N. (1983). "Representative Deliberations and Representative Decisions: Proportional Representation and the Borda Rule". The American Political Science Review. 77 (3): 718–733. doi:10.2307/1957270. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 1957270. S2CID 147162169.
  14. ^ Fishburn, Peter C. (1981-10-01). "Majority committees". Journal of Economic Theory. 25 (2): 255–268. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(81)90005-3. ISSN 0022-0531.
  15. ^ Fishburn, Peter C. (1981-12-01). "An Analysis of Simple Voting Systems for Electing Committees". SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics. 41 (3): 499–502. doi:10.1137/0141041. ISSN 0036-1399.
  16. ^ Darmann, Andreas (2013-11-01). "How hard is it to tell which is a Condorcet committee?". Mathematical Social Sciences. 66 (3): 282–292. doi:10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2013.06.004. ISSN 0165-4896. PMC 4376023. PMID 25843993.
  17. ^ Gehrlein, William V. (1985-12-01). "The Condorcet criterion and committee selection". Mathematical Social Sciences. 10 (3): 199–209. doi:10.1016/0165-4896(85)90043-5. ISSN 0165-4896.
  18. ^ Ratliff, Thomas C. (2003-12-01). "Some startling inconsistencies when electing committees". Social Choice and Welfare. 21 (3): 433–454. doi:10.1007/s00355-003-0209-y. ISSN 1432-217X. S2CID 36949675.
  19. ^ a b c d Barberà, Salvador; Coelho, Danilo (2008). "How to choose a non-controversial list with k names". Social Choice and Welfare. 31 (1): 79–96. doi:10.1007/s00355-007-0268-6. ISSN 0176-1714. JSTOR 41107910. S2CID 16974573.
  20. ^ Coelho, Danilo; Barberà, Salvador (2005). Understanding, evaluating and selecting voting rules through games and axioms. Bellaterra: Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona. ISBN 978-84-689-0967-7.
  21. ^ Kamwa, Eric (2017-05-01). "On stable rules for selecting committees". Journal of Mathematical Economics. 70: 36–44. doi:10.1016/j.jmateco.2017.01.008. ISSN 0304-4068. S2CID 125508393.
  22. ^ Elkind, Edith; Lang, Jérôme; Saffidine, Abdallah (2015). "Condorcet winning sets". Social Choice and Welfare. 44 (3): 493–517. doi:10.1007/s00355-014-0853-4. ISSN 0176-1714. JSTOR 43662603. S2CID 31128109.
  23. ^ Aziz, Haris; Monnot, Jérôme (2020-02-17). "Computing and testing Pareto optimal committees". Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems. 34 (1): 24. arXiv:1803.06644. doi:10.1007/s10458-020-09445-y. ISSN 1573-7454. S2CID 3955482.
  24. ^ Faliszewski, Piotr; Skowron, Piotr; Slinko, Arkadii; Talmon, Nimrod (2016-07-09). "Committee scoring rules: axiomatic classification and hierarchy". Proceedings of the Twenty-Fifth International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence. IJCAI'16. New York, New York, USA: AAAI Press: 250–256. ISBN 978-1-57735-770-4.
  25. ^ Skowron, Piotr; Faliszewski, Piotr; Lang, Jerome (2015-01-01). Finding a Collective Set of Items: From Proportional Multirepresentation to Group Recommendation. AAAI'15. Vol. 1402. pp. 2131–2137. arXiv:1402.3044. Bibcode:2014arXiv1402.3044S. ISBN 978-0262511292. {{cite book}}: |journal= ignored (help)
  26. ^ Lu, Tyler; Boutilier, Craig (2011-01-01). Budgeted Social Choice: From Consensus to Personalized Decision Making. IJCAI'11. pp. 280–286. doi:10.5591/978-1-57735-516-8/IJCAI11-057. ISBN 9781577355137. {{cite book}}: |journal= ignored (help)
  27. ^ Skowron, Piotr; Faliszewski, Piotr; Slinko, Arkadii (2015-05-01). "Achieving fully proportional representation: Approximability results". Artificial Intelligence. 222: 67–103. arXiv:1312.4026. doi:10.1016/j.artint.2015.01.003. S2CID 467056.

