fbpx
Wikipedia

Historical materialism

Historical materialism is Karl Marx's theory of history. Marx locates historical change in the rise of class societies and the way humans labor together to make their livelihoods.[1]

For Marx and his lifetime collaborator, Friedrich Engels, historical materialism is the "view of the course of history which seeks the ultimate cause and the great moving power of all important historic events in the economic development of society, in the changes in the modes of production and exchange, in the consequent division of society into distinct classes, and in the struggles of these classes against one another."[2]

Although Marx never brought together a formal or comprehensive description of historical materialism in one published work, his key ideas are woven into a variety of works from the 1840s onward.[3] Since Marx's time, the theory has been modified and expanded. It now has many Marxist and non-Marxist variants.

Enlightenment views of history Edit

Marx's view of history is shaped by his engagement with the intellectual and philosophical movement known as the Age of Enlightenment and the profound scientific, political, economic and social transformations that took place in Britain and other parts of Europe in the 16th, 17th and 18th centuries.[4][5][6]

The 'spirit of liberty' Edit

Enlightenment thinkers responded to the worldly transformations by promoting individual liberty and attacking religious dogmas and the divine right of kings.[7] A swathe of thinkers including Hobbes (1588–1679), Montesquieu (1689–1755), Voltaire (1694–1778), Smith (1723–1790), Turgot (1727–1781) and Condorcet (1743–1794) detached from the ecclesiastical interpretation of the world and offered new scientific studies of human nature, history, economics and society. Some philosophers, for example, Vico (1668–1744), Herder (1744–1803) and Hegel (1770–1831), sought to discover an organizing theme, meaning, or direction in human history.[8] For many Enlightenment philosophers, the power of ideas became the mainspring for understanding historical change and the rise and fall of civilizations. History was the gradual advance of the 'spirit of liberty' or the growth of nationalism or democracy, rationality and law.[9] This view of history remains popular to this day.[10][11][12][13]

'Great man' history Edit

Marx rejected the enlightenment view that ideas alone were the driving force in society or that the underlying cause for the rise and fall of kingdoms, empires and states, was due to the actions of people at the top of society: kings, queens, emperors, generals, or religious leaders. The 'great man' and occasionally 'great woman' view of historical change was popularized by the 19th century Scottish philosopher Thomas Carlyle (1795–1881) who wrote 'the history of the world is nothing but the biography of great men'.[14] According to Marx, this conception of history amounted to nothing more than a collection of 'high-sounding dramas of princes and states'.[15]

Materialist conception of history Edit

Inspired by Enlightenment thinkers, especially Condorcet, the utopian socialist Henri de Saint-Simon (1760–1825) formulated his own materialist interpretation of history, similar to those later used in Marxism, analyzing historical epochs based on their level of technology and organization and dividing them between eras of slavery, serfdom, and finally wage labor.[16][17] According to the socialist leader Jean Jaurès, the French writer Antoine Barnave was the first to develop the theory that economic forces were the driving factors in history.[18]

Hegel's contribution to Marx's theory of history Edit

While studying at the University of Berlin, Marx encountered the philosophy of Hegel (1770–1831) which had a profound and lasting influence on his thinking. One of Hegel's key critiques of enlightenment philosophy was that while thinkers were often able to describe what made societies from one epoch to the next different, they struggled to account for why they changed.[19]

Hegel and historicism Edit

Classical economists presented a model of civil society based on a universal and unchanging human nature.[20] Hegel challenged this view and argued that human nature as well as the formulations of art, science and the institutions of the state and its codes, laws and norms were all defined by their history and could only be understood by examining their historical development.[21][22] Hegel historicised philosophical thought and saw it as an expression of a specific culture rather than an eternal truth. Thus: 'Philosophy is its own age comprehended in thought'.[23]

World spirit Edit

In each society, humans were 'free by nature' but constrained by their 'brutal recklessness of passion' and 'untamed natural impulses' which led to injustice and violence.[24] It was only through wider society and the state, which was expressed in each historical epoch, by a 'spirit of the age', collective consciousness or Geist, that 'Freedom' could be realized.[25] For Hegel, history was the working through of a process where humans become ever more conscious of the rational principles that govern social development.

Dialectics of change Edit

Hegel's dialectical method presents the world as a complex totality. This means that all parts of society, for example, science, art, law, labor and the economy, the state and the family etc., are all interconnected and mutually influential and therefore cannot be properly understood or analysed in isolation.[26] Institutions and bodies are never static – they undergo a constant process of modification and development over time. According to Hegel, at any particular point in time, society is an amalgam of contesting forces – some promoting stability and others striving for change. It is not just external factors that bring about transformation but internal contradictions. The unceasing drive of this dynamic is played out by real people struggling to achieve their aims. The outcome is that ideas, institutions and bodies of society are reconfigured into new forms expressing new characteristics. At certain decisive moments in history, during periods of great conflict, the actions of 'great historical men' can align with the 'spirit of the age' to bring about a fundamental advance in freedom.[27]

Algebra of revolution Edit

 
A caricature drawn by Engels of Max Stirner, whose 1844 work The Unique and its Property prompted Marx and Engels to theorize a scientific approach to the study of history which they first laid out in The German Ideology (1845) along with a lengthy rebuttal of Stirner

The implication of Hegel's philosophy was incendiary – every social order, no matter how powerful and secure will eventually wither away. These ideas were inspirational to Marx and the Young Hegelians who sought to develop a radical critique of the Prussian authorities and lambasted the failure to introduce constitutional change or reform social institutions.[28] However, Hegel's contention, in Marx's view, that ideas or the 'spirit of the age' drive history was mistaken. 'Hegel', wrote Marx, 'fell into the illusion of conceiving the real as the product of thought …'[29] On the contrary, Marx contended, the engine of history was to be found in a materialist understanding of society - the productive process and the way humans labored to meet their needs. Marx and Engels first set out their materialist conception of history in The German Ideology, written in 1845. The book is a lengthy polemic against Marx and Engels' fellow Young Hegelians and contemporaries Ludwig Feuerbach, Bruno Bauer, and Max Stirner.

Historical materialism Edit

In the Marxian view, human history is like a river. From any given vantage point, a river looks much the same day after day. But actually it is constantly flowing and changing, crumbling its banks, widening and deepening its channel. The water seen one day is never the same as that seen the next. Some of it is constantly being evaporated and drawn up, to return as rain. From year to year these changes may be scarcely perceptible. But one day, when the banks are thoroughly weakened and the rains long and heavy, the river floods, bursts its banks, and may take a new course. This represents the dialectical part of Marx's famous theory of dialectical (or historical) materialism.

— Hubert Kay, Life, 1948[30]

The production of life Edit

Marx underpins his theory of history by drawing attention to a fundamental reality of human existence – the necessity to labor to ensure our physical survival. Only once this is guaranteed may mankind pursue politics, science, art, religion, etc.[31] Human labor, therefore, forms the materialist basis for society and is at the heart of Marx's account of history. Thus, throughout history, in all societies and in all modes of production, from the earliest paleolithic hunter gatherers, through to feudal societies and to modern capitalist economies, there is an 'everlasting Nature-imposed condition of human existence' which compels humans to join together socially to produce their means of subsistence.[32] The first historical act, Marx writes in the German Ideology, is the production of means to satisfy our material needs: This is a: 'fundamental condition of all history, which today, as thousands of years ago, must daily and hourly be fulfilled merely in order to sustain human life'.[33]

Forces and relations of production Edit

Marx identified two mutually interdependent structures to describe how humans interacted with nature, and in the process of producing their subsistence, created ever more complex rules and institutions to manage their interaction between each other and with the environment. These are the forces and relations of production.

Forces of production Edit

The forces of production are everything that humans use to make the things that society needs. They include human labor and the raw materials, land, tools, instruments and knowledge required for production. The flint sharpened spears and harpoons developed by early humans in the late Palaeolithic Age are all forces of production. Over time, the forces of production tend to develop and expand as new skills, knowledge and technology (for example wooden scratch plows then heavier iron plows) are put to use to meet human needs.[34] From one generation to the next, technical skills, evolving traditions of practice and mechanical innovations are reproduced and disseminated. Today, the productive forces available to humanity are vast and continue to develop and expand.

Relations of production Edit

Marx then extended this premise by asserting the importance of the fact that, in order to carry out production and exchange, people have to enter into very definite social relations, or more specifically, "relations of production". However, production does not get carried out in the abstract, or by entering into arbitrary or random relations chosen at will, but instead are determined by the development of the existing forces of production.[35]

The relations of production are determined by the level and character of these productive forces present at any given time in history. In all societies, human beings collectively work on nature but, especially in class societies, do not do the same work. In such societies, there is a division of labor in which people not only carry out different kinds of labor but occupy different social positions on the basis of those differences. The most important such division is that between manual and intellectual labor whereby one class produces a given society's wealth while another is able to monopolize control of the means of production. In this way, both govern that society and live off of the wealth generated by the laboring classes.[36]

Base and superstructure Edit

Marx identified society's relations of production (arising on the basis of given productive forces) as the economic base of society. He also explained that on the foundation of the economic base, there arise certain political institutions, laws, customs, culture, etc., and ideas, ways of thinking, morality, etc. These constitute the political/ideological "superstructure" of society. This superstructure not only has its origin in the economic base, but its features also ultimately correspond to the character and development of that economic base, i.e. the way people organize society, its relations of production, and its mode of production.[37] G.A. Cohen argues in Karl Marx's Theory of History: A Defence that a society's superstructure stabilizes or entrenches its economic structure, but that the economic base is primary and the superstructure secondary. That said, it is precisely because the superstructure strongly affects the base that the base selects that superstructure. As Charles Taylor puts it, "These two directions of influence are so far from being rivals that they are actually complementary. The functional explanation requires that the secondary factor tend to have a causal effect on the primary, for this dispositional fact is the key feature of the explanation."[38] It is because the influences in the two directions are not symmetrical that it makes sense to speak of primary and secondary factors, even where one is giving a non-reductionist, "holistic" account of social interaction.

