fbpx
Wikipedia

Dominance (economics)

Market dominance is the control of a economic market by a firm.[1] A dominant firm possesses the power to affect competition[2] and influence market price.[3] A firms' dominance is a measure of the power of a brand, product, service, or firm, relative to competitive offerings, whereby a dominant firm can behave independent of their competitors or consumers,[4] and without concern for resource allocation.[5] Dominant positioning is both a legal concept and an economic concept and the distinction between the two is important when determining whether a firm's market position is dominant.

Abuse of market dominance is an anti-competitive practice, however dominance itself is legal.

Sources of market dominance edit

Firms can achieve dominance in their industry through multiple means, such as;

First-mover advantages edit

Many dominant firms are the first "important" competitor in their industry.[7] These firms can achieve short- or long-term advantages over their competitors when they are the first offering in a new industry. First-movers can set a benchmark for competitors and consumers regarding expectations of product and service offering, technology, convenience, quality, or price.[8] These firms are representative of their industry and their brand can become synonymous with the product category itself, such as the company Band-Aid. First-mover advantage is a limited source of market dominance if a firm becomes complacent or fails to keep up innovation by competitors.[9]

Innovation edit

It is recognised that firms who place greater importance on product innovation often have an advantage over firms who do not.[10] The significant links to Game theory have are apparent, and in conjunction with empirical evidence, research has attempted to explain whether more dominant firms or less dominant firms innovate more.[11]

Brand Equity edit

Referring to the value that branding adds over a generic equivalent, Brand Equity can contribute to gains in market dominance for firms who choose to capitalise on its worth, whether through charging a price premium or other business strategy.[12]

Economies of Scale edit

As firms expand, production becomes more efficient and costs lower.[13] It has been shown in empirically several times that there is a clear link between profitability and market share, and thus market dominance.[14] The explicit relationship between economies of scale and market shares has also been explored.[15]

Measuring market dominance edit

Identifying a dominant position involves the use of several factors. The European Commission's Guidance on A102 states that a dominant position is derived from a combination of factors, which taken separately are not determinative. Therefore, it is necessary to consider the constraints imposed by existing supplies from, and the position of, actual competitors, meaning those who are competing with the undertaking in question. This involves looking at the day-to-day downwards pressure that retains low product prices and competitiveness within the market, which market shares are only useful as a first indication of; this needs to be followed by the consideration of other factors such as market conditions and dynamics.[16]

Market share edit

There is often a geographic element to the competitive landscape. In defining market dominance, one must see to what extent a product, brand, or firm controls a product category in a given geographic area.[17] There are several ways of measuring market dominance. The most direct is market share. This is the percentage of the total market served by a firm or brand. A declining scale of market shares is common in most industries: that is, if the industry leader has say 50% share, the next largest might have 25% share, the next 12% share, the next 6% share, and all remaining firms combined might have 7% share.

Market share is not a perfect proxy of market dominance. Although there are no hard and fast rules governing the relationship between market share and market dominance, the following are general criteria:[18]

  • A company, brand, product, or service that has a combined market share exceeding 60% most probably has market power and market dominance.
  • A market share of over 35% but less than 60%, held by one brand, product or service, is an indicator of market strength but not necessarily dominance.
  • A market share of less than 35%, held by one brand, product or service, is not an indicator of strength or dominance and will not raise anti-competitive concerns by government regulators.

Market shares within an industry might not exhibit a declining scale. There could be only two firms in a duopolistic market, each with 50% share; or there could be three firms in the industry each with 33% share; or 100 firms each with 1% share. The concentration ratio of an industry is used as an indicator of the relative size of leading firms in relation to the industry as a whole. One commonly used concentration ratio is the four-firm concentration ratio, which consists of the combined market share of the four largest firms, as a percentage, in the total industry. The higher the concentration ratio, the greater the market power of the leading firms.

Legally, the determination is often more complex. A case that can be used to define market dominance under EU Law is the United Brands v Commission (The ‘bananas’ case) where the court of justice said, 'the dominant position thus referred to by Article [102] relates to a position of economic strength enjoyed by an undertaking which enables it to prevent effective competition being maintained on the relevant market by affording it the power to behave to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors, customers and ultimately of its consumers’[19] The commission's Guidance suggests that market shares is only a ‘useful first indication’ in the process of assessing market power.

Market dominance and monopolies edit

Market dominance is closely related to the economic concept of competition. Monopolistic power is derived from market share, and thus intertwined with dominance.[20] Whilst a theoretical monopoly will have a single firm supplying the industry, market dominance can describe a situation where multiple firms operate in the market, however a single firm has majority control.[21]

As economic competition is encouraged, regulation in most countries applies to both monopolistic firms, as well as firms who hold dominant market positions. In Australia, for example, the Australian Competition & Consumer Commission hold the position that a firm with significant market power (relating to dominant firms, all the way up to firms in a complete monopoly) must not "do anything that has the purpose, effect or likely effect of substantially lessening competition." [22]