multiwinner, voting, also, called, multiple, winner, elections, committee, voting, committee, elections, electoral, system, which, multiple, candidates, elected, number, elected, candidates, usually, fixed, advance, example, number, seats, country, parliament,. Multiwinner voting 1 also called multiple winner elections 2 or committee voting 3 or committee elections 4 is an electoral system in which multiple candidates are elected The number of elected candidates is usually fixed in advance For example it can be the number of seats in a country s parliament or the required number of members in a committee There are many scenarios in which multiwinner voting is useful They can be broadly classified into three classes based on the main objective in electing the committee 5 Excellence Here each voter is an expert and each vote expresses his her opinion about which candidate s is better for a certain task The goal is to find the best candidates An example application is shortlisting selecting from a list of candidate employees a small set of finalists who will proceed to the final stage of evaluation e g using an interview Here each candidate is evaluated independently of the other candidates If two candidates are similar then probably both will be elected if they are both good or both will be rejected if both are bad Diversity Here the elected candidates should be as different as possible For example suppose the candidates are possible locations for constructing a facility such as a fire station Most citizens naturally prefer a fire station in the city center However there is no need to have two fire stations in the same place it is better to diversify the selection and put the second station in a more remote location In contrast to the excellence setting if two candidates are similar then probably exactly one of them will be elected Another scenario in which diversity is important is when a search engine selects results for display or when an airline selects movies for screening during a flight Proportionality Here the elected candidates should represent in scientifically balanced way the diverse opinion held by the population of voters measured by the votes they cast as much as possible This is a common goal in parliamentary elections see proportional representation Contents 1 Basic concepts 1 1 Approval voting for committees 1 2 Positional scoring rules for committees 1 3 Condorcet committees 1 4 Other criteria 2 Excellence elections 3 Diversity elections 4 Proportional elections 5 Further reading 6 See also 7 ReferencesBasic concepts editA major challenge in the study of multiwinner voting is finding reasonable adaptations of concepts from single winner voting These can be classified based on the voting type approval voting vs ranked voting Some election systems elect multiple members by competition held among individual candidates Such systems are some variations of Multiple non transferable voting and Single transferable voting In other systems candidates are grouped in committees slates and voters cast votes for the committees or slates These committee based systems are described here Approval voting for committees edit Main article Multiwinner approval voting Approval voting is a common method for single winner elections and sometimes for multiwinner elections In single winner elections each voter marks the candidate he approves and the candidate with the most votes wins With multiwinner voting there are many ways to decide which candidate should be elected In some each voter ranks the candidates in others they cast X votes As well each voter may cast single or multiple votes Already in 1895 Thiele suggested a family of weight based rules 3 6 Each rule in the family is defined by a sequence of k weakly positive weights w1 wk where k is the committee size Each voter assigns to each committee containing p candidates approved by the voter a score equal to w1 wp The committee with the highest total score is elected Some common voting rules in Thiele s family are Multiple non transferable vote MNTV the weight vector is 1 1 1 It is also called plurality at large approval voting Approval Chamberlin Courant ACC the weight vector is 1 0 0 That is each voter gives 1 point to a committee iff it contains one of his approved candidates Proportional approval voting PAV the weight vector is the