To summarize, history develops in accordance with the following observations:

 
Scenes from the tomb of Nakht depicting an agricultural division of labour in Ancient Egypt, painted in the 15th century BC
  1. Social progress is driven by progress in the material, productive forces a society has at its disposal (technology, labour, capital goods and so on).
  2. Humans are inevitably involved in productive relations (roughly speaking, economic relationships or institutions), which constitute our most decisive social relations. These relations progress with the development of the productive forces. They are largely determined by the division of labor, which in turn tends to determine social class.
  3. Relations of production are both determined by the means and forces of production and set the conditions of their development. For example, capitalism tends to increase the rate at which the forces develop and stresses the accumulation of capital.
  4. The relations of production define the mode of production, e.g. the capitalist mode of production is characterized by the polarization of society into capitalists and workers.
  5. The superstructure—the cultural and institutional features of a society, its ideological materials—is ultimately an expression of the mode of production on which the society is founded.
  6. Every type of state is a powerful institution of the ruling class; the state is an instrument which one class uses to secure its rule and enforce its preferred relations of production and its exploitation onto society.[citation needed]
  7. State power is usually only transferred from one class to another by social and political upheaval.[citation needed]
  8. When a given relation of production no longer supports further progress in the productive forces, either further progress is strangled, or 'revolution' must occur.[citation needed]
  9. The actual historical process is not predetermined but depends on class struggle, especially the elevation of class consciousness and organization of the working class.[citation needed]

Key implications in the study and understanding of history Edit

Many writers note that historical materialism represented a revolution in human thought, and a break from previous ways of understanding the underlying basis of change within various human societies. As Marx puts it, "a coherence arises in human history"[39] because each generation inherits the productive forces developed previously and in turn further develops them before passing them on to the next generation. Further, this coherence increasingly involves more of humanity the more the productive forces develop and expand to bind people together in production and exchange.

This understanding counters the notion that human history is simply a series of accidents, either without any underlying cause or caused by supernatural beings or forces exerting their will on society. Historical materialism posits that history is made as a result of struggle between different social classes rooted in the underlying economic base. According to G. A. Cohen, author of Karl Marx's Theory of History: A Defence, the level of development of society's productive forces (i.e., society's technological powers, including tools, machinery, raw materials, and labour power) determines society's economic structure, in the sense that it selects a structure of economic relations that tends best to facilitate further technological growth. In historical explanation, the overall primacy of the productive forces can be understood in terms of two key theses:

(a) The productive forces tend to develop throughout history (the Development Thesis).
(b) The nature of the production relations of a society is explained by the level of development of its productive forces (the Primacy Thesis proper).[40]

In saying that productive forces have a universal tendency to develop, Cohen's reading of Marx is not claiming that productive forces always develop or that they never decline. Their development may be temporarily blocked, but because human beings have a rational interest in developing their capacities to control their interactions with external nature in order to satisfy their wants, the historical tendency is strongly toward further development of these capacities.

Broadly, the importance of the study of history lies in the ability of history to explain the present. John Bellamy Foster asserts that historical materialism is important in explaining history from a scientific perspective, by following the scientific method, as opposed to belief-system theories like creationism and intelligent design, which do not base their beliefs on verifiable facts and hypotheses.[41]

Modes of production Edit

The main modes of production that Marx identified include primitive communism, slave society, feudalism, capitalism and communism. In each of these stages of production, people interact with nature and production in different ways. Any surplus from that production was distributed differently. Marx propounded that humanity first began living in primitive communist societies, then came the ancient societies such as Rome and Greece which were based on a ruling class of citizens and a class of slaves, then feudalism which was based on nobles and serfs, and then capitalism which is based on the capitalist class (bourgeoisie) and the working class (proletariat). In his idea of a future communist society, Marx explains that classes would no longer exist, and therefore the exploitation of one class by another is abolished.

 
Ancient cave painting showing the primitive communist mode of production

Primitive communism Edit

To historical materialists, hunter-gatherer societies, also known as primitive communist societies, were structured so that economic forces and political forces were one and the same. Societies generally did not have a state, property, money, nor social classes. Due to their limited means of production (hunting and gathering) each individual was only able to produce enough to sustain themselves, thus without any surplus there is nothing to exploit. A slave at this point would only be an extra mouth to feed. This inherently makes them communist in social relations although primitive in productive forces.

Ancient mode of production Edit

 
Ancient Egyptian art depicting the ancient mode of production

Slave societies, the ancient mode of production, were formed as productive forces advanced, namely due to agriculture and its ensuing abundance which led to the abandonment of nomadic society. Slave societies were marked by their use of slavery and minor private property; production for use was the primary form of production. Slave society is considered by historical materialists to be the first-class society formed of citizens and slaves. Surplus from agriculture was distributed to the citizens, who exploited the slaves that worked the fields.[42]

 
Medieval art depicting the feudal mode of production

Feudal mode of production Edit

The feudal mode of production emerged from slave society (e.g. in Europe after the collapse of the Roman Empire), coinciding with the further advance of productive forces. Feudal society's class relations were marked by an entrenched nobility and serfdom. Simple commodity production existed in the form of artisans and merchants. This merchant class would grow in size and eventually form the bourgeoisie. However, production was still largely for use.

Capitalist mode of production Edit

The capitalist mode of production materialized when the rising bourgeois class grew large enough to institute a shift in the productive forces. The bourgeoisie's primary form of production was in the form of commodities, i.e. they produced with the purpose of exchanging their products. As this commodity production grew, the old feudal systems came into conflict with the new capitalist ones; feudalism was then eschewed as capitalism emerged. The bourgeoisie's influence expanded until commodity production became fully generalized:

 
Factory workers in the capitalist mode of production

The feudal system of industry, in which industrial production was monopolised by closed guilds, now no longer sufficed for the growing wants of the new markets. The manufacturing system took its place. The guild-masters were pushed on one side by the manufacturing middle class; division of labour between the different corporate guilds vanished in the face of division of labour in each single workshop.[43]

With the rise of the bourgeoisie came the concepts of nation-states and nationalism. Marx argued that capitalism completely separated the economic and political forces. Marx took the state to be a sign of this separation—it existed to manage the massive conflicts of interest which arose between the proletariat and bourgeoisie in capitalist society. Marx observed that nations arose at the time of the appearance of capitalism on the basis of community of economic life, territory, language, certain features of psychology, and traditions of everyday life and culture. In The Communist Manifesto Marx and Engels explained that the coming into existence of nation-states was the result of class struggle, specifically of the capitalist class's attempts to overthrow the institutions of the former ruling class. Prior to capitalism, nations were not the primary political form.[44] Vladimir Lenin shared a similar view on nation-states.[45] There were two opposite tendencies in the development of nations under capitalism. One of them was expressed in the activation of national life and national movements against the oppressors. The other was expressed in the expansion of links among nations, the breaking down of barriers between them, the establishment of a unified economy and of a world market (globalization); the first is a characteristic of lower-stage capitalism and the second a more advanced form, furthering the unity of the international proletariat.[46] Alongside this development was the forced removal of the serfdom from the countryside to the city, forming a new proletarian class. This caused the countryside to become reliant on large cities. Subsequently, the new capitalist mode of production also began expanding into other societies that had not yet developed a capitalist system (e.g. the scramble for Africa). The Communist Manifesto stated:

National differences and antagonism between peoples are daily more and more vanishing, owing to the development of the bourgeoisie, to freedom of commerce, to the world market, to uniformity in the mode of production and in the conditions of life corresponding thereto.

The supremacy of the proletariat will cause them to vanish still faster. United action, of the leading civilised countries at least, is one of the first conditions for the emancipation of the proletariat.

In proportion as the exploitation of one individual by another will also be put an end to, the exploitation of one nation by another will also be put an end to. In proportion as the antagonism between classes within the nation vanishes, the hostility of one nation to another will come to an end.[47]

Under capitalism, the bourgeoisie and proletariat become the two primary classes. Class struggle between these two classes was now prevalent. With the emergence of capitalism, productive forces were now able to flourish, causing the industrial revolution in Europe. Despite this, however, the productive forces eventually reach a point where they can no longer expand, causing the same collapse that occurred at the end of feudalism:

Modern bourgeois society, with its relations of production, of exchange and of property, a society that has conjured up such gigantic means of production and of exchange, is like the sorcerer who is no longer able to control the powers of the nether world whom he has called up by his spells. [...] The productive forces at the disposal of society no longer tend to further the development of the conditions of bourgeois property; on the contrary, they have become too powerful for these conditions, by which they are fettered, and so soon as they overcome these fetters, they bring disorder into the whole of bourgeois society, endanger the existence of bourgeois property.[43]

Communist mode of production Edit

Lower-stage of communism Edit

The bourgeoisie, as Marx stated in The Communist Manifesto, has "forged the weapons that bring death to itself; it has also called into existence the men who are to wield those weapons—the modern working class—the proletarians."[43] Historical materialists henceforth believe that the modern proletariat are the new revolutionary class in relation to the bourgeoisie, in the same way that the bourgeoisie was the revolutionary class in relation to the nobility under feudalism.[48] The proletariat, then, must seize power as the new revolutionary class in a dictatorship of the proletariat.

Between capitalist and communist society there lies the period of the revolutionary transformation of the one into the other. Corresponding to this is also a political transition period in which the state can be nothing but the revolutionary dictatorship of the proletariat.[48]

Marx also describes a communist society developed alongside the proletarian dictatorship:

Within the co-operative society based on common ownership of the means of production, the producers do not exchange their products; just as little does the labor employed on the products appear here as the value of these products, as a material quality possessed by them, since now, in contrast to capitalist society, individual labor no longer exists in an indirect fashion but directly as a component part of total labor. The phrase "proceeds of labor", objectionable also today on account of its ambiguity, thus loses all meaning. What we have to deal with here is a communist society, not as it has developed on its own foundations, but, on the contrary, just as it emerges from capitalist society; which is thus in every respect, economically, morally, and intellectually, still stamped with the birthmarks of the old society from whose womb it emerges. Accordingly, the individual producer receives back from society—after the deductions have been made—exactly what he gives to it. What he has given to it is his individual quantum of labor. For example, the social working day consists of the sum of the individual hours of work; the individual labor time of the individual producer is the part of the social working day contributed by him, his share in it. He receives a certificate from society that he has furnished such-and-such an amount of labor (after deducting his labor for the common funds); and with this certificate, he draws from the social stock of means of consumption as much as the same amount of labor cost. The same amount of labor which he has given to society in one form, he receives back in another.[49]

This lower-stage of communist society is, according to Marx, analogous to the lower-stage of capitalist society, i.e. the transition from feudalism to capitalism, in that both societies are "stamped with the birthmarks of the old society from whose womb it emerges." The emphasis on the idea that modes of production do not exist in isolation but rather are materialized from the previous existence is a core idea in historical materialism.