Relevance of market shares

According to the European Commission, market shares provide a useful first indication of the structure of any market and of the relative importance of the various undertakings active on it.[16] In paragraph 15 of the Guidance on A102, the European Commission state that a high market share over a long period of time can be a preliminary indication of dominance. The International Competition Network stress that determining whether substantial market power is apparent should not be based on market shares alone, but instead an analysis of all factors affecting the competitive conditions in the market, should be used.[23]

100% market shares are very rare but can arise in niche areas, a close example of this being 91.8% market share in Tetra Pak 1 (BTG Licence), and the 96% market share in plasterboard held by BPB in BPB Industries Plc v Commission OJ.[24][25]

In Hoffman-La Roche v Commission, the Court of Justice said that large market shares are ‘evidence of the existence of a dominant position’ which led to the Court of Justice decision in AKZO v Commission that where there is market share of at least 50%, without exceptional circumstances, there will be a presumption of dominance that shifts the burden of proof on to the undertaking.[26][27] The European Commission has affirmed this threshold in cases since AKZO. For example, in paragraph 100 of the Commission Judgment in the Court of First Instance in France Telecom v Commission, the Commission state that ‘…very large shares are in themselves, and save in exceptional circumstances, evidence of the existence of a dominant position…’, citing the Court of Justice judgement in AZKO, paragraph 60, ‘…this was so in the case of a 50% market share.’.[28]

European Commission's Tenth Report on Competition implies that a significant disparity between the largest and the second-largest firm shares can indicate that the largest firm has a dominant position in the market. Specifically, under a section entitled "Scrutiny of mergers for compatibility with Article 86 EEC," the Report states:

A dominant position can generally be said to exist once a market share to the order of 40% to 45% is reached. [footnote: A dominant position cannot even be ruled out in respect of market shares between 20% and 40%; Ninth Report on Competition Policy, point 22.] Although this share does not in itself automatically give control of the market, if there are large gaps between the position of the firm concerned and those of its closest competitors and also other factors likely to place it at an advantage as regards competition, a dominant position may well exist. (European Commission's Tenth Report on Competition, page 103, paragraph 150.)

Impact on competitors edit

Another way of calculating market dominance, by looking at competition as market shares, are even less useful when assessing the competitive pressure that is exerted on an undertaking – i.e. the competition that would come from other firms that are not yet operating on the market but have the capacity to enter it in the near future. Of particular importance here are paragraphs 16 and 17 of the commission's Guidance...16. Competition is a dynamic process and an assessment of the competitive constraints on an undertaking cannot be based solely on the existing market situation. The potential impact of expansion by actual competitors or entry by potential competitors, including the threat of such expansion or entry, is also relevant. An undertaking can be deterred from increasing prices if expansion or entry is likely, timely and sufficient. For the commission to consider expansion or entry likely it must be sufficiently profitable for the competitor or entrant, taking into account factors such as the barriers to expansion or entry, the likely reactions of the allegedly dominant undertaking and other competitors, and the risks and costs of failure.

The Guidance also states that the constraints imposed by the credible threat of future expansion by actual competitors, or entry by potential competitors, is a required factor of consideration. For example, Intellectual Property in the form of patent protection, is a potential legal barrier to entering the market for new businesses, as was shown in Microsoft Corp. In this case, the Court of Justice confirmed the commission's decision, that Microsoft were dominant and had abused their dominant position regarding their refusal to supply the interoperability information for operating PC Windows with other systems. Microsoft was forced to license out its interoperability data.

Herfindahl–Hirschman index edit

There is also the Herfindahl–Hirschman index. It is a measure of the size of firms in relation to the industry and an indicator of the amount of competition among them. It is defined as the sum of the squares of the market shares of each individual firm. As such, it can range from 0 to 10,000, moving from a very large amount of very small firms to a single monopolistic producer. Decreases in the Herfindahl–Hirschman index generally indicate a loss of pricing power and an increase in competition, whereas increases imply the opposite.

Kwoka's dominance index edit

Kwoka's dominance index ( ) is defined as the sum of the squared differences between each firm's share and the next largest share in a market:

 

where

  for all  .[29]

Other measures of market dominance edit

As part of its merger review process, Mexican Competition Commission uses García Alba's dominance index ( ), described as the Herfindahl–Hirschman index of a Herfindahl–Hirschman index ( ). Formally,   is the sum of squared firm contributions to the market  :   where  Asymmetry Index ( ) is defined as the statistical variance of market shares:   [30][31]

Customer power edit

Countervailing Buyer Power is something else that should be considered when calculating market dominance. In market where the buyers have more power than suppliers in determining prices or changes in the market a firm of high market share may not exercise its powers against competitors easily as it always has to be accountable to customers that give it its high market share and are not hesitant to switch product preference to the next firm. Such customers will need to have sufficient bargaining strength which will normally come from its size or its commercial significance in the industry sector.

The final point that must be considered is the bargaining strength of the undertaking's customers, also known as the countervailing buyer power. This refers to the competitive constraints that customers may exert where they are a large size, or commercially significant, for a dominant firm. However, the commission will not come to a final decision without examining all of the factors which may be relevant to constrain the behavior of the undertaking.[16]

Previous findings of dominance can not be used to calculate dominance as agreed in the Coca-Cola v Commission [2000] case where it was Court held that the Commission must take a fresh approach to the market conditions each time it adopts a decision in relation to Art 102.