Harmonic progression 1 1 2 1 3 1 k There are rules based on other principles such as minimax approval voting 7 and its generalizations 8 Phragmen s voting rules 9 and the Method of Equal Shares 10 11 Computing the winner with SNTV can be done in polynomial time but with ACC it is NP hard 12 as well as with PAV Positional scoring rules for committees edit Positional scoring rules are common in rank based single winner voting Each voter ranks the candidates from best to worst a pre specified function assigns a score to each candidate based on his rank and the candidate with the highest total score is elected In multiwinner voting held using these systems we need to assign scores to committees rather than to individual candidates There are various ways to do this for example 1 Single non transferable vote each voter gives 1 point to a committee if it contains his most preferred candidate In other words each voter votes for a single candidate in a contest that elects multiwinners and the k candidates with the largest number of votes are elected This generalizes First past the post voting It can be computed in polynomial time Multiple non transferable vote also called bloc voting each voter gives 1 point to a committee for each open seat in his top k In other words each voter votes for k candidates where k seats are open and the k candidates with the largest number of votes are elected k Borda each voter gives to each committee member his Borda count Each voter ranks the candidates and the rankings are scored together The k candidates with the highest total Borda score are elected Borda Chamberlin Courant BCC each voter gives to each committee the Borda count of his most preferred candidate in the committee 13 Computing the winner with BCC is NP hard 12 Condorcet committees edit In single winner voting a Condorcet winner is a candidate who wins in every head to head election against each of the other candidates A Condorcet method is a method that selects a Condorcet winner whenever it exists There are several ways to adapt Condorcet s criterion to multiwinner voting The first adaptation was by Peter Fishburn 14 15 a committee is a Condorcet committee iff it is preferred by a majority of voters to any other possible committee Fishburn assumed that the voters rank committees by the number of members in their approval set i e they have dichotomous preferences Later works assumed that the voters rank committees by other criteria such as by their Borda count It is coNP complete to check if a committee satisfies this criterion and coNP hard to decide if there exist a Condorcet committee 16 Another adaptation was by Gehrlein 17 and Ratliff 18 a committee is a Condorcet set iff each candidate in it is preferred by a majority of voters to each candidate outside it A multiwinner voting rule is sometimes called stable iff it selects a Condorcet set whenever it exists 19 Some stable rules are 20 Multiwinner Copeland s method each committee is scored by the number of external defeats the number of pairs c d where c is in the committee d is not and c is preferred to d by a majority of the voters Multiwinner Minimax Condorcet method each committee is scored by the size of external opposition the minimum over all pairs c d of the number of voters who prefer c Multiwinner variants of some other Condorcet rules 21 A third adaptation was by Elkind Lang and Saffidine 22 a Condorcet winning set is a set that for each member d not in the set some member c in the set is preferred to d by a majority Based on this definition they present a different multiwinner variant of the Minimax Condorcet method Other criteria edit Computing Pareto efficient committees is NP hard in general 23 Excellence elections editExcellence means that the committee should contain the best candidates Excellence based voting rules are often called screening rules 19 They are often used as a first step in a selection of a single best candidate that is a method for creating a shortlist A basic property that should be satisfied by such a rule is committee monotonicity also called house monotonicity a variant of resource monotonicity if some k candidates are elected by a rule and then the committee size increases to k 1 and the rule is re applied then the first k candidates should still be elected Some families of committee monotone rules are