There is considerable debate among communists regarding the nature of this society. Some such as Joseph Stalin, Fidel Castro, and other Marxist-Leninists believe that the lower-stage of communism constitutes its own mode of production, which they call socialist rather than communist. Marxist-Leninists believe that this society may still maintain the concepts of property, money, and commodity production.[50]

Higher-stage of communism Edit

To Marx, the higher-stage of communist society is a free association of producers which has successfully negated all remnants of capitalism, notably the concepts of states, nationality, sexism, families, alienation, social classes, money, property, commodities, the bourgeoisie, the proletariat, division of labor, cities and countryside, class struggle, religion, ideology, and markets. It is the negation of capitalism.[51][52]

Marx made the following comments on the higher-phase of communist society:

In a higher phase of communist society, after the enslaving subordination of the individual to the division of labor, and therewith also the antithesis between mental and physical labor, has vanished; after labor has become not only a means of life but life's prime want; after the productive forces have also increased with the all-around development of the individual, and all the springs of co-operative wealth flow more abundantly—only then can the narrow horizon of bourgeois right be crossed in its entirety and society inscribe on its banners: From each according to his ability, to each according to his needs![49]

Warnings against misuse Edit

In the 1872 Preface to the French edition of Das Kapital Vol. 1, Marx emphasized that "[t]here is no royal road to science, and only those who do not dread the fatiguing climb of its steep paths have a chance of gaining its luminous summits."[53] Reaching a scientific understanding required conscientious, painstaking research, instead of philosophical speculation and unwarranted, sweeping generalizations. Having abandoned abstract philosophical speculation in his youth, Marx himself showed great reluctance during the rest of his life about offering any generalities or universal truths about human existence or human history.

Marx took care to indicate that he was only proposing a guideline to historical research (Leitfaden or Auffassung), and was not providing any substantive "theory of history" or "grand philosophy of history", let alone a "master-key to history". Engels expressed irritation with dilettante academics who sought to knock up their skimpy historical knowledge as quickly as possible into some grand theoretical system that would explain "everything" about history. He opined that historical materialism and the theory of modes of production were being used as an excuse for not studying history.[54]

The first explicit and systematic summary of the materialist interpretation of history to be published was Engels's book Herr Eugen Dühring's Revolution in Science, written with Marx's approval and guidance, and often referred to as the Anti-Dühring. One of the polemics was to ridicule the easy "world schematism" of philosophers, who invented the latest wisdom from behind their writing desks. Towards the end of his life, in 1877, Marx wrote a letter to the editor of the Russian paper Otetchestvennye Zapisky, which significantly contained the following disclaimer:

Russia... will not succeed without having first transformed a good part of her peasants into proletarians; and after that, once taken to the bosom of the capitalist regime, she will experience its pitiless laws like other profane peoples. That is all. But that is not enough for my critic. He feels obliged to metamorphose my historical sketch of the genesis of capitalism in Western Europe into an historico-philosophic theory of the marche generale imposed by fate upon every people, whatever the historic circumstances in which it finds itself, in order that it may ultimately arrive at the form of economy which will ensure, together with the greatest expansion of the productive powers of social labour, the most complete development of man. But I beg his pardon. (He is both honouring and shaming me too much.)[55]

Marx goes on to illustrate how the same factors can in different historical contexts produce very different results so that quick and easy generalizations are not really possible. To indicate how seriously Marx took research when he died, his estate contained several cubic metres of Russian statistical publications (it was, as the old Marx observed, in Russia that his ideas gained the most influence).

Insofar as Marx and Engels regarded historical processes as law-governed processes, the possible future directions of historical development were to a great extent limited and conditioned by what happened before. Retrospectively, historical processes could be understood to have happened by necessity in certain ways and not others, and to some extent at least, the most likely variants of the future could be specified on the basis of careful study of the known facts.

Towards the end of his life, Engels commented several times about the abuse of historical materialism.

In a letter to Conrad Schmidt dated 5 August 1890, he stated:

And if this man [i.e., Paul Barth] has not yet discovered that while the material mode of existence is the primum agens [first agent] this does not preclude the ideological spheres from reacting upon it in their turn, though with a secondary effect, he cannot possibly have understood the subject he is writing about. [...] The materialist conception of history has a lot of [dangerous friends] nowadays, to whom it serves as an excuse for not studying history. Just as Marx used to say, commenting on the French "Marxists" of the late 70s: "All I know is that I am not a Marxist." [...] In general, the word "materialistic" serves many of the younger writers in Germany as a mere phrase with which anything and everything is labelled without further study, that is, they stick to this label and then consider the question disposed of. But our conception of history is above all a guide to study, not a lever for construction after the manner of the Hegelian. All history must be studied afresh, and the conditions of existence of the different formations of society must be examined individually before the attempt is made to deduce them from the political, civil law, aesthetic, philosophic, religious, etc., views corresponding to them. Up to now but little has been done here because only a few people have got down to it seriously. In this field we can utilize heaps of help, it is immensely big, and anyone who will work seriously can achieve much and distinguish himself. But instead of this too many of the younger Germans simply make use of the phrase historical materialism (and everything can be turned into a phrase) only in order to get their own relatively scanty historical knowledge—for economic history is still in its swaddling clothes!—constructed into a neat system as quickly as possible, and they then deem themselves something very tremendous. And after that, a Barth can come along and attack the thing itself, which in his circle has indeed been degraded to a mere phrase.[56]

Finally, in a letter to Franz Mehring dated 14 July 1893, Engels stated:

[T]here is only one other point lacking, which, however, Marx and I always failed to stress enough in our writings and in regard to which we are all equally guilty. That is to say, we all laid, and were bound to lay, the main emphasis, in the first place, on the derivation of political, juridical and other ideological notions, and of actions arising through the medium of these notions, from basic economic facts. But in so doing we neglected the formal side—the ways and means by which these notions, etc., come about—for the sake of the content. This has given our adversaries a welcome opportunity for misunderstandings, of which Paul Barth is a striking example.[57]

Criticism Edit

Philosopher of science Karl Popper, in The Poverty of Historicism and Conjectures and Refutations, critiqued such claims of the explanatory power or valid application of historical materialism by arguing that it could explain or explain away any fact brought before it, making it unfalsifiable and thus pseudoscientific. Similar arguments were brought by Leszek Kołakowski in Main Currents of Marxism.[58]

In his 1940 essay Theses on the Philosophy of History, scholar Walter Benjamin compares historical materialism to the Turk, an 18th-century device which was promoted as a mechanized automaton which could defeat skilled chess players but actually concealed a human who controlled the machine. Benjamin suggested that, despite Marx's claims to scientific objectivity, historical materialism was actually quasi-religious. Like the Turk, wrote Benjamin, "[t]he puppet called 'historical materialism' is always supposed to win. It can do this with no further ado against any opponent, so long as it employs the services of theology, which as everyone knows is small and ugly and must be kept out of sight." Benjamin's friend and colleague Gershom Scholem would argue that Benjamin's critique of historical materialism was so definitive that, as Mark Lilla would write, "nothing remains of historical materialism [...] but the term itself".[59]

Neven Sesardic argues that historical materialism is a highly exaggerated claim. Sesardic observes that it was clear to many Marxists that the social, cultural and ideological superstructure of society was not under the control of the base but had at least some degree of autonomy. It was also clear that phenomena of the superstructure could determine part of the economic base. Thus, Sesardic argues that Marxists moved from a claim of the dominance of the economic base to a scenario in which the base sometimes determines the superstructure and the superstructure sometimes determines the base, which Sesardic argues destroys their whole position. This is because this new claim, according to Sesardic, is so innocuous that no-one would deny it, whereas the old claim was very radical, as it posited the dominance of economics. Sesardic argues that Marxists should have abandoned historical materialism when its strong version became untenable, but instead they chose to water it down until it became a trivial claim.[60]

Continued development Edit

In a foreword to his essay Ludwig Feuerbach and the End of Classical German Philosophy (1886), three years after Marx's death, Engels claimed confidently that "the Marxist world outlook has found representatives far beyond the boundaries of Germany and Europe and in all the literary languages of the world."[61] Indeed, in the years after Marx and Engels' deaths, "historical materialism" was identified as a distinct philosophical doctrine and was subsequently elaborated upon and systematized by Orthodox Marxist and Marxist–Leninist thinkers such as Eduard Bernstein, Karl Kautsky, Georgi Plekhanov and Nikolai Bukharin. This occurred despite the fact that many of Marx's earlier works on historical materialism, including The German Ideology, remained unpublished until the 1930s.

The substantivist ethnographic approach of economic anthropologist and sociologist Karl Polanyi bears similarities to historical materialism. Polanyi distinguishes between the formal definition of economics as the logic of rational choice between limited resources and a substantive definition of economics as the way humans make their living from their natural and social environment.[62] In The Great Transformation (1944), Polanyi asserts that both the formal and substantive definitions of economics hold true under capitalism, but that the formal definition falls short when analyzing the economic behavior of pre-industrial societies, whose behavior was more often governed by redistribution and reciprocity.[63] While Polanyi was influenced by Marx, he rejected the primacy of economic determinism in shaping the course of history, arguing that rather than being a realm unto itself, an economy is embedded within its contemporary social institutions, such as the state in the case of the market economy.[64]

Perhaps the most notable recent exploration of historical materialism is G. A. Cohen's Karl Marx's Theory of History: A Defence,[65] which inaugurated the school of Analytical Marxism. Cohen advances a sophisticated technological-determinist interpretation of Marx "in which history is, fundamentally, the growth of human productive power, and forms of society rise and fall according as they enable or impede that growth."[66]

Jürgen Habermas believes historical materialism "needs revision in many respects", especially because it has ignored the significance of communicative action.[67]

Göran Therborn has argued that the method of historical materialism should be applied to historical materialism as an intellectual tradition, and to the history of Marxism itself.[68]

In the early 1980s, Paul Hirst and Barry Hindess elaborated a structural Marxist interpretation of historical materialism.[69]

Regulation theory, especially in the work of Michel Aglietta draws extensively on historical materialism.[70]

Following the collapse of the Soviet Union in the early 1990s, much of Marxist thought was seen as anachronistic. A major effort to "renew" historical materialism comes from historian Ellen Meiksins Wood, who wrote in 1995 that, "There is something off about the assumption that the collapse of Communism represents a terminal crisis for Marxism. One might think, among other things, that in a period of capitalist triumphalism there is more scope than ever for the pursuit of Marxism's principal project, the critique of capitalism."[71]

[T]he kernel of historical materialism was an insistence on the historicity and specificity of capitalism, and denial that its laws were the universal laws of history...this focus on the specificity of capitalism, as a moment with historical origins as well as an end, with a systemic logic specific to it, encourages a truly historical sense lacking in classical political economy and conventional ideas of progress, and this had potentially fruitful implications for the historical study of other modes of production too.[71]

Referencing Marx's Theses on Feuerbach, Wood argued for historical materialism to be understood as "a theoretical foundation for interpreting the world in order to change it."