Legal definition edit

There are different perspectives of what indicates dominance and how to go about establishing dominance. One of these being the perspective of the European Commission regarding their application of Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (Formerly Article 82 of the Treaty establishing the European Community), that deals specifically with the abuse of dominance in the market regarding competition law.

The European Commission equates dominance with the economic concept of substantial market power, which indicates that dominance can be exerted and abused, in its Guidance on A102 Enforcement Priorities. In paragraph 10 of the Guidance, it is stated that where there is no competitive pressure, an undertaking, which is a legal entity acting in the course of business, is probably able to exercise substantial market power. Furthermore, in paragraph 11, this is developed on, arguing if an undertaking can increase their products above the competitive price level, and does not face economic restraints, it is therefore dominant.[16] For example, in basic terms, if two businesses are selling competing products, and one can increase their selling price, and not suffer an economic consequence such as a boycott of their products or a shift of their customers to a cheaper product, they are dominant.

The Guidance is not law, it is instead a set of rules the courts are to follow. However, the same definition can be found elsewhere, in Chapter 3 of the Unilateral Conduct Workbook.[32] The Guidance is also supported by paragraph 65 of the commission's judgement in United Brands v Commission.[33]

“65THE DOMINANT POSITION REFERRED TO IN THIS ARTICLE (102) RELATES TO A POSITION OF ECONOMIC STRENGTH ENJOYED BY AN UNDERTAKING WHICH ENABLES IT TO PREVENT EFFECTIVE COMPETITION BEING MAINTAINED ON THE RELEVANT MARKET BY GIVING IT THE POWER TO BEHAVE TO AN APPRECIABLE EXTENT INDEPENDENTLY OF ITS COMPETITORS , CUSTOMERS AND ULTIMATELY OF ITS CONSUMERS."

The identification of the relevant and geographic market must first be established before being able to calculate shares or an undertaking’s dominance within that market. Dominance as an economic concept is determined within EU competition law through a 2-stage process, which first requires the identification of the relevant market as was established in Continental Can v Commission. This was affirmed in paragraph 30 of the judgement of AstraZeneca AB v Commission, in which the Commission stated that it must be assessed whether an undertaking is able to act independently of its competitors, customers and consumers.[34]

The identification of the relevant and geographic market is assessed through the hypothetical monopolist test, which questions would a party's customer, switch to an alternative supplier located elsewhere, in response to a small relative price increase. Therefore, it is a question of interchangeability and demand substitutability, meaning whether one product can be a substitute for another, and whether an undertaking's market power puts them above price competition. The second stage of the test requires the commission to look at various factors to see if an undertaking enjoys a dominant position on that relevant market.[35]

