fbpx
Wikipedia

Ideal type

Ideal type (German: Idealtypus), also known as pure type, is a typological term most closely associated with the sociologist Max Weber (1864–1920).[1] For Weber, the conduct of social science depends upon the construction of abstract, hypothetical concepts. The "ideal type" is therefore a subjective element in social theory and research, and one of the subjective elements distinguishing sociology from natural science.

Meaning edit

An ideal type is formed from characteristics and elements of the given phenomena, but it is not meant to correspond to all of the characteristics of any one particular case. It is not meant to refer to perfect things, moral ideals nor to statistical averages but rather to stress certain elements common to most cases of the given phenomenon. In using the word "ideal," Max Weber refers to the world of ideas (German: Gedankenbilder, "mental images") and not to perfection; these "ideal types" are idea-constructs that help put the seeming chaos of social reality in order.

Weber wrote: "An ideal type is formed by the one-sided accentuation of one or more points of view and by the synthesis of a great many diffuse, discrete, more or less present and occasionally absent concrete individual phenomena, which are arranged according to those onesidedly emphasized viewpoints into a unified analytical construct..."[2] Therefore, ideal types are a form of perfect representation. It is a useful tool for comparative sociology in analyzing social or economic phenomena, having advantages over a very general, abstract idea and a specific historical example. It can be used to analyze both a general, suprahistorical phenomenon such as capitalism or historically unique occurrences such as in Weber's Protestant Ethics analysis.

To try to understand a particular phenomenon, one must not only describe the actions of its participants but "interpret" them by classifying behavior as belonging to some prior "ideal type." Weber described four "ideal types" of behavior: zweckrational (goal-rationality), wertrational (value-rationality), affektual (emotional-rationality), and traditional (custom, unconscious habit).

Weber states that an "ideal type" never seeks to claim its validity in terms of a reproduction of or correspondence with social reality. Its validity can be ascertained only in terms of adequacy, which is too conveniently ignored by the proponents of positivism. This does not mean, however, that objectivity, limited as it is, can be gained by "weighing the various evaluations against one another and making a 'statesman-like' compromise among them", which is often proposed as a solution by those propounding methodological perspectivism. Such a practice, which Weber calls "syncretism", is not only impossible but also unethical, for it avoids "the practical duty to stand up for our own ideals" [Weber 1904/1949, p. 58[3]].

Scholarly reception edit

It is commonly argued that idealization plays a key role in the methodology of other social sciences, especially of economics.[4]

For example, homo economicus is the result of a consistent abstraction-idealization process. One of the fundamental axioms of neoclassical economics, the law of diminishing marginal utility, followed from the highlighting of Weber-Fechner's law in psychophysics, which highlights that the growth of subjectively perceived intensity of recurrent stimuli with the same physical intensity is always decreasing. The same law emerges in the law of diminishing marginal returns. Homo economicus as presupposed by Neoclassicals is an idealized, abstract creature that can be characterized by an intention to exchange and whose only task is to take economic decisions. For homo economicus, there is no time or social and natural environment, he is ageless, he has no whims, and his decisions are not biased by occasional effects from the (social) environment. So, his behaviour only reflects the objective and consistently prevailing economic laws established by formal rationality. After all, human (and social) sciences, similarly to natural sciences, i.e. abstracting from everything subjective, constrained themselves to phrase only objective truths.

However, the conceptualizing routine of neoclassical economics differs from the genuine approach of Max Weber in that Neoclassicals focused exactly on finding and deducing economic laws (in accordance with the efforts of natural sciences), while the ideal-types of the Weberian sociology only supported the interpretative understanding of past events with no references to causal laws. Even if the method and the strategy of creating ideal-typical concepts are common, these are two opposing scientific programs eventually. Weber offers an excellent description and a user's guide to the technique of abstraction and idealization that also directly applies to the conceptualizing strategy of mainstream economics that is on a completely different track with its law-seeking efforts.[5]

Criticism edit

Critics of ideal type include proponents of the normal type theory. Some sociologists argue that ideal type tends to focus on extreme phenomena and overlook the connections between them, and that it is difficult to show how the types and their elements fit into a theory of a total social system.