See also Edit

References Edit

Citations Edit

  1. ^ Baur, Michael (January 2017). "Marx on Historical Materialism". ResearchGate: 1–2.
  2. ^ Jayapalan, N. (2001). Comprehensive History of Political Thought. Atlantic Publisher & Distributors. p. 248.
  3. ^ Berlin, Isaiah (2013). Karl Marx with a foreword by Alan Ryan (5th ed.). Princeton University Press. p. 112. ISBN 9780691156507. JSTOR j.ctt46n3qx.13.
  4. ^ Hankins, Thomas (1985). Science and the Enlightenment. Cambridge University Press. pp. 1–16. ISBN 0-521-28619-0.
  5. ^ Brenner, Robert (2003). Merchants and Revolution Commercial Change, Political Conflict, and London's Overseas Traders, 1550-1653. Verso Books. ISBN 978-1859843338.
  6. ^ Davidson, Neil (6 April 2006). "Enlightenment and anti-capitalism". International Socialism (110).
  7. ^ Porter, Roy (2001). Enlightenment. Penguin Books. pp. 12–14. ISBN 9780140250282.
  8. ^ Philosophy of History. 2020. {{cite book}}: |website= ignored (help)
  9. ^ Hume, David (12 August 2016). History of England from the Invasion of Julius Caesar to the Revolution in 1688. Hansebooks GmbH. ISBN 978-3-7428-3234-4. OCLC 1129763042.
  10. ^ Durrant, Will (2002). The Greatest Minds and Ideas of All Time. Simon & Schuster. ISBN 9780743235532.
  11. ^ Carnwath, Ally; Halfhead, Lucy; Toms, Katie (2008). "Blue sky thinking: 10 ideas that changed the course of history". The Guardian.
  12. ^ Arp, Robert (2018). 1001 Ideas That Changed the Way We Think. Octopus. ISBN 9781788400886.
  13. ^ Hart, Diane (1987). Spirit of Liberty: An American History. Addison-Wesley. ISBN 978-0201209235.
  14. ^ MacCulloch, Diarmaid. "Is There Still Value in 'Great Man' History?". History Today. Retrieved 20 May 2022. Published in History Today Volume 69 Issue 9 September 2019
  15. ^ Marx, Karl. "Feuerbach. Opposition of the Materialist and Idealist Outlook: B. The Illusion of the Epoch". The German Ideology – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  16. ^ Kołakowski, Leszek (2005). Main Currents of Marxism: The Founders, the Golden Age, the Breakdown. W. W. Norton & Company. pp. 154–156. ISBN 978-0-393-06054-6 – via Google Books.
  17. ^ Robinson, Cedric J. (18 January 2019). An Anthropology of Marxism (2 ed.). University of North Carolina Press. p. 9. ISBN 978-1-4696-4992-4. OCLC 1083096631 – via Google Books.
  18. ^ Guthrie, William Buck (1907). Socialism Before the French Revolution: A History. Macmillan. pp. 306–307 – via Google Books.
  19. ^ Berlin, Isaiah (2014). Freedom and Its Betrayal: Six Enemies of Human Liberty (Updated ed.). Princeton University Press. p. 90. ISBN 9780691157573.
  20. ^ Choi, Young (1990). "Smith's View On Human Nature: A Problem In The Interpretation of "The Wealth Of Nations" And "The Theory Of Moral Sentiments"" (PDF). Review of Social Economy. 48 (3): 288–302. doi:10.1080/00346769000000025. JSTOR 29769511.
  21. ^ Pradella, Lucia (October 2014). "Hegel, Imperialism, and Universal History". Science & Society. 78 (4): 428. doi:10.1521/siso.2014.78.4.426. JSTOR 24583660.
  22. ^ Fox-Williams, Jack (2020). "Hegel's Understanding of History". Philosophy Now (140).
  23. ^ Winter, Max (2016). "Philosophy is its own time apprehended in thoughts": Hegel on Time and Concept". Revista Portuguesa de Filosofia. 72 (2/3): 339–349. doi:10.17990/RPF/2016_72_2_0339. JSTOR 44028676.
  24. ^ Hegel, Georg Wilhelm Friedrich (2001). The Philosophy of History. Canada: Batochhe Books. pp. 55–565. ISBN 978-0486437552.
  25. ^ "What did Hegel mean by Geist?". Social Theory Applied. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  26. ^ Rees, John (1998). The Algebra of Revolution The Dialectic and the Classical Marxist Tradition. London: Routledge. pp. 45–47. ISBN 978-0415198776.
  27. ^ Hegel, Georg Wilhelm Friedrich (2001). The Philosophy of History. Canada: Batoche Books. p. 44.
  28. ^ Berlin, Isaiah (2013). Karl Marx: Thoroughly Revised Fifth Edition. Princeton University Press. pp. 57–61. ISBN 978-0691156507.
  29. ^ Marx, Karl. Grundrisse – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  30. ^ Kay, Hubert (18 October 1948). "Karl Marx". Life. p. 66.
  31. ^ Engels, Friedrich (2022). "Frederick Engels' Speech at the Grave of Karl Marx". Marxists Internet Archive.
  32. ^ Marx, Karl (1867). "7: The Labour-Process and the Process of Producing Surplus-Value". Capital. Vol. One: The Production of Absolute Surplus-Value – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  33. ^ Marx, Karl (1845). "1: Feuerbach. Opposition of the Materialist and Idealist Outlook". The German Ideology – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  34. ^ Lin, Justin Yifu (1995). "The Needham Puzzle: Why the Industrial Revolution Did Not Originate in China" (PDF). Economic Development and Cultural Change. 43 (2): 269–292. doi:10.1086/452150. JSTOR 1154499. S2CID 35637470.The case of China shows that a trend is just a trend. In 1400 China possessed many of the ingredients for dynamic technological growth and expansion of political and economic power. They had printing presses, gunpowder, were familiar with distillation, used vaccination for small pox and explored the coastal states of Africa. The reasons for these advances not being capitalised on is explored by the Lin article.
  35. ^ Marx, Karl (1999). "48". Capital: Critique of Political Economy. Vol. 3. Retrieved 5 December 2018 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  36. ^ Callinicos, Alex (2011). The Revolutionary Ideas of Karl Marx. Chicago: Haymarket Books. p. 99.
  37. ^ "Karl Marx (Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy)". Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. The Metaphysics Research Lab, Center for the Study of Language and Information (CSLI), Stanford University. Retrieved 6 September 2018.
  38. ^ Charles Taylor, "Critical Notice", Canadian Journal of Philosophy 10 (1980), p. 330.
  39. ^ Marx & Engels 1968, p. 660.
  40. ^ Cohen, p. 134.
  41. ^ Foster & Clark 2008.
  42. ^ Harman, C. A People's History of the World. Bookmarks.
  43. ^ a b c Marx, Karl (1848). The Communist Manifesto. London. Retrieved 12 March 2019.
  44. ^ Dixon, Norm. "Marx, Engels and Lenin on the National Question". Links International Journal of Socialist Renewal. Retrieved 21 April 2018.
  45. ^ "V.I. Lenin. O natsional'nom voprose i natsional'noy politike" В.И. Ленин. О национальном вопросе и национальной политике [V.I. Lenin. On the national question and national policy] (in Russian). Retrieved 21 April 2018.
  46. ^ Lenin n.d.
  47. ^ Marx, Karl (1848). "Chapter I. Bourgeois and Proletarians". The Communist Manifesto. London. Retrieved 4 April 2019 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  48. ^ a b Marx, Karl. Critique of the Gotha Programme. Retrieved 12 March 2019 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  49. ^ a b Marx, Karl. Critique of the Gotha Programme. Retrieved 12 March 2019 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  50. ^ Stalin, Joseph. Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR. Retrieved 12 March 2019 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  51. ^ Marx, Karl (1845). "Idealism and Materialism". The German Ideology. Retrieved 12 March 2019.
  52. ^ Marx, Karl (1848). "Chapter II. Proletarians and Communists". The Communist Manifesto. London. Retrieved 12 March 2019 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  53. ^ Marx, Karl (1999). "Chapter 48. The Trinity Formula". Capital: Critique of Political Economy. Vol. 1. Retrieved 5 December 2018 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  54. ^ Engels, cited approvingly by E. P. Thompson in 'The peculiarities of the English,' Socialist Register, 1965.
  55. ^ "Letter from Marx to Editor of the Otecestvenniye Zapisky". Retrieved 10 November 2018 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  56. ^ "Letters: Marx–Engels Correspondence 1890". Retrieved 7 December 2011 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  57. ^ "Letters: Marx–Engels Correspondence 1893". Retrieved 7 December 2011 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  58. ^ Kołakowski 1978; Popper 1957.
  59. ^ Lilla, Mark (25 May 1995). "The Riddle of Walter Benjamin". The New York Review of Books.
  60. ^ Sesardić, Neven (1985). Marxian Utopia. Centre for Research into Communist Economies. pp. 14–15. ISBN 0948027010.
  61. ^ Engels 1946.
  62. ^ Polanyi, K. (1944). The Great Transformation. New York. pp. 44–49.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  63. ^ ibid. p. 41.
  64. ^ Hann, Chris (2018). "Economic Anthropology". Economic Anthropology. The International Encyclopedia of Anthropology. John Wiley & Sons. pp. 1–16. doi:10.1002/9781118924396.wbiea2194. ISBN 9780470657225.
  65. ^ Cohen 2000.
  66. ^ Cohen, G. A. (1978). Karl Marx's Theory of History. Princeton: Princeton University Press. p. x.
  67. ^ Habermas, Jürgen (Autumn 1975). "Toward a Reconstruction of Historical Materialism" (PDF). Theory and Society. 2 (3): 287–300. doi:10.1007/BF00212739. S2CID 113407026. Retrieved 5 December 2018.
  68. ^ Therborn, Göran (1980). Science, Class and Society: on the formation of Sociology and Historical Materialism. London: Verso Books.
  69. ^ Hirst, Paul; Hindess, Barry (1975). Pre-Capitalist Modes of Production. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
  70. ^ Jessop, Bob (2001). "Capitalism, the Regulation Approach, and Critical Realism". In Brown, A.; Fleetwood, S.; Roberts, J. (eds.). Critical Realism and Marxism. London: Routledge.
  71. ^ a b "Introduction". Democracy against Capitalism. Cambridge University Press. 1995. pp. 1–16. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511558344.001. ISBN 978-0-521-47096-4.