Market Dominance Attractiveness edit

Why firms want a greater market share is a logical concept with both empirical and theoretical foundations. One of the main driving principles is a firm's profit motive, dealing specifically with why firms choose to maximize their profits.[36] As research links market share to return on investment, it is expected that firms will choose to follow strategies which lead to increasing market share and a more dominant position in the market.[37]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Rosenbaum, David Ira (1998). Market Dominance: How Firms Gain, Hold, Or Lose it and the Impact on Economic Performance. Greenwood Publishing Group. ISBN 978-0-275-95604-2.
  2. ^ Shepherd, William (1990). The Economics of Industrial Organisation. NJ: Englewood Cliffs. pp. 273=0.
  3. ^ Doyle, Chris (20–22 November 2002). "Market Definition and Dominance" (PDF).
  4. ^ "What does dominant market position mean? Is it acceptable? | Department of Economics". www.econ.iastate.edu. Retrieved 2022-05-02.
  5. ^ "Market Dominance: How Firms Gain, Hold, or Lose It and the Impact on Economic Performance". eh.net. Retrieved 2022-05-02.
  6. ^ Buzzell, Robert D.; Gale, Bradley T.; Sultan, Ralph G. M. (1975-01-01). "Market Share—a Key to Profitability". Harvard Business Review. ISSN 0017-8012. Retrieved 2022-05-02.
  7. ^ Suarez, Fernando F.; Lanzolla, Gianvito (2005-04-01). "The Half-Truth of First-Mover Advantage". Harvard Business Review. ISSN 0017-8012. Retrieved 2022-05-02.
  8. ^ Kerin, Roger A.; Varadarajan, P. Rajan; Peterson, Robert A. (1992). "First-Mover Advantage: A Synthesis, Conceptual Framework, and Research Propositions". Journal of Marketing. 56 (4): 33. doi:10.2307/1251985. ISSN 0022-2429. JSTOR 1251985.
  9. ^ Lieberman, Marvin; Montgomery, David (1988). "First-Mover Advantages". Strategic Management Journal. 9. Wiley: 41–58. doi:10.1002/smj.4250090706. JSTOR 2486211.
  10. ^ Bloom, Paul; Kotler, Philip (1975-11-01). "Strategies for High Market-Share Companies". Harvard Business Review. ISSN 0017-8012. Retrieved 2023-04-22.
  11. ^ Oviedo de Valeria, Jenny (1994-08-02). "chrome-extension://efaidnbmnnnibpcajpcglclefindmkaj/http://www.revista-educacion-matematica.org.mx/descargas/vol6/vol6-2/vol6-2-5.pdf". Educación matemática. 6 (2): 73–86. doi:10.24844/em0602.06. ISSN 2448-8089. S2CID 256222263.
  12. ^ Joshi, Sagar (3 September 2021). "Brand Equity: How to Encourage Customers to Trust Your Brand". G2. Retrieved 24 April 2023.
  13. ^ "Economies of Scale: What Are They and How Are They Used?". Investopedia. Retrieved 2023-04-23.
  14. ^ Wernerfelt, Birger (February 1986). "The Relation Between Market Share and Profitability". Journal of Business Strategy. 6 (4): 67–74. doi:10.1108/eb039133 – via Research Gate.
  15. ^ Makadok, Richard (October 1999). "Interfirm differences in scale economies and the evolution of market shares". Strategic Management Journal. 20 (10): 935–952. doi:10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(199910)20:10<935::AID-SMJ56>3.0.CO;2-G – via Wiley.
  16. ^ a b c d "EUR-Lex - 52009XC0224(01) - EN - EUR-Lex". eur-lex.europa.eu. Retrieved 2018-04-30.
  17. ^ (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2012-04-10. Retrieved 2013-02-04.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  18. ^ Utton, Michael A. (2005-01-01). Market Dominance and Antitrust Policy. Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN 978-1-84376-748-0.
  19. ^ "United Nations Commission on International Trade Law (UNCITRAL) Yearbook 1976". United Nations Commission on International Trade Law (UNCITRAL) Yearbook. 1976-05-06. doi:10.18356/60cfa22d-en. ISBN 9789210450928. ISSN 2412-1169.
  20. ^ "What Is a Monopoly? Types, Regulations, and Impact on Markets". Investopedia. Retrieved 2023-04-24.
  21. ^ STRONG, NATHAN; BOLLARD, ALAN; PICKFORD, MICHAEL (2000). "Defining Market Dominance: A Study of Antitrust Decisions on Business Acquisitions in New Zealand". Review of Industrial Organization. 17 (2): 209–227. doi:10.1023/A:1007850614256. ISSN 0889-938X. JSTOR 41798951. S2CID 152600540.
  22. ^ "Misuse of market power". Australian Competition & Consumer Commission. 2023-03-26. Retrieved 2023-04-24.
  23. ^ Recommended Practices: Dominance/Substantial Market Power Analysis Pursuant To Unilateral Conduct Laws. ICN Unilateral Conduct Working Group.
  24. ^ 88/501/EEC: Commission Decision of 26 July 1988 relating to a proceeding under Articles 85 and 86 of the EEC Treaty (IV/31.043 - Tetra Pak I (BTG licence) (Only the English and French texts are authentic), 1988-10-04, retrieved 2018-04-30
  25. ^ "EUR-Lex - 61989TJ0065 - EN - EUR-Lex". eur-lex.europa.eu. Retrieved 2018-04-30.
  26. ^ "EUR-Lex - 61976CJ0085 - EN - EUR-Lex". eur-lex.europa.eu. Retrieved 2018-04-30.
  27. ^ "EUR-Lex - 61986CJ0062 - EN - EUR-Lex". eur-lex.europa.eu. Retrieved 2018-04-30.
  28. ^ "CURIA - Documents". curia.europa.eu. Retrieved 2018-04-30.
  29. ^ Kwoka, J. E. "Large firm dominance and price-cost margins in manufacturing industries." Southern Econ J (1977) vol. 44, pp. 183–9.
  30. ^ Brown, Donald M., and Frederick R. Warren-Boulton, Testing the Structure- Competition Relationship on Cross-Sectional Firm Data, EAG 88-6, May 11, 1988.
  31. ^ Warren-Boulton, Frederick R. (1990). "Implications of U.S. Experience with Horizontal Mergers and Takeovers for Canadian Competition Policy". in Mathewson, G. Franklin et al. (eds.). The Law and Economics of Competition Policy. Vancouver, B.C.: The Fraser Institute. ISBN 0-88975-121-8.
  32. ^ Unilateral Conduct Workbook Chapter 3: Assessment of Dominance. 10th Annual ICN Conference The Hague, Netherlands: The Unilateral Conduct Working Group. May 2011.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  33. ^ "EUR-Lex - 61976CJ0027 - EN - EUR-Lex". eur-lex.europa.eu. Retrieved 2018-04-30.
  34. ^ "CURIA - Documents". curia.europa.eu. Retrieved 2018-04-30.
  35. ^ "EUR-Lex - 61972CJ0006 - EN - EUR-Lex". eur-lex.europa.eu. Retrieved 2018-04-30.
  36. ^ Mauborgne, W. Chan Kim | Renée (2016-03-29). "Three Steps Towards Market Domination". INSEAD Knowledge. Retrieved 2023-04-24.
  37. ^ Buzzell, Robert D.; Gale, Bradley T.; Sultan, Ralph G. M. (1975-01-01). "Market Share—a Key to Profitability". Harvard Business Review. ISSN 0017-8012. Retrieved 2023-04-24.