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Weber, Max (1949). Max Weber on the methodology of the social sciences. Translated by Shils, Edward A.; Finch, Henry A. (First ed.). Glencoe, Illinois: Free Press. p. 42-44, 90-107,110,114,125.
  2. ^ Shils, Edward A. and Finch, Henry A. (trans. and ed.), The methodology of the social sciences (1903–17), New York: Free Press, 1997, p. 90.
  3. ^ Max Weber, Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy
  4. ^ Mäki, Uskali (2009). "Realistic Realism about Unrealistic Models". The Oxford Handbook of Philosophy of Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 68–98. ISBN 9780195189254.
  5. ^ Galbács, Peter (2015). "Methodological Principles and an Epistemological Introduction". The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics. A Positive Critique. Contributions to Economics. Heidelberg/New York/Dordrecht/London: Springer. pp. 1–52. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-17578-2. ISBN 978-3-319-17578-2.

Further reading edit

  • Pawel Zaleski, "Ideal Types in Max Weber's Sociology of Religion: Some Theoretical Inspirations for a Study of the Religious Field", Polish Sociological Review 3(171), 2010.

External links edit

  • "Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy". pp. Max Weber (5.2: Ideal Type). Retrieved 2009-06-08.
  • Science, Values and Politics in Max Weber's Methodology. Ashgate Publishing, Ltd. 2007. ISBN 978-0-7546-4529-0.
  • Johnson, Allan G. (2000). "Ideal Type". The Blackwell Dictionary of Sociology. Wiley-Blackwell. ISBN 978-0-631-21681-0.
  • . pp. The Ideal Type. Archived from the original on April 29, 2009. Retrieved 2009-06-08.