Sources Edit

Further reading Edit

  • Acton, H. B. The Illusion of the Epoch.
    Critical account which focusses on incoherencies in the thought of Marx, Engels and Lenin.
  • Anderson, Perry (1974). Lineages of the Absolutist State.
  • Aronowitz, Stanley (1981). The Crisis in Historical Materialism.
    American criticism of orthodox Marxism and argument for a more radical version of historical materialism that sticks closer to Marx by changing itself to keep up with changes in the historical situation.
  • Blackledge, Paul (2006). Reflections on the Marxist Theory of History.
  • Blackledge, Paul (2018). Vidal, Matt; Smith, Tony; Rotta, Tomás; Prew, Paul (eds.). "Historical Materialism" in Oxford Handbook on Karl Marx. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780190695545.001.0001. ISBN 9780190695545. {{cite book}}: |journal= ignored (help)
  • Boudin, Louis B. (1907). The Theoretical System of Karl Marx. Chicago: Charles H. Kerr Publishing Co.
    Contains an early defence of the materialist conception of history against its critics of the day.
  • Childe, V. Gordon. Man Makes Himself.
    Free interpretation of Marx's idea.
  • Cohen, Gerald. Karl Marx's Theory of History: A Defence.
    Influential analytical Marxist interpretation.
  • Draper, Hal. Karl Marx's Theory of Revolution.
    Captures the full subtlety of Marx's thought, but at length in four volumes.
  • Fleischer, Helmut. Marxism and History.
    Good reply to false interpretations of Marx's view of history.
  • Gandler, Stefan (2015). Critical Marxism in Mexico: Adolfo Sánchez Vázquez and Bolívar Echeverría. Historical Materialism Book Series. Vol. 87. Leiden, Netherlands: Brill Academic Press. ISBN 978-90-04-28468-5. ISSN 1570-1522.
  • Giddens, Anthony (1981). A Contemporary Critique of Historical Materialism.
  • Graham, Loren R. Science Philosophy and Human Behavior in the Soviet Union.
    Sympathetically critical of dialectical materialism.
  • Habermas, Jürgen (January 1976). Communication and the Evolution of Society.
    Argues historical materialism must be revised to include communicative action.
  • Harman, Chris. A People's History of the World.
    Marxist view of history according to a leader of the International Socialist Tendency.
  • Harper, J. (1942). "Materialism and Historical Materialism". New Essays. 6 (2). Retrieved 21 April 2018 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  • Holt, Justin P. (2014). The Social Thought of Karl Marx. Los Angeles: SAGE Publications. doi:10.4135/9781483349381. ISBN 978-1-4129-9784-3.
    Provides an introductory chapter on historical materialism.
  • Jakubowski, Franz. Ideology and Superstructure.
    Attempts to provide an alternative to schematic interpretations of historical materialism.
  • Jordan, Z. A. (1967). "The Origins of Dialectical Materialism". The Evolution of Dialectical Materialism: A Philosophical and Sociological Analysis. London: Macmillan. Retrieved 21 April 2018 – via Marx Myths & Legends.
    Good survey.
  • Mandel, Ernest. Introduction to Marxism.
    Emphasizes understanding the roots of class society and the state.
  •  ———  (1986). The Place of Marxism in History. International Institute for Research and Education. Retrieved 21 April 2018 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
    Modelled on Lenin's "Three components of Marxism"[citation needed] but with a section on the reception and diffusion of Marxism in the world.
  • Mao Zedong. Four Essays on Philosophy.
    Standard Maoist reading of Marx's materialism.
  • Marx, Karl (1848). Manifesto of the Communist Party.
  •  ———  (1869). The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Napoleon.
  •  ———  (1887). Engels, Friedrich (ed.). Capital: Critique of Political Economy. Volume I: The Process of Production of Capital. Translated by Moore, Samuel; Aveling, Edward. Moscow: Progress Publishers.
  •  ———  (1895). The Class Struggles in France, 1848–1850.
  •  ———  (1932). Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844.
  •  ———  (1932). The German Ideology.
  •  ———  (1956). Engels, Friedrich (ed.). Capital: Critique of Political Economy. Volume II: The Process of Circulation of Capital. Translated by Lasker, I. (2nd ed.). Moscow: Progress Publishers.
  •  ———  (1959). Capital: Critique of Political Economy. Volume III: The Process of Capitalist Production as a Whole.
  •  ———  (1964). Hobsbawm, E. J. (ed.). Pre-Capitalist Economic Formations. Translated by Cohen, Jack. London: Lawrence & Wishart.
  •  ———  (1969). "Theses on Feuerbach". Marx/Engels Selected Works. Moscow: Progress Publishers. pp. 13–15.
  • Mehring, Franz (1975). On Historical Materialism. Translated by Archer, Bob. London: New Park Press. Retrieved 21 April 2018 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
    Classic statement by a contemporary and friend of Marx & Engels.
  • Novack, George (2002). Understanding History: Marxist Essays. Chippendale, New South Wales: Resistance Books. ISBN 978-1-876646-23-3. Retrieved 21 April 2018 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
    Trotskyist interpretations of problems of history.
  • Nowak, Leszek. Property and Power: Towards a Non-Marxian Historical Materialism.
    Attempts to develop a post-Stalinist interpretation of Marx's project.
  • Rees, John. The Algebra of Revolution.
    Classical Marxist account of the philosophy of Marx, Engels, Lenin, Lukacs, and Trotsky.
  • Rigby, S. H. (1998). Marxism and History: A Critical Introduction (2nd ed.). Manchester: Manchester University Press. ISBN 978-0-7190-5612-3.
  • Shaw, William H. Marx's Theory of History.
    Provides a short survey.
  • Spirkin, Alexander (1990). Fundamentals of Philosophy. Translated by Syrovatkin, Sergei. Moscow: Progress Publishers. ISBN 978-5-01-002582-3. Retrieved 15 January 2011.
  • Stalin, Joseph. Dialectical and Historical Materialism.
    Classic statement of Stalinist doctrine.
  • Suchting, Wal. Marx: An Introduction.
    Includes a good short introduction.
  • "The Materialist Conception of History". Education Bulletin. No. 1. 1979. Retrieved 21 April 2018.
  • Therborn, Göran. Science, Class and Society.
    Critical survey of the relationship between sociology and historical materialism.
  • Thompson, E. P. The Poverty of Theory.
    Polemic which ridicules theorists of history who do not actually study history.
  • Wetter, Gustav A. Dialectical Materialism: a Historical and Systematic Survey of Philosophy in the Soviet Union.
    Alternative survey.
  • Witt-Hansen, Johan. Historical Materialism: The Method, The Theories.
    Sees historical materialism as a methodology and Das Kapital as an application of the method.
  • Wood, Allen W. (2004). Karl Marx. Arguments of the Philosophers (2nd ed.). Abingdon, England: Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-31697-2.
    Delves into misinterpretations of Marx including the substitution of "Historical materialism" by Lenin.

