fbpx
Wikipedia

Lewis–Mogridge position

The Lewis–Mogridge position, named after David Lewis and Martin J. H. Mogridge, was formulated in 1990 and observes that as more roads are built, more traffic consequently fills these roads. Speed gains from some new roads can disappear within months, if not weeks. Sometimes, new roads help to reduce traffic jams, but, in most cases, the congestion is only shifted to another junction.

The position reads traffic expands to meet the available road space (Mogridge, 1990). It is generally referred to as induced demand in the transport literature, and was posited as the "Iron Law of Congestion" by Anthony Downs.[1] It is a special case of Jevons paradox (where the resource in question is traffic capacity), and relates to Marchetti's constant (average commute times are similar in widely varying conditions).

Following the position, it is not generally concluded that new roads are never justified but that their development needs to consider the whole traffic system, which means understanding the movement of goods and people in detail as well as the motivation behind the movement.

The position is often used to understand problems caused by private transport such as congested roads in cities and on motorways. It can also be used to explain the success of schemes such as the London congestion charge.[citation needed]

The position, however, is not confined to private transport. Mogridge, a British transport researcher, concluded also that all road investment in a congested urban area will have the effect of reducing the average speed of the transport system as a whole: road and public transport. The relationship and overall equilibria are also known as the "Downs–Thomson paradox". However, according to Downs, the link between average speeds on public transport and private transport applies only "to regions in which the vast majority of peak-hour commuting is done on rapid transit systems with separate rights of way. Central London is an example, since in 2001 around 85 percent of all morning peak-period commuters into that area used public transit (including 77 percent on separate rights of way) and only 11 percent used private cars. When peak-hour travel equilibrium has been reached between the subway system and the major commuting roads, then the travel time required for any given trip is roughly equal on both modes."[2]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ "The Unstoppable Appeal of Highway Expansion". Bloomberg.com. 2021-09-28. Retrieved 2021-09-28.
  2. ^ Downs, Anthony (2004). Still stuck in traffic: Coping with peak-hour traffic congestion. Brookings Institution Press. p. 133. ISBN 9780815796558. OCLC 938122068.
  3. ^ "The Road Network Paradox". Davros.org. Retrieved 2017-04-28.

Sources edit

  • Mogridge, Martin J. H., Travel in towns: jam yesterday, jam today and jam tomorrow? Macmillan Press, London, 1990. ISBN 0-333-53204-X
  • Lewis D. (1977), Estimating the influence of public policy on road traffic levels in greater London. J. Transport Econ. Policy, 11, pp. 155–168.
  • Clément, L., La conjecture de MJH Mogridge : test sur l’agglomération de Lyon (PDF), Cahiers Scientifiques du Transport (30), 1995.
  • Afimeimounga, H., Solomon, W., Ziedins, I. The Downs–Thomson Paradox: Existence, Uniqueness and Stability of User Equilibria, Queueing Systems: Theory and Applications archive, Volume 49, Issue 3–4 (January 2005).
  • Mogridge, M. J. H., Holden, D. J., Bird, J. and Terzis, G. C. "The Downs–Thomson paradox and the transportation planning process". International Journal of Transportation Economics, 14, pp. 283–311, 1987.

lewis, mogridge, position, this, article, multiple, issues, please, help, improve, discuss, these, issues, talk, page, learn, when, remove, these, template, messages, this, article, includes, list, general, references, lacks, sufficient, corresponding, inline,. This article has multiple issues Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page Learn how and when to remove these template messages This article includes a list of general references but it lacks sufficient corresponding inline citations Please help to improve this article by introducing more precise citations April 2017 Learn how and when to remove this template message This article needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Lewis Mogridge position news newspapers books scholar JSTOR February 2008 Learn how and when to remove this template message Learn how and when to remove this template message The Lewis Mogridge position named after David Lewis and Martin J H Mogridge was formulated in 1990 and observes that as more roads are built more traffic consequently fills these roads Speed gains from some new roads can disappear within months if not weeks Sometimes new roads help to reduce traffic jams but in most cases the congestion is only shifted to another junction The position reads traffic expands to meet the available road space Mogridge 1990 It is generally referred to as induced demand in the transport literature and was posited as the Iron Law of Congestion by Anthony Downs 1 It is a special case of Jevons paradox where the resource in question is traffic capacity and relates to Marchetti s constant average commute times are similar in widely varying conditions Following the position it is not generally concluded that new roads are never justified but that their development needs to consider the whole traffic system which means understanding the movement of goods and people in detail as well as the motivation behind the movement The position is often used to understand problems caused by private transport such as congested roads in cities and on motorways It can also be used to explain the success of schemes such as the London congestion charge citation needed The position however is not confined to private transport Mogridge a British transport researcher concluded also that all road investment in a congested urban area will have the effect of reducing the average speed of the transport system as a whole road and public transport The relationship and overall equilibria are also known as the Downs Thomson paradox However according to Downs the link between average speeds on public transport and private transport applies only to regions in which the vast majority of peak hour commuting is done on rapid transit systems with separate rights of way Central London is an example since in 2001 around 85 percent of all morning peak period commuters into that area used public transit including 77 percent on separate rights of way and only 11 percent used private cars When peak hour travel equilibrium has been reached between the subway system and the major commuting roads then the travel time required for any given trip is roughly equal on both modes 2 See also editBraess s paradox which states that adding a road to a road network can slow the traffic 3 and to Marchetti s constant Jevons paradox and rebound effect John Glen Wardrop Marchetti s constant a corollary of which is that decreasing congestion may increase the distance people are willing to commute thereby increasing the traffic burden Mohring effect Unused highway Roads that were closed or never usedReferences edit The Unstoppable Appeal of Highway Expansion Bloomberg com 2021 09 28 Retrieved 2021 09 28 Downs Anthony 2004 Still stuck in traffic Coping with peak hour traffic congestion Brookings Institution Press p 133 ISBN 9780815796558 OCLC 938122068 The Road Network Paradox Davros org Retrieved 2017 04 28 Sources editMogridge Martin J H Travel in towns jam yesterday jam today and jam tomorrow Macmillan Press London 1990 ISBN 0 333 53204 X Lewis D 1977 Estimating the influence of public policy on road traffic levels in greater London J Transport Econ Policy 11 pp 155 168 Clement L La conjecture de MJH Mogridge test sur l agglomeration de Lyon PDF Cahiers Scientifiques du Transport 30 1995 Afimeimounga H Solomon W Ziedins I The Downs Thomson Paradox Existence Uniqueness and Stability of User Equilibria Queueing Systems Theory and Applications archive Volume 49 Issue 3 4 January 2005 Mogridge M J H Holden D J Bird J and Terzis G C The Downs Thomson paradox and the transportation planning process International Journal of Transportation Economics 14 pp 283 311 1987 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Lewis Mogridge position amp oldid 1168431715, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.