Sequential rules 19 using any single winner voting rule pick a single candidate and add it to the committee Repeat the process k times Best k rules 1 using any scoring rule assign a score to each candidate Pick the k candidates with the highest scores The property of committee monotonicity is incompatible with the property of stability a particular adaptation of Condorcet s criterion there exists a single voting profile that admits a unique Condorcet set of size 2 and a unique Condorcet set of size 3 and they are disjoint the set of size 2 is not contained in the set of size 3 19 On the other hand there exists a family of positional scoring rules the separable positional scoring rules that are committee monotone These rules are also computable in polynomial time if their underlying single winner scoring functions are 1 For example k Borda is separable while Multiple non transferable vote is not Diversity elections editDiversity means that the committee should contain the top ranked candidates of as many voters as possible Formally the following axioms are reasonable for diversity centered applications Narrow top criterion 1 if there exists a committee of size k containing the top ranked candidate of every voter then it should be elected Top member monotonicity 24 if a committee is elected and some voter shifts upwards the rank of his most preferred winner then the same committee should be elected Proportional elections editMain article Justified representation Proportionality means that each cohesive group of voters that is a group of voters with similar preferences should be represented by a number of winners proportional to its size Formally if the committee is of size k there are n voters and some L n k voters rank the same L candidates at the top or approve the same L candidates then these L candidates should be elected This principle is easy to implement when the voters vote for parties in party list systems but it can also be adapted to approval voting or ranked voting see justified representation Further reading editFinding a Collective Set of Items From Proportional Multirepresentation to Group Recommendation 25 Budgeted Social Choice From Consensus to Personalized Decision Making 26 Achieving fully proportional representation Approximability results 27 See also editParticipatory budgeting can be seen as an extension of multiwinner voting in which each candidate has a cost In multiwinner voting the price of each candidate is 1 and the budget is k References edit a b c d e Elkind Edith Faliszewski Piotr Skowron Piotr Slinko Arkadii 2017 03 01 Properties of multiwinner voting rules Social Choice and Welfare 48 3 599 632 doi 10 1007 s00355 017 1026 z ISSN 1432 217X PMC 7089675 PMID 32226187 RangeVoting org Glossary rangevoting org Retrieved 2021 06 25 a b Aziz Haris Brill Markus Conitzer Vincent Elkind Edith Freeman Rupert Walsh Toby 2017 Justified representation in approval based committee voting Social Choice and Welfare 48 2 461 485 doi 10 1007 s00355 016 1019 3 S2CID 8564247 Bock Hans Hermann Day William H E McMorris F R 1998 05 01 Consensus rules for committee elections Mathematical Social Sciences 35 3 219 232 doi 10 1016 S0165 4896 97 00033 4 ISSN 0165 4896 Piotr Faliszewski Piotr Skowron Arkadii Slinko Nimrod Talmon 2017 10 26 Multiwinner Voting A New Challenge for Social Choice Theory In Endriss Ulle ed Trends in Computational Social Choice Lulu com ISBN 978 1 326 91209 3 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Sanchez Fernandez Luis Elkind Edith Lackner Martin Fernandez Norberto Fisteus Jesus Val Pablo Basanta Skowron Piotr 2017 02 10 Proportional Justified Representation Proceedings of the AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence 31 1 doi 10 1609 aaai v31i1 10611 hdl 10016 26166 ISSN 2374 3468 S2CID 17538641 Brams Steven J Kilgour D Marc Sanver M Remzi 2007 09 01 A minimax procedure for electing committees Public Choice 132 3 401 420 doi 10 1007 s11127 007 9165 x ISSN 1573 7101 S2CID 46632580 Amanatidis Georgios Barrot Nathanael Lang Jerome Markakis Evangelos Ries Bernard 2015 05 04 Multiple Referenda and Multiwinner Elections Using Hamming Distances Complexity and Manipulability Proceedings of the 2015 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems AAMAS 15 Istanbul Turkey International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems 715 723 ISBN 978 1 4503 3413 6 Brill Markus Freeman Rupert Janson Svante Lackner Martin 2017 02 10 Phragmen s Voting Methods and Justified Representation Proceedings of the AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence 31 1 doi 10 1609 aaai v31i1 10598 ISSN 2374 3468 S2CID 2290202 Peters Dominik Skowron Piotr 2020 Proportionality and the Limits of Welfarism Proceedings of the 21st ACM Conference on Economics and Computation EC 20 pp 793 794 arXiv 1911 11747 doi 10 1145 3391403 3399465 ISBN 9781450379755 S2CID 208291203 Pierczynski Grzegorz Peters Dominik Skowron Piotr 2020 Proportional Participatory Budgeting with Additive Utilities Proceedings of the 2021 Conference on Neural Information Processing Systems NeurIPS 21 arXiv 2008 13276 a b Procaccia Ariel D Rosenschein Jeffrey S Zohar Aviv 2007 04 19 On the complexity of achieving proportional representation Social Choice and Welfare 30 3 353 362 doi 10 1007 s00355 007 0235 2 S2CID 18126521 Chamberlin John R Courant Paul N 1983 Representative Deliberations and Representative Decisions Proportional Representation and the Borda Rule The American Political Science Review 77 3 718 733 doi 10 2307 1957270 ISSN 0003 0554 JSTOR 1957270 S2CID 147162169 Fishburn Peter C 1981 10 01 Majority committees Journal of Economic Theory 25 2 255 268 doi 10 1016 0022 0531 81 90005 3 ISSN 0022 0531 Fishburn Peter C 1981 12 01 An Analysis of Simple Voting Systems for Electing Committees SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics 41 3 499 502 doi 10 1137 0141041 ISSN 0036 1399 Darmann Andreas 2013 11 01 How hard is it to tell which is a Condorcet committee Mathematical Social Sciences 66 3 282 292 doi 10 1016 j mathsocsci 2013 06 004 ISSN 0165 4896 PMC 4376023 PMID 25843993 Gehrlein William V 1985 12 01 The Condorcet criterion and committee selection Mathematical Social Sciences 10 3 199 209 doi 10 1016 0165 4896 85 90043 5 ISSN 0165 4896 Ratliff Thomas C 2003 12 01 Some startling inconsistencies when electing committees Social Choice and Welfare 21 3 433 454 doi 10 1007 s00355 003 0209 y ISSN 1432 217X S2CID 36949675 a b c d Barbera Salvador Coelho Danilo 2008 How to choose a non controversial list with k names Social Choice and Welfare 31 1 79 96 doi 10 1007 s00355 007 0268 6 ISSN 0176 1714 JSTOR 41107910 S2CID 16974573 Coelho Danilo Barbera Salvador 2005 Understanding evaluating and selecting voting rules through games and axioms Bellaterra Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona ISBN 978 84 689 0967 7 Kamwa Eric 2017 05 01 On stable rules for selecting committees Journal of Mathematical Economics 70 36 44 doi 10 1016 j jmateco 2017 01 008 ISSN 0304 4068 S2CID 125508393 Elkind Edith Lang Jerome Saffidine Abdallah 2015 Condorcet winning sets Social Choice and Welfare 44 3 493 517 doi 10 1007 s00355 014 0853 4 ISSN 0176 1714 JSTOR 43662603 S2CID 31128109 Aziz Haris Monnot Jerome 2020 02 17 Computing and testing Pareto optimal committees Autonomous Agents and Multi Agent Systems 34 1 24 arXiv 1803 06644 doi 10 1007 s10458 020 09445 y ISSN 1573 7454 S2CID 3955482 Faliszewski Piotr Skowron Piotr Slinko Arkadii Talmon Nimrod 2016 07 09 Committee scoring rules axiomatic classification and hierarchy Proceedings of the Twenty Fifth International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence IJCAI 16 New York New York USA AAAI Press 250 256 ISBN 978 1 57735 770 4 Skowron Piotr Faliszewski Piotr Lang Jerome 2015 01 01 Finding a Collective Set of Items From Proportional Multirepresentation to Group Recommendation AAAI 15 Vol 1402 pp 2131 2137 arXiv 1402 3044 Bibcode 2014arXiv1402 3044S ISBN 978 0262511292 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a journal ignored help Lu Tyler Boutilier Craig 2011 01 01 Budgeted Social Choice From Consensus to Personalized Decision Making IJCAI 11 pp 280 286 doi 10 5591 978 1 57735 516 8 IJCAI11 057 ISBN 9781577355137 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a journal ignored help Skowron Piotr Faliszewski Piotr Slinko Arkadii 2015 05 01 Achieving fully proportional representation Approximability results Artificial Intelligence 222 67 103 arXiv 1312 4026 doi 10 1016 j artint 2015 01 003 S2CID 467056 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Multiwinner voting amp oldid 1193622751, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.