historical, materialism, journal, historical, materialism, journal, this, article, multiple, issues, please, help, improve, discuss, these, issues, talk, page, learn, when, remove, these, template, messages, this, article, contains, many, overly, lengthy, quot. For the journal see Historical Materialism journal This article has multiple issues Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page Learn how and when to remove these template messages This article contains too many or overly lengthy quotations for an encyclopedic entry Please help improve the article by presenting facts as a neutrally worded summary with appropriate citations Consider transferring direct quotations to Wikiquote or for entire works to Wikisource December 2018 This article s tone or style may not reflect the encyclopedic tone used on Wikipedia See Wikipedia s guide to writing better articles for suggestions March 2022 Learn how and when to remove this template message This article possibly contains original research Please improve it by verifying the claims made and adding inline citations Statements consisting only of original research should be removed March 2022 Learn how and when to remove this template message Learn how and when to remove this template message Historical materialism is Karl Marx s theory of history Marx locates historical change in the rise of class societies and the way humans labor together to make their livelihoods 1 For Marx and his lifetime collaborator Friedrich Engels historical materialism is the view of the course of history which seeks the ultimate cause and the great moving power of all important historic events in the economic development of society in the changes in the modes of production and exchange in the consequent division of society into distinct classes and in the struggles of these classes against one another 2 Although Marx never brought together a formal or comprehensive description of historical materialism in one published work his key ideas are woven into a variety of works from the 1840s onward 3 Since Marx s time the theory has been modified and expanded It now has many Marxist and non Marxist variants Contents 1 Enlightenment views of history 1 1 The spirit of liberty 1 2 Great man history 1 3 Materialist conception of history 2 Hegel s contribution to Marx s theory of history 2 1 Hegel and historicism 2 2 World spirit 2 3 Dialectics of change 2 4 Algebra of revolution 3 Historical materialism 3 1 The production of life 3 2 Forces and relations of production 3 2 1 Forces of production 3 2 2 Relations of production 3 3 Base and superstructure 4 Key implications in the study and understanding of history 5 Modes of production 5 1 Primitive communism 5 2 Ancient mode of production 5 3 Feudal mode of production 5 4 Capitalist mode of production 5 5 Communist mode of production 5 5 1 Lower stage of communism 5 5 2 Higher stage of communism 6 Warnings against misuse 7 Criticism 8 Continued development 9 See also 10 References 10 1 Citations 10 2 Sources 11 Further readingEnlightenment views of history EditMarx s view of history is shaped by his engagement with the intellectual and philosophical movement known as the Age of Enlightenment and the profound scientific political economic and social transformations that took place in Britain and other parts of Europe in the 16th 17th and 18th centuries 4 5 6 The spirit of liberty Edit Enlightenment thinkers responded to the worldly transformations by promoting individual liberty and attacking religious dogmas and the divine right of kings 7 A swathe of thinkers including Hobbes 1588 1679 Montesquieu 1689 1755 Voltaire 1694 1778 Smith 1723 1790 Turgot 1727 1781 and Condorcet 1743 1794 detached from the ecclesiastical interpretation of the world and offered new scientific studies of human nature history economics and society Some philosophers for example Vico 1668 1744 Herder 1744 1803 and Hegel 1770 1831 sought to discover an organizing theme meaning or direction in human history 8 For many Enlightenment philosophers the power of ideas became the mainspring for understanding historical change and the rise and fall of civilizations History was the gradual advance of the spirit of liberty or the growth of nationalism or democracy rationality and law 9 This view of history remains popular to this day 10 11 12 13 Great man history Edit Marx rejected the enlightenment view that ideas alone were the driving force in society or that the underlying cause for the rise and fall of kingdoms empires and states was due to the actions of people at the top of society kings queens emperors generals or religious leaders The great man and occasionally great woman view of historical change was popularized by the 19th century Scottish philosopher Thomas Carlyle 1795 1881 who wrote the history of the world is nothing but the biography of great men 14 According to Marx this conception of history amounted to nothing more than a collection of high sounding dramas of princes and states 15 Materialist conception of history Edit Inspired by Enlightenment thinkers especially Condorcet the utopian socialist Henri de Saint Simon 1760 1825 formulated his own materialist interpretation of history similar to those later used in Marxism analyzing historical epochs based on their level of technology and organization and dividing them between eras of slavery serfdom and finally wage labor 16 17 According to the socialist leader Jean Jaures the French writer Antoine Barnave was the first to develop the theory that economic forces were the driving factors in history 18 Hegel s contribution to Marx s theory of history EditWhile studying at the University of Berlin Marx encountered the philosophy of Hegel 1770 1831 which had a profound and lasting influence on his thinking One of Hegel s key critiques of enlightenment philosophy was that while thinkers were often able to describe what made societies from one epoch to the next different they struggled to account for why they changed 19 Hegel and historicism Edit Classical economists presented a model of civil society based on a universal and unchanging human nature 20 Hegel challenged this view and argued that human nature as well as the formulations of art science and the institutions of the state and its codes laws and norms were all defined by their history and could only be understood by examining their historical development 21 22 Hegel historicised philosophical thought and saw it as an expression of a specific culture rather than an eternal truth Thus Philosophy is its own age comprehended in thought 23 World spirit Edit In each society humans were free by nature but constrained by their brutal recklessness of passion and untamed natural impulses which led to injustice and violence 24 It was only through wider society and the state which was expressed in each historical epoch by a spirit of the age collective consciousness or Geist that Freedom could be realized 25 For Hegel history was the working through of a process where humans become ever more conscious of the rational principles that govern social development Dialectics of change Edit Main article Hegelian Dialectic Hegel s dialectical method presents the world as a complex totality This means that all parts of society for example science art law labor and the economy the state and the family etc are all interconnected and mutually influential and therefore cannot be properly understood or analysed in isolation 26 Institutions and bodies are never static they undergo a constant process of modification and development over time According to Hegel at any particular point in time society is an amalgam of contesting forces some promoting stability and others striving for change It is not just external factors that bring about transformation but internal contradictions The unceasing drive of this dynamic is played out by real people struggling to achieve their aims The outcome is that ideas institutions and bodies of society are reconfigured into new forms expressing new characteristics At certain decisive moments in history during periods of great conflict the actions of great historical men can align with the spirit of the age to bring about a fundamental advance in freedom 27 Algebra of revolution Edit nbsp A caricature drawn by Engels of Max Stirner whose 1844 work The Unique and its Property prompted Marx and Engels to theorize a scientific approach to the study of history which they first laid out in The German Ideology 1845 along with a lengthy rebuttal of StirnerThe implication of Hegel s philosophy was incendiary every social order no matter how powerful and secure will eventually wither away These ideas were inspirational to Marx and the Young Hegelians who sought to develop a radical critique of the Prussian authorities and lambasted the failure to introduce constitutional change or reform social institutions 28 However Hegel s contention in Marx s view that ideas or the spirit of the age drive history was mistaken Hegel wrote Marx fell into the illusion of conceiving the real as the product of thought 29 On the contrary Marx contended the engine of history was to be found in a materialist understanding of society the productive process and the way humans labored to meet their needs Marx and Engels first set out their materialist conception of history in The German Ideology written in 1845 The book is a lengthy polemic against Marx and Engels fellow Young Hegelians and contemporaries Ludwig Feuerbach Bruno Bauer and Max Stirner Historical materialism EditIn the Marxian view human history is like a river From any given vantage point a river looks much the same day after day But actually it is constantly flowing and changing crumbling its banks widening and deepening its channel The water seen one day is never the same as that seen the next Some of it is constantly being evaporated and drawn up to return as rain From year to year these changes may be scarcely perceptible But one day when the banks are thoroughly weakened and the rains long and heavy the river floods bursts its banks and may take a new course This represents the dialectical part of Marx s famous theory of dialectical or historical materialism Hubert Kay Life 1948 30 The production of life Edit Marx underpins his theory of history by drawing attention to a fundamental reality of human existence the necessity to labor to ensure our physical survival Only once this is guaranteed may mankind pursue politics science art religion etc 31 Human labor therefore forms the materialist basis for society and is at the heart of Marx s account of history Thus throughout history in all societies and in all modes of production from the earliest paleolithic hunter gatherers through to feudal societies and to modern capitalist economies there is an everlasting Nature imposed condition of human existence which compels humans to join together socially to produce their means of subsistence 32 The first historical act Marx writes in the German Ideology is the production of means to satisfy our material needs This is a fundamental condition of all history which today as thousands of years ago must daily and hourly be fulfilled merely in order to sustain human life 33 Forces and relations of production Edit Marx identified two mutually interdependent structures to describe how humans interacted with nature and in the process of producing their subsistence created ever more complex rules and institutions to manage their interaction between each other and with the environment These are the forces and relations of production Forces of production Edit The forces of production are everything that humans use to make the things that society needs They include human labor and the raw materials land tools instruments and knowledge required for production The flint sharpened spears and harpoons developed by early humans in the late Palaeolithic Age are all forces of production Over time the forces of production tend to develop and expand as new skills knowledge and technology for example wooden scratch plows then heavier iron plows are put to use to meet human needs 34 From one generation to the next technical skills evolving traditions of practice and mechanical innovations are reproduced and disseminated Today the productive forces available to humanity are vast and continue to develop and expand Relations of production Edit Marx then extended this premise by asserting the importance of the fact that in order to carry out production and exchange people have to enter into very definite social relations or more specifically relations of production However production does not get carried out in the abstract or by entering into arbitrary or random relations chosen at will but instead are determined by the development of the existing forces of production 35 The relations of production are determined by the level and character of these productive forces present at any given time in history In all societies human beings collectively work on nature but especially in class societies do not do the same work In such societies there is a division of labor in which people not only carry out different kinds of labor but occupy different social positions on the basis of those differences The most important such division is that between manual and intellectual labor whereby one class produces a given society s wealth while another is able to monopolize control of the means of production In this way both govern that society and live off of the wealth generated by the laboring classes 36 Base and superstructure Edit Marx identified society s relations of production arising on the basis of given productive forces as the economic base of society He also explained that on the foundation of the economic base there arise certain political institutions laws customs culture etc and ideas ways of thinking morality etc These constitute the political ideological superstructure of society This superstructure not only has its origin in the economic base but its features also ultimately correspond to the character and development of that economic base i e the way people organize society its relations of production and its mode of production 37 G A Cohen argues in Karl Marx s Theory of History A Defence that a society s superstructure stabilizes or entrenches its economic structure but that the economic base is primary and the superstructure secondary That said it is precisely because the superstructure strongly affects the base that the base selects that superstructure As Charles Taylor puts it These two directions of influence are so far from being rivals that they are actually complementary The functional explanation requires that the secondary factor tend to have a causal effect on the primary for this dispositional fact is the key feature of the explanation 38 It is because the influences in the two directions are not symmetrical that it makes sense to speak of primary and secondary factors even where one is giving a non reductionist holistic account of social interaction To summarize history develops in accordance with the following observations nbsp Scenes from the tomb of Nakht depicting an agricultural division of labour in Ancient Egypt painted in the 15th century BCSocial progress is driven by progress in the material productive forces a society has at its disposal technology labour capital goods and so on Humans are inevitably involved in productive relations roughly speaking economic relationships or institutions which constitute our most decisive social relations These relations progress with the development of the productive forces They are largely determined by the division of labor which in turn tends to determine social class Relations of production are both determined by the means and forces of production and set the conditions of their development For example capitalism tends to increase the rate at which the forces develop and stresses