dominance, economics, other, uses, dominance, game, theory, strategic, dominance, market, dominance, control, economic, market, firm, dominant, firm, possesses, power, affect, competition, influence, market, price, firms, dominance, measure, power, brand, prod. For other uses see Dominance For game theory see Strategic dominance Market dominance is the control of a economic market by a firm 1 A dominant firm possesses the power to affect competition 2 and influence market price 3 A firms dominance is a measure of the power of a brand product service or firm relative to competitive offerings whereby a dominant firm can behave independent of their competitors or consumers 4 and without concern for resource allocation 5 Dominant positioning is both a legal concept and an economic concept and the distinction between the two is important when determining whether a firm s market position is dominant Abuse of market dominance is an anti competitive practice however dominance itself is legal Contents 1 Sources of market dominance 1 1 First mover advantages 1 2 Innovation 1 3 Brand Equity 1 4 Economies of Scale 2 Measuring market dominance 2 1 Market share 2 1 1 Market dominance and monopolies 2 2 Impact on competitors 2 3 Herfindahl Hirschman index 2 4 Kwoka s dominance index 2 5 Other measures of market dominance 2 6 Customer power 3 Legal definition 4 Market Dominance Attractiveness 5 See also 6 ReferencesSources of market dominance editFirms can achieve dominance in their industry through multiple means such as First mover advantage Innovation Brand equity and Economies of scale 6 First mover advantages edit Many dominant firms are the first important competitor in their industry 7 These firms can achieve short or long term advantages over their competitors when they are the first offering in a new industry First movers can set a benchmark for competitors and consumers regarding expectations of product and service offering technology convenience quality or price 8 These firms are representative of their industry and their brand can become synonymous with the product category itself such as the company Band Aid First mover advantage is a limited source of market dominance if a firm becomes complacent or fails to keep up innovation by competitors 9 Innovation edit It is recognised that firms who place greater importance on product innovation often have an advantage over firms who do not 10 The significant links to Game theory have are apparent and in conjunction with empirical evidence research has attempted to explain whether more dominant firms or less dominant firms innovate more 11 Brand Equity edit Referring to the value that branding adds over a generic equivalent Brand Equity can contribute to gains in market dominance for firms who choose to capitalise on its worth whether through charging a price premium or other business strategy 12 Economies of Scale edit As firms expand production becomes more efficient and costs lower 13 It has been shown in empirically several times that there is a clear link between profitability and market share and thus market dominance 14 The explicit relationship between economies of scale and market shares has also been explored 15 Measuring market dominance editIdentifying a dominant position involves the use of several factors The European Commission s Guidance on A102 states that a dominant position is derived from a combination of factors which taken separately are not determinative Therefore it is necessary to consider the constraints imposed by existing supplies from and the position of actual competitors meaning those who are competing with the undertaking in question This involves looking at the day to day downwards pressure that retains low product prices and competitiveness within the market which market shares are only useful as a first indication of this needs to be followed by the consideration of other factors such as market conditions and dynamics 16 Market share edit There is often a geographic element to the competitive landscape In defining market dominance one must see to what extent a product brand or firm controls a product category in a given geographic area 17 There are several ways of measuring market dominance The most direct is market share This is the percentage of the total market served by a firm or brand A declining scale of market shares is common in most industries that is if the industry leader has say 50 share the next largest might have 25 share the next 12 share the next 6 share and all remaining firms combined might have 7 share Market share is not a perfect proxy of market dominance Although there are no hard and fast rules governing the relationship between market share and market dominance the following are general criteria 18 A company brand product or service that has a combined market share exceeding 60 most probably has market power and market dominance A market share of over 35 but less than 60 held by one brand product or service is an indicator of market strength but not necessarily dominance A market share of less than 35 held by one brand product or service is not an indicator of strength or dominance and will not raise anti competitive concerns by government regulators Market shares within an industry might not exhibit a declining scale There could be only two firms in a duopolistic market each with 50 share or there could be three firms in the industry each with 33 share or 100 firms each with 1 share The concentration ratio of an industry is used as an indicator of the relative size of leading firms in relation to the industry as a whole One commonly used concentration ratio is the four firm concentration ratio which consists of the combined market share of the four largest firms as a percentage in the total industry The higher the concentration ratio the greater the market power of the leading firms Legally the determination is often more complex A case that can be used to define market dominance under EU Law