ideal, type, german, idealtypus, also, known, pure, type, typological, term, most, closely, associated, with, sociologist, weber, 1864, 1920, weber, conduct, social, science, depends, upon, construction, abstract, hypothetical, concepts, ideal, type, therefore. Ideal type German Idealtypus also known as pure type is a typological term most closely associated with the sociologist Max Weber 1864 1920 1 For Weber the conduct of social science depends upon the construction of abstract hypothetical concepts The ideal type is therefore a subjective element in social theory and research and one of the subjective elements distinguishing sociology from natural science Contents 1 Meaning 2 Scholarly reception 3 Criticism 4 See also 5 References 6 Further reading 7 External linksMeaning editAn ideal type is formed from characteristics and elements of the given phenomena but it is not meant to correspond to all of the characteristics of any one particular case It is not meant to refer to perfect things moral ideals nor to statistical averages but rather to stress certain elements common to most cases of the given phenomenon In using the word ideal Max Weber refers to the world of ideas German Gedankenbilder mental images and not to perfection these ideal types are idea constructs that help put the seeming chaos of social reality in order Weber wrote An ideal type is formed by the one sided accentuation of one or more points of view and by the synthesis of a great many diffuse discrete more or less present and occasionally absent concrete individual phenomena which are arranged according to those onesidedly emphasized viewpoints into a unified analytical construct 2 Therefore ideal types are a form of perfect representation It is a useful tool for comparative sociology in analyzing social or economic phenomena having advantages over a very general abstract idea and a specific historical example It can be used to analyze both a general suprahistorical phenomenon such as capitalism or historically unique occurrences such as in Weber s Protestant Ethics analysis To try to understand a particular phenomenon one must not only describe the actions of its participants but interpret them by classifying behavior as belonging to some prior ideal type Weber described four ideal types of behavior zweckrational goal rationality wertrational value rationality affektual emotional rationality and traditional custom unconscious habit Weber states that an ideal type never seeks to claim its validity in terms of a reproduction of or correspondence with social reality Its validity can be ascertained only in terms of adequacy which is too conveniently ignored by the proponents of positivism This does not mean however that objectivity limited as it is can be gained by weighing the various evaluations against one another and making a statesman like compromise among them which is often proposed as a solution by those propounding methodological perspectivism Such a practice which Weber calls syncretism is not only impossible but also unethical for it avoids the practical duty to stand up for our own ideals Weber 1904 1949 p 58 3 Scholarly reception editIt is commonly argued that idealization plays a key role in the methodology of other social sciences especially of economics 4 For example homo economicus is the result of a consistent abstraction idealization process One of the fundamental axioms of neoclassical economics the law of diminishing marginal utility followed from the highlighting of Weber Fechner s law in psychophysics which highlights that the growth of subjectively perceived intensity of recurrent stimuli with the same physical intensity is always decreasing The same law emerges in the law of diminishing marginal returns Homo economicus as presupposed by Neoclassicals is an idealized abstract creature that can be characterized by an intention to exchange and whose only task is to take economic decisions For homo economicus there is no time or social and natural environment he is ageless he has no whims and his decisions are not biased by occasional effects from the social environment So his behaviour only reflects the objective and consistently prevailing economic laws established by formal rationality After all human and social sciences similarly to natural sciences i e abstracting from everything subjective constrained themselves to phrase only objective truths However the conceptualizing routine of neoclassical economics differs from the genuine approach of Max Weber in that Neoclassicals focused exactly on finding and deducing economic laws in accordance with the efforts of natural sciences while the ideal types of the Weberian sociology only supported the interpretative understanding of past events with no references to causal laws Even if the method and the strategy of creating ideal typical concepts are common these are two opposing scientific programs eventually Weber offers an excellent description and a user s guide to the technique of abstraction and idealization that also directly applies to the conceptualizing strategy of mainstream economics that is on a completely different track with its law seeking efforts 5 Criticism editCritics of ideal type include proponents of the normal type theory Some sociologists argue that ideal type tends to focus on extreme phenomena and overlook the connections between them and that it is difficult to show how the types and their elements fit into a theory of a total social system See also edit nbsp Society portal Antipositivism Morphological analysis problem solving Reification fallacy Social action Structure and agency The Three Types of Legitimate Rule Tripartite classification of authority VerstehenReferences edit Weber Max 1949 Max Weber on the methodology of the social sciences Translated by Shils Edward A Finch Henry A First ed Glencoe Illinois Free Press p 42 44 90 107 110 114 125 Shils Edward A and Finch Henry A trans and ed The methodology of the social sciences 1903 17 New York Free Press 1997 p 90 Max Weber Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Maki Uskali 2009 Realistic Realism about Unrealistic Models The Oxford Handbook of Philosophy of Economics Oxford Oxford University Press pp 68 98 ISBN 9780195189254 Galbacs Peter 2015 Methodological Principles and an Epistemological Introduction The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics A Positive Critique Contributions to Economics Heidelberg New York Dordrecht London Springer pp 1 52 doi 10 1007 978 3 319 17578 2 ISBN 978 3 319 17578 2 Further reading editPawel Zaleski Ideal Types in Max Weber s Sociology of Religion Some Theoretical Inspirations for a Study of the Religious Field Polish Sociological Review 3 171 2010 External links edit Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy pp Max Weber 5 2 Ideal Type Retrieved 2009 06 08 Science Values and Politics in Max Weber s Methodology Ashgate Publishing Ltd 2007 ISBN 978 0 7546 4529 0 Johnson Allan G 2000 Ideal Type The Blackwell Dictionary of Sociology Wiley Blackwell ISBN 978 0 631 21681 0 Website of Trinity International University pp The Ideal Type Archived from the original on April 29 2009 Retrieved 2009 06 08 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Ideal type amp oldid 1206993394, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.