the accumulation of capital The relations of production define the mode of production e g the capitalist mode of production is characterized by the polarization of society into capitalists and workers The superstructure the cultural and institutional features of a society its ideological materials is ultimately an expression of the mode of production on which the society is founded Every type of state is a powerful institution of the ruling class the state is an instrument which one class uses to secure its rule and enforce its preferred relations of production and its exploitation onto society citation needed State power is usually only transferred from one class to another by social and political upheaval citation needed When a given relation of production no longer supports further progress in the productive forces either further progress is strangled or revolution must occur citation needed The actual historical process is not predetermined but depends on class struggle especially the elevation of class consciousness and organization of the working class citation needed Key implications in the study and understanding of history EditMany writers note that historical materialism represented a revolution in human thought and a break from previous ways of understanding the underlying basis of change within various human societies As Marx puts it a coherence arises in human history 39 because each generation inherits the productive forces developed previously and in turn further develops them before passing them on to the next generation Further this coherence increasingly involves more of humanity the more the productive forces develop and expand to bind people together in production and exchange This understanding counters the notion that human history is simply a series of accidents either without any underlying cause or caused by supernatural beings or forces exerting their will on society Historical materialism posits that history is made as a result of struggle between different social classes rooted in the underlying economic base According to G A Cohen author of Karl Marx s Theory of History A Defence the level of development of society s productive forces i e society s technological powers including tools machinery raw materials and labour power determines society s economic structure in the sense that it selects a structure of economic relations that tends best to facilitate further technological growth In historical explanation the overall primacy of the productive forces can be understood in terms of two key theses a The productive forces tend to develop throughout history the Development Thesis b The nature of the production relations of a society is explained by the level of development of its productive forces the Primacy Thesis proper 40 In saying that productive forces have a universal tendency to develop Cohen s reading of Marx is not claiming that productive forces always develop or that they never decline Their development may be temporarily blocked but because human beings have a rational interest in developing their capacities to control their interactions with external nature in order to satisfy their wants the historical tendency is strongly toward further development of these capacities Broadly the importance of the study of history lies in the ability of history to explain the present John Bellamy Foster asserts that historical materialism is important in explaining history from a scientific perspective by following the scientific method as opposed to belief system theories like creationism and intelligent design which do not base their beliefs on verifiable facts and hypotheses 41 Modes of production EditThe main modes of production that Marx identified include primitive communism slave society feudalism capitalism and communism In each of these stages of production people interact with nature and production in different ways Any surplus from that production was distributed differently Marx propounded that humanity first began living in primitive communist societies then came the ancient societies such as Rome and Greece which were based on a ruling class of citizens and a class of slaves then feudalism which was based on nobles and serfs and then capitalism which is based on the capitalist class bourgeoisie and the working class proletariat In his idea of a future communist society Marx explains that classes would no longer exist and therefore the exploitation of one class by another is abolished nbsp Ancient cave painting showing the primitive communist mode of productionPrimitive communism Edit To historical materialists hunter gatherer societies also known as primitive communist societies were structured so that economic forces and political forces were one and the same Societies generally did not have a state property money nor social classes Due to their limited means of production hunting and gathering each individual was only able to produce enough to sustain themselves thus without any surplus there is nothing to exploit A slave at this point would only be an extra mouth to feed This inherently makes them communist in social relations although primitive in productive forces Ancient mode of production Edit nbsp Ancient Egyptian art depicting the ancient mode of productionSlave societies the ancient mode of production were formed as productive forces advanced namely due to agriculture and its ensuing abundance which led to the abandonment of nomadic society Slave societies were marked by their use of slavery and minor private property production for use was the primary form of production Slave society is considered by historical materialists to be the first class society formed of citizens and slaves Surplus from agriculture was distributed to the citizens who exploited the slaves that worked the fields 42 nbsp Medieval art depicting the feudal mode of productionFeudal mode of production Edit The feudal mode of production emerged from slave society e g in Europe after the collapse of the Roman Empire coinciding with the further advance of productive forces Feudal society s class relations were marked by an entrenched nobility and serfdom Simple commodity production existed in the form of artisans and merchants This merchant class would grow in size and eventually form the bourgeoisie However production was still largely for use Capitalist mode of production Edit The capitalist mode of production materialized when the rising bourgeois class grew large enough to institute a shift in the productive forces The bourgeoisie s primary form of production was in the form of commodities i e they produced with the purpose of exchanging their products As this commodity production grew the old feudal systems came into conflict with the new capitalist ones feudalism was then eschewed as capitalism emerged The bourgeoisie s influence expanded until commodity production became fully generalized nbsp Factory workers in the capitalist mode of productionThe feudal system of industry in which industrial production was monopolised by closed guilds now no longer sufficed for the growing wants of the new markets The manufacturing system took its place The guild masters were pushed on one side by the manufacturing middle class division of labour between the different corporate guilds vanished in the face of division of labour in each single workshop 43 With the rise of the bourgeoisie came the concepts of nation states and nationalism Marx argued that capitalism completely separated the economic and political forces Marx took the state to be a sign of this separation it existed to manage the massive conflicts of interest which arose between the proletariat and bourgeoisie in capitalist society Marx observed that nations arose at the time of the appearance of capitalism on the basis of community of economic life territory language certain features of psychology and traditions of everyday life and culture In The Communist Manifesto Marx and Engels explained that the coming into existence of nation states was the result of class struggle specifically of the capitalist class s attempts to overthrow the institutions of the former ruling class Prior to capitalism nations were not the primary political form 44 Vladimir Lenin shared a similar view on nation states 45 There were two opposite tendencies in the development of nations under capitalism One of them was expressed in the activation of national life and national movements against the oppressors The other was expressed in the expansion of links among nations the breaking down of barriers between them the establishment of a unified economy and of a world market globalization the first is a characteristic of lower stage capitalism and the second a more advanced form furthering the unity of the international proletariat 46 Alongside this development was the forced removal of the serfdom from the countryside to the city forming a new proletarian class This caused the countryside to become reliant on large cities Subsequently the new capitalist mode of production also began expanding into other societies that had not yet developed a capitalist system e g the scramble for Africa The Communist Manifesto stated National differences and antagonism between peoples are daily more and more vanishing owing to the development of the bourgeoisie to freedom of commerce to the world market to uniformity in the mode of production and in the conditions of life corresponding thereto The supremacy of the proletariat will cause them to vanish still faster United action of the leading civilised countries at least is one of the first conditions for the emancipation of the proletariat In proportion as the exploitation of one individual by another will also be put an end to the exploitation of one nation by another will also be put an end to In proportion as the antagonism between classes within the nation vanishes the hostility of one nation to another will come to an end 47 Under capitalism the bourgeoisie and proletariat become the two primary classes Class struggle between these two classes was now prevalent With the emergence of capitalism productive forces were now able to flourish causing the industrial revolution in Europe Despite this however the productive forces eventually reach a point where they can no longer expand causing the same collapse that occurred at the end of feudalism Modern bourgeois society with its relations of production of exchange and of property a society that has conjured up such gigantic means of production and of exchange is like the sorcerer who is no longer able to control the powers of the nether world whom he has called up by his spells The productive forces at the disposal of society no longer tend to further the development of the conditions of bourgeois property on the contrary they have become too powerful for these conditions by which they are fettered and so soon as they overcome these fetters they bring disorder into the whole of bourgeois society endanger the existence of bourgeois property 43 Communist mode of production Edit Lower stage of communism Edit The bourgeoisie as Marx stated in The Communist Manifesto has forged the weapons that bring death to itself it has also called into existence the men who are to wield those weapons the modern working class the proletarians 43 Historical materialists henceforth believe that the modern proletariat are the new revolutionary class in relation to the bourgeoisie in the same way that the bourgeoisie was the revolutionary class in relation to the nobility under feudalism 48 The proletariat then must seize power as the new revolutionary class in a dictatorship of the proletariat Between capitalist and communist society there lies the period of the revolutionary transformation of the one into the other Corresponding to this is also a political transition period in which the state can be nothing but the revolutionary dictatorship of the proletariat 48 Marx also describes a communist society developed alongside the proletarian dictatorship Within the co operative society based on common ownership of the means of production the producers do not exchange their products just as little does the labor employed on the products appear here as the value of these products as a material quality possessed by them since now in contrast to capitalist society individual labor no longer exists in an indirect fashion but directly as a component part of total labor The phrase proceeds of labor objectionable also today on account of its ambiguity thus loses all meaning What we have to deal with here is a communist society not as it has developed on its own foundations but on the contrary just as it emerges from capitalist society which is thus in every respect economically morally and intellectually still stamped with the birthmarks of the old society from whose womb it emerges Accordingly the individual producer receives back from society after the deductions have been made exactly what he gives to it What he has given to it is his individual quantum of labor For example the social working day consists of the sum of the individual hours of work the individual labor time of the individual producer is the part of the social working day contributed by him his share in it He receives a certificate from society that he has furnished such and such an amount of labor after deducting his labor for the common funds and with this certificate he draws from the social stock of means of consumption as much as the same amount of labor cost The same amount of labor which he has given to society in one form he receives back in another 49 This lower stage of communist society is according to Marx analogous to the lower stage of capitalist society i e the transition from feudalism to capitalism in that both societies are stamped with the birthmarks of the old society from whose womb it emerges The emphasis on the idea that modes of production do not exist in isolation but rather are materialized from the previous existence is a core idea in historical materialism There is considerable debate among communists regarding the nature of this society Some such as Joseph Stalin Fidel Castro and other Marxist Leninists believe that the lower stage of communism constitutes its own mode of production which they call socialist rather than communist Marxist Leninists believe that this society may still maintain the concepts of property money and commodity production 50 Higher stage of communism Edit To Marx the higher stage of communist society is a free association of producers which has successfully negated all remnants of capitalism notably the concepts of states nationality sexism families alienation social classes money property commodities the bourgeoisie the proletariat division of labor cities and countryside class struggle religion ideology and markets It is the negation of capitalism 51 52 Marx made the following comments on the higher phase of communist society In a higher phase of communist society after the enslaving subordination of the individual to the division of labor and therewith also the antithesis between mental and physical labor has vanished after labor has become not only a means of life but life s prime want after the productive forces have also increased with the all around development of the individual and all the springs of co operative wealth flow more abundantly only then can the narrow horizon of bourgeois right be crossed in its entirety and society inscribe on its banners From each according to his ability to each according to his needs 49 Warnings against misuse EditSee also Economic determinism In the 1872 Preface to the French edition of Das Kapital Vol 1 Marx emphasized that t here is no royal road to science and only those who do not dread the fatiguing climb of its steep paths have a chance of gaining its luminous summits 53 Reaching a scientific understanding required conscientious