is the United Brands v Commission The bananas case where the court of justice said the dominant position thus referred to by Article 102 relates to a position of economic strength enjoyed by an undertaking which enables it to prevent effective competition being maintained on the relevant market by affording it the power to behave to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors customers and ultimately of its consumers 19 The commission s Guidance suggests that market shares is only a useful first indication in the process of assessing market power Market dominance and monopolies edit Market dominance is closely related to the economic concept of competition Monopolistic power is derived from market share and thus intertwined with dominance 20 Whilst a theoretical monopoly will have a single firm supplying the industry market dominance can describe a situation where multiple firms operate in the market however a single firm has majority control 21 As economic competition is encouraged regulation in most countries applies to both monopolistic firms as well as firms who hold dominant market positions In Australia for example the Australian Competition amp Consumer Commission hold the position that a firm with significant market power relating to dominant firms all the way up to firms in a complete monopoly must not do anything that has the purpose effect or likely effect of substantially lessening competition 22 Relevance of market sharesAccording to the European Commission market shares provide a useful first indication of the structure of any market and of the relative importance of the various undertakings active on it 16 In paragraph 15 of the Guidance on A102 the European Commission state that a high market share over a long period of time can be a preliminary indication of dominance The International Competition Network stress that determining whether substantial market power is apparent should not be based on market shares alone but instead an analysis of all factors affecting the competitive conditions in the market should be used 23 100 market shares are very rare but can arise in niche areas a close example of this being 91 8 market share in Tetra Pak 1 BTG Licence and the 96 market share in plasterboard held by BPB in BPB Industries Plc v Commission OJ 24 25 In Hoffman La Roche v Commission the Court of Justice said that large market shares are evidence of the existence of a dominant position which led to the Court of Justice decision in AKZO v Commission that where there is market share of at least 50 without exceptional circumstances there will be a presumption of dominance that shifts the burden of proof on to the undertaking 26 27 The European Commission has affirmed this threshold in cases since AKZO For example in paragraph 100 of the Commission Judgment in the Court of First Instance in France Telecom v Commission the Commission state that very large shares are in themselves and save in exceptional circumstances evidence of the existence of a dominant position citing the Court of Justice judgement in AZKO paragraph 60 this was so in the case of a 50 market share 28 European Commission s Tenth Report on Competition implies that a significant disparity between the largest and the second largest firm shares can indicate that the largest firm has a dominant position in the market Specifically under a section entitled Scrutiny of mergers for compatibility with Article 86 EEC the Report states A dominant position can generally be said to exist once a market share to the order of 40 to 45 is reached footnote A dominant position cannot even be ruled out in respect of market shares between 20 and 40 Ninth Report on Competition Policy point 22 Although this share does not in itself automatically give control of the market if there are large gaps between the position of the firm concerned and those of its closest competitors and also other factors likely to place it at an advantage as regards competition a dominant position may well exist European Commission s Tenth Report on Competition page 103 paragraph 150 Impact on competitors edit Another way of calculating market dominance by looking at competition as market shares are even less useful when assessing the competitive pressure that is exerted on an undertaking i e the competition that would come from other firms that are not yet operating on the market but have the capacity to enter it in the near future Of particular importance here are paragraphs 16 and 17 of the commission s Guidance 16 Competition is a dynamic process and an assessment of the competitive constraints on an undertaking cannot be based solely on the existing market situation The potential impact of expansion by actual competitors or entry by potential competitors including the threat of such expansion or entry is also relevant An undertaking can be deterred from increasing prices if expansion or entry is likely timely and sufficient For the commission to consider expansion or entry likely it must be sufficiently profitable for the competitor or entrant taking into account factors such as the barriers to expansion or entry the likely reactions of the allegedly dominant undertaking and other competitors and the risks and costs of failure The Guidance also states that the constraints imposed by the credible threat of future expansion by actual competitors or entry by potential competitors is a required factor of consideration For example Intellectual Property in the form of patent protection is a potential legal barrier to entering the market for new businesses as was shown in Microsoft Corp In this case the Court of Justice confirmed the commission s decision that Microsoft were dominant and had abused their dominant position regarding their refusal to supply the interoperability information for operating PC Windows with other systems Microsoft was forced to license out its interoperability data Herfindahl Hirschman index edit Main article Herfindahl Hirschman index There is also the Herfindahl Hirschman index It is a measure of the size of firms in relation to the industry and an indicator of the amount of competition among them It is defined as the sum of the squares of the market shares of each individual firm As such it can range from 0 to 10 000 moving from a very large amount of very small firms to a single monopolistic producer Decreases in the Herfindahl Hirschman index generally indicate a loss of pricing power and an increase in competition whereas increases imply the opposite Kwoka s dominance index edit Kwoka s dominance index D displaystyle text D nbsp is defined as the sum of the squared differences between each firm s share and the next largest share in a market D i 1 n 1 s i s i 1 2 displaystyle text D sum i 1 n 1 s i s i 1 2 nbsp where s 1 s i s i 1 s n displaystyle s 1 geq geq s i geq s i 1 geq geq s n nbsp for all i 1 n 1 displaystyle i 1 n 1 nbsp 29 Other measures of market dominance edit As part of its merger review process Mexican Competition Commission uses Garcia Alba s dominance index ID displaystyle text ID nbsp described as the Herfindahl Hirschman index of a Herfindahl Hirschman index HHI displaystyle text HHI nbsp Formally ID displaystyle text ID nbsp is the sum of squared firm contributions to the market HHI displaystyle text HHI nbsp ID i 1 n h i 2 displaystyle text ID sum i 1 n h i 2 nbsp where h i s i 2 HHI displaystyle h i frac s i 2 text HHI nbsp Asymmetry Index AI displaystyle text AI nbsp is defined as the statistical variance of market shares AI i 1 n s i 1 n 2 n displaystyle text AI frac sum i 1 n left s i frac 1 n right 2 n nbsp 30 31 Customer power edit Countervailing Buyer Power is something else that should be considered when calculating market dominance In market where the buyers have more power than suppliers in determining prices or changes in the market a firm of high market share may not exercise its powers against competitors easily as it always has to be accountable to customers that give it its high market share and are not hesitant to switch product preference to the next firm Such customers will need to have sufficient bargaining strength which will normally come from its size or its commercial significance in the industry sector The final point that must be considered is the bargaining strength of the undertaking s customers also known as the countervailing buyer power This refers to the competitive constraints that customers may exert where they are a large size or commercially significant for a dominant firm However the commission will not come to a final decision without examining all of the factors which may be relevant to constrain the behavior of the undertaking 16 Previous findings of dominance can not be used to calculate dominance as agreed in the Coca Cola v Commission 2000 case where it was Court held that the Commission must take a fresh approach to the market conditions each time it adopts a decision in relation to Art 102 Legal definition editThere are different perspectives of what indicates dominance and how to go about establishing dominance One of these being the perspective of the European Commission regarding their application of Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union Formerly Article 82 of the Treaty establishing the European Community that deals specifically with the abuse of dominance in the market regarding competition law The European Commission equates dominance with the economic concept of substantial market power which indicates that dominance can be exerted and abused in its Guidance on A102 Enforcement Priorities In paragraph 10 of the Guidance it is stated that where there is no competitive pressure an undertaking which is a legal entity acting in the course of business is probably able to exercise substantial market power Furthermore in paragraph 11 this is developed on arguing if an undertaking can increase their products above the competitive price level and does not face economic restraints it is therefore dominant 16 For example in basic terms if two businesses are selling competing products and one can increase their selling price and not suffer an economic consequence such as a boycott of their products or a shift of their customers to a cheaper product they are dominant The Guidance is not law it is instead a set of rules the courts are to follow However the same definition can be found elsewhere in Chapter 3 of the Unilateral Conduct Workbook 32 The Guidance is also supported by paragraph 65 of the commission s judgement in United Brands v Commission 33 65THE DOMINANT POSITION REFERRED TO IN THIS ARTICLE 102 RELATES TO A POSITION OF ECONOMIC STRENGTH ENJOYED BY AN UNDERTAKING WHICH ENABLES IT TO PREVENT EFFECTIVE COMPETITION BEING MAINTAINED ON THE RELEVANT MARKET BY GIVING IT THE POWER TO BEHAVE TO AN APPRECIABLE EXTENT INDEPENDENTLY OF ITS COMPETITORS CUSTOMERS AND ULTIMATELY OF ITS CONSUMERS The identification of the relevant and geographic market must first be established before being able to calculate shares or an undertaking s dominance within that market Dominance as an economic concept is determined within EU competition law through a 2 stage process which first requires the identification of the relevant market as was established in Continental Can v Commission This was affirmed in paragraph 30 of the judgement of AstraZeneca AB v Commission in which the Commission stated that it must be assessed whether an undertaking is able to act independently of its competitors customers and consumers 34 The identification of the relevant and geographic market is assessed through the hypothetical monopolist test which questions would a party s customer switch to an alternative supplier located elsewhere in response to a small relative price increase Therefore it is a question of interchangeability and demand substitutability meaning whether one product can be a substitute for another and whether an undertaking s market power puts them above price competition The second stage of the test requires the commission to look at various factors to see if an undertaking enjoys a dominant position on that relevant market 35 Market Dominance Attractiveness editWhy firms want a greater market share is a logical concept with both empirical and theoretical foundations One of the main driving principles is a firm s profit motive dealing specifically with why firms choose to maximize their profits 36 As research links market share to return on investment it is expected that firms will choose to follow strategies which lead to increasing market share and a more dominant position in the market 37 See also editEarly adopter Market power Competition law First mover advantageReferences edit Rosenbaum David Ira 1998 Market Dominance How Firms Gain Hold Or Lose it and the Impact on Economic Performance Greenwood Publishing Group ISBN 978 0 275 95604 2 Shepherd William 1990 The Economics of Industrial Organisation NJ Englewood Cliffs pp 273 0 Doyle Chris 20 22 November 2002 Market Definition and Dominance PDF What does dominant market position mean Is it acceptable Department of Economics www econ iastate edu Retrieved 2022 05 02 Market Dominance How Firms Gain Hold or Lose It and the Impact on Economic Performance eh net Retrieved 2022 05 02 Buzzell Robert D Gale Bradley T Sultan Ralph G M 1975 01 01 Market Share a Key to Profitability Harvard Business Review ISSN 0017 8012 Retrieved 2022 05 02 Suarez Fernando F Lanzolla Gianvito 2005 04 01 The Half Truth of First Mover Advantage Harvard Business Review ISSN 0017 8012 Retrieved 2022 05 02 Kerin Roger A Varadarajan P Rajan Peterson Robert A 1992 First Mover Advantage A Synthesis Conceptual Framework and Research Propositions Journal of Marketing 56 4 33 doi 10 2307 1251985 ISSN 0022 2429 JSTOR 1251985 Lieberman Marvin Montgomery David 1988 First Mover Advantages Strategic Management Journal 9 Wiley 41 58 doi 10 1002 smj 4250090706 JSTOR 2486211 Bloom Paul Kotler Philip 1975 11 01 Strategies for High Market Share Companies Harvard Business Review ISSN 0017 8012 Retrieved 2023 04 22 Oviedo de Valeria Jenny 1994 08 02 chrome extension efaidnbmnnnibpcajpcglclefindmkaj http www revista educacion matematica org mx descargas vol6 vol6 2 vol6 2 5 pdf Educacion matematica 6 2 73 86 doi 10 24844 em0602 06 ISSN 2448 8089 S2CID 256222263 Joshi Sagar 3 September 2021 Brand Equity How to Encourage Customers to Trust Your Brand G2 Retrieved 24 April 2023 Economies of Scale What Are They and How Are They Used Investopedia Retrieved 2023 04 23 Wernerfelt Birger February 1986 The Relation Between Market Share and Profitability Journal of Business Strategy 6 4 67 74 doi 10 1108 eb039133 via Research Gate Makadok Richard October 1999 Interfirm differences in scale economies and the evolution of market shares Strategic Management Journal 20 10 935 952 doi 10 1002 SICI 1097 0266 199910 20 10 lt 935 AID SMJ56 gt 3 0 CO 2 G via Wiley a b c d EUR Lex 52009XC0224 01 EN EUR Lex eur lex europa eu Retrieved 2018 04 30 Archived copy PDF Archived from the original PDF on 2012 04 10 Retrieved 2013 02 04 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint archived copy as title link Utton Michael A 2005 01 01 Market Dominance and Antitrust Policy Edward Elgar Publishing ISBN 978 1 84376 748 0 United Nations Commission on International Trade Law UNCITRAL Yearbook 1976 United Nations Commission on International Trade Law UNCITRAL Yearbook 1976 05 06 doi 10 18356 60cfa22d en ISBN 9789210450928 ISSN 2412 1169 What Is a Monopoly Types Regulations and Impact on Markets Investopedia Retrieved 2023 04 24 STRONG NATHAN BOLLARD ALAN PICKFORD MICHAEL 2000 Defining Market Dominance A Study of Antitrust Decisions on Business Acquisitions in New Zealand Review of Industrial Organization 17 2 209 227 doi 10 1023 A 1007850614256 ISSN 0889 938X JSTOR 41798951 S2CID 152600540 Misuse of market power Australian Competition amp Consumer Commission 2023 03 26 Retrieved 2023 04 24 Recommended Practices Dominance Substantial Market Power Analysis Pursuant To Unilateral Conduct Laws ICN Unilateral Conduct Working Group 88 501 EEC Commission Decision of 26 July 1988 relating to a proceeding under Articles 85 and 86 of the EEC Treaty IV 31 043 Tetra Pak I BTG licence Only the English and French texts are authentic 1988 10 04 retrieved 2018 04 30 EUR Lex 61989TJ0065 EN EUR Lex eur lex europa eu Retrieved 2018 04 30 EUR Lex 61976CJ0085 EN EUR Lex eur lex europa eu Retrieved 2018 04 30 EUR Lex 61986CJ0062 EN EUR Lex eur lex europa eu Retrieved 2018 04 30 CURIA Documents curia europa eu Retrieved 2018 04 30 Kwoka J E Large firm dominance and price cost margins in manufacturing industries Southern Econ J 1977 vol 44 pp 183 9 Brown Donald M and Frederick R Warren Boulton Testing the Structure Competition Relationship on Cross Sectional Firm Data EAG 88 6 May 11 1988 Warren Boulton Frederick R 1990 Implications of U S Experience with Horizontal Mergers and Takeovers for Canadian Competition Policy in Mathewson G Franklin et al eds The Law and Economics of Competition Policy Vancouver B C The Fraser Institute ISBN 0 88975 121 8 Unilateral Conduct Workbook Chapter 3 Assessment of Dominance 10th Annual ICN Conference The Hague Netherlands The Unilateral Conduct Working Group May 2011 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint location link EUR Lex 61976CJ0027 EN EUR Lex eur lex europa eu Retrieved 2018 04 30 CURIA Documents curia europa eu Retrieved 2018 04 30 EUR Lex 61972CJ0006 EN EUR Lex eur lex europa eu Retrieved 2018 04 30 Mauborgne W Chan Kim Renee 2016 03 29 Three Steps Towards Market Domination INSEAD Knowledge Retrieved 2023 04 24 Buzzell Robert D Gale Bradley T Sultan Ralph G M 1975 01 01 Market Share a Key to Profitability Harvard Business Review ISSN 0017 8012 Retrieved 2023 04 24 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Dominance economics amp oldid 1209350400, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.