painstaking research instead of philosophical speculation and unwarranted sweeping generalizations Having abandoned abstract philosophical speculation in his youth Marx himself showed great reluctance during the rest of his life about offering any generalities or universal truths about human existence or human history Marx took care to indicate that he was only proposing a guideline to historical research Leitfaden or Auffassung and was not providing any substantive theory of history or grand philosophy of history let alone a master key to history Engels expressed irritation with dilettante academics who sought to knock up their skimpy historical knowledge as quickly as possible into some grand theoretical system that would explain everything about history He opined that historical materialism and the theory of modes of production were being used as an excuse for not studying history 54 The first explicit and systematic summary of the materialist interpretation of history to be published was Engels s book Herr Eugen Duhring s Revolution in Science written with Marx s approval and guidance and often referred to as the Anti Duhring One of the polemics was to ridicule the easy world schematism of philosophers who invented the latest wisdom from behind their writing desks Towards the end of his life in 1877 Marx wrote a letter to the editor of the Russian paper Otetchestvennye Zapisky which significantly contained the following disclaimer Russia will not succeed without having first transformed a good part of her peasants into proletarians and after that once taken to the bosom of the capitalist regime she will experience its pitiless laws like other profane peoples That is all But that is not enough for my critic He feels obliged to metamorphose my historical sketch of the genesis of capitalism in Western Europe into an historico philosophic theory of the marche generale imposed by fate upon every people whatever the historic circumstances in which it finds itself in order that it may ultimately arrive at the form of economy which will ensure together with the greatest expansion of the productive powers of social labour the most complete development of man But I beg his pardon He is both honouring and shaming me too much 55 Marx goes on to illustrate how the same factors can in different historical contexts produce very different results so that quick and easy generalizations are not really possible To indicate how seriously Marx took research when he died his estate contained several cubic metres of Russian statistical publications it was as the old Marx observed in Russia that his ideas gained the most influence Insofar as Marx and Engels regarded historical processes as law governed processes the possible future directions of historical development were to a great extent limited and conditioned by what happened before Retrospectively historical processes could be understood to have happened by necessity in certain ways and not others and to some extent at least the most likely variants of the future could be specified on the basis of careful study of the known facts Towards the end of his life Engels commented several times about the abuse of historical materialism In a letter to Conrad Schmidt dated 5 August 1890 he stated And if this man i e Paul Barth has not yet discovered that while the material mode of existence is the primum agens first agent this does not preclude the ideological spheres from reacting upon it in their turn though with a secondary effect he cannot possibly have understood the subject he is writing about The materialist conception of history has a lot of dangerous friends nowadays to whom it serves as an excuse for not studying history Just as Marx used to say commenting on the French Marxists of the late 70s All I know is that I am not a Marxist In general the word materialistic serves many of the younger writers in Germany as a mere phrase with which anything and everything is labelled without further study that is they stick to this label and then consider the question disposed of But our conception of history is above all a guide to study not a lever for construction after the manner of the Hegelian All history must be studied afresh and the conditions of existence of the different formations of society must be examined individually before the attempt is made to deduce them from the political civil law aesthetic philosophic religious etc views corresponding to them Up to now but little has been done here because only a few people have got down to it seriously In this field we can utilize heaps of help it is immensely big and anyone who will work seriously can achieve much and distinguish himself But instead of this too many of the younger Germans simply make use of the phrase historical materialism and everything can be turned into a phrase only in order to get their own relatively scanty historical knowledge for economic history is still in its swaddling clothes constructed into a neat system as quickly as possible and they then deem themselves something very tremendous And after that a Barth can come along and attack the thing itself which in his circle has indeed been degraded to a mere phrase 56 Finally in a letter to Franz Mehring dated 14 July 1893 Engels stated T here is only one other point lacking which however Marx and I always failed to stress enough in our writings and in regard to which we are all equally guilty That is to say we all laid and were bound to lay the main emphasis in the first place on the derivation of political juridical and other ideological notions and of actions arising through the medium of these notions from basic economic facts But in so doing we neglected the formal side the ways and means by which these notions etc come about for the sake of the content This has given our adversaries a welcome opportunity for misunderstandings of which Paul Barth is a striking example 57 Criticism EditPhilosopher of science Karl Popper in The Poverty of Historicism and Conjectures and Refutations critiqued such claims of the explanatory power or valid application of historical materialism by arguing that it could explain or explain away any fact brought before it making it unfalsifiable and thus pseudoscientific Similar arguments were brought by Leszek Kolakowski in Main Currents of Marxism 58 In his 1940 essay Theses on the Philosophy of History scholar Walter Benjamin compares historical materialism to the Turk an 18th century device which was promoted as a mechanized automaton which could defeat skilled chess players but actually concealed a human who controlled the machine Benjamin suggested that despite Marx s claims to scientific objectivity historical materialism was actually quasi religious Like the Turk wrote Benjamin t he puppet called historical materialism is always supposed to win It can do this with no further ado against any opponent so long as it employs the services of theology which as everyone knows is small and ugly and must be kept out of sight Benjamin s friend and colleague Gershom Scholem would argue that Benjamin s critique of historical materialism was so definitive that as Mark Lilla would write nothing remains of historical materialism but the term itself 59 Neven Sesardic argues that historical materialism is a highly exaggerated claim Sesardic observes that it was clear to many Marxists that the social cultural and ideological superstructure of society was not under the control of the base but had at least some degree of autonomy It was also clear that phenomena of the superstructure could determine part of the economic base Thus Sesardic argues that Marxists moved from a claim of the dominance of the economic base to a scenario in which the base sometimes determines the superstructure and the superstructure sometimes determines the base which Sesardic argues destroys their whole position This is because this new claim according to Sesardic is so innocuous that no one would deny it whereas the old claim was very radical as it posited the dominance of economics Sesardic argues that Marxists should have abandoned historical materialism when its strong version became untenable but instead they chose to water it down until it became a trivial claim 60 Continued development EditIn a foreword to his essay Ludwig Feuerbach and the End of Classical German Philosophy 1886 three years after Marx s death Engels claimed confidently that the Marxist world outlook has found representatives far beyond the boundaries of Germany and Europe and in all the literary languages of the world 61 Indeed in the years after Marx and Engels deaths historical materialism was identified as a distinct philosophical doctrine and was subsequently elaborated upon and systematized by Orthodox Marxist and Marxist Leninist thinkers such as Eduard Bernstein Karl Kautsky Georgi Plekhanov and Nikolai Bukharin This occurred despite the fact that many of Marx s earlier works on historical materialism including The German Ideology remained unpublished until the 1930s The substantivist ethnographic approach of economic anthropologist and sociologist Karl Polanyi bears similarities to historical materialism Polanyi distinguishes between the formal definition of economics as the logic of rational choice between limited resources and a substantive definition of economics as the way humans make their living from their natural and social environment 62 In The Great Transformation 1944 Polanyi asserts that both the formal and substantive definitions of economics hold true under capitalism but that the formal definition falls short when analyzing the economic behavior of pre industrial societies whose behavior was more often governed by redistribution and reciprocity 63 While Polanyi was influenced by Marx he rejected the primacy of economic determinism in shaping the course of history arguing that rather than being a realm unto itself an economy is embedded within its contemporary social institutions such as the state in the case of the market economy 64 Perhaps the most notable recent exploration of historical materialism is G A Cohen s Karl Marx s Theory of History A Defence 65 which inaugurated the school of Analytical Marxism Cohen advances a sophisticated technological determinist interpretation of Marx in which history is fundamentally the growth of human productive power and forms of society rise and fall according as they enable or impede that growth 66 Jurgen Habermas believes historical materialism needs revision in many respects especially because it has ignored the significance of communicative action 67 Goran Therborn has argued that the method of historical materialism should be applied to historical materialism as an intellectual tradition and to the history of Marxism itself 68 In the early 1980s Paul Hirst and Barry Hindess elaborated a structural Marxist interpretation of historical materialism 69 Regulation theory especially in the work of Michel Aglietta draws extensively on historical materialism 70 Following the collapse of the Soviet Union in the early 1990s much of Marxist thought was seen as anachronistic A major effort to renew historical materialism comes from historian Ellen Meiksins Wood who wrote in 1995 that There is something off about the assumption that the collapse of Communism represents a terminal crisis for Marxism One might think among other things that in a period of capitalist triumphalism there is more scope than ever for the pursuit of Marxism s principal project the critique of capitalism 71 T he kernel of historical materialism was an insistence on the historicity and specificity of capitalism and denial that its laws were the universal laws of history this focus on the specificity of capitalism as a moment with historical origins as well as an end with a systemic logic specific to it encourages a truly historical sense lacking in classical political economy and conventional ideas of progress and this had potentially fruitful implications for the historical study of other modes of production too 71 Referencing Marx s Theses on Feuerbach Wood argued for historical materialism to be understood as a theoretical foundation for interpreting the world in order to change it See also Edit nbsp Wikiquote has quotations related to Historical materialism nbsp History portalBooksDialectical Materialism and Historical Materialism Fundamentals of Marxism LeninismConceptsEconomic determinism Formalist substantivist debate Parametric determinism Technological determinism Technological unemployment Theory of historical trajectoryComparativeProgressive revelation Bahaʼi References EditCitations Edit Baur Michael January 2017 Marx on Historical Materialism ResearchGate 1 2 Jayapalan N 2001 Comprehensive History of Political Thought Atlantic Publisher amp Distributors p 248 Berlin Isaiah 2013 Karl Marx with a foreword by Alan Ryan 5th ed Princeton University Press p 112 ISBN 9780691156507 JSTOR j ctt46n3qx 13 Hankins Thomas 1985 Science and the Enlightenment Cambridge University Press pp 1 16 ISBN 0 521 28619 0 Brenner Robert 2003 Merchants and Revolution Commercial Change Political Conflict and London s Overseas Traders 1550 1653 Verso Books ISBN 978 1859843338 Davidson Neil 6 April 2006 Enlightenment and anti capitalism International Socialism 110 Porter Roy 2001 Enlightenment Penguin Books pp 12 14 ISBN 9780140250282 Philosophy of History 2020 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a website ignored help Hume David 12 August 2016 History of England from the Invasion of Julius Caesar to the Revolution in 1688 Hansebooks GmbH ISBN 978 3 7428 3234 4 OCLC 1129763042 Durrant Will 2002 The Greatest Minds and Ideas of All Time Simon amp Schuster ISBN 9780743235532 Carnwath Ally Halfhead Lucy Toms Katie 2008 Blue sky thinking 10 ideas that changed the course of history The Guardian Arp Robert 2018 1001 Ideas That Changed the Way We Think Octopus ISBN 9781788400886 Hart Diane 1987 Spirit of Liberty An American History Addison Wesley ISBN 978 0201209235 MacCulloch Diarmaid Is There Still Value in Great Man History History Today Retrieved 20 May 2022 Published in History Today Volume 69 Issue 9 September 2019 Marx Karl Feuerbach Opposition of the Materialist and Idealist Outlook B The Illusion of the Epoch The German Ideology via Marxists Internet Archive Kolakowski Leszek 2005 Main Currents of Marxism The Founders the Golden Age the Breakdown W W Norton amp Company pp 154 156 ISBN 978 0 393 06054 6 via Google Books Robinson Cedric J 18 January 2019 An Anthropology of Marxism 2 ed University of North Carolina Press p 9 ISBN 978 1 4696 4992 4 OCLC 1083096631 via Google Books Guthrie William Buck 1907 Socialism Before the French Revolution A History Macmillan pp 306 307 via Google Books Berlin Isaiah 2014 Freedom and Its Betrayal Six Enemies of Human Liberty Updated ed Princeton University Press p 90 ISBN 9780691157573 Choi Young 1990 Smith s View On Human Nature A Problem In The Interpretation of The Wealth Of Nations And The Theory Of Moral Sentiments PDF Review of Social Economy 48 3 288 302 doi 10 1080 00346769000000025 JSTOR 29769511 Pradella Lucia October 2014 Hegel Imperialism and Universal History Science amp Society 78 4 428 doi 10 1521 siso 2014 78 4 426 JSTOR 24583660 Fox Williams Jack 2020 Hegel s Understanding of History Philosophy Now 140 Winter Max 2016 Philosophy is its own time apprehended in thoughts Hegel on Time and Concept Revista Portuguesa de Filosofia 72 2 3 339 349 doi 10 17990 RPF 2016 72 2 0339 JSTOR 44028676 Hegel Georg Wilhelm Friedrich 2001 The Philosophy of History Canada Batochhe Books pp 55 565 ISBN 978 0486437552 What did Hegel mean by Geist Social Theory Applied Retrieved 5 August 2022 Rees John 1998 The Algebra of Revolution The Dialectic and the Classical Marxist Tradition London Routledge pp 45 47 ISBN 978 0415198776 Hegel Georg Wilhelm Friedrich 2001 The Philosophy of History Canada Batoche Books p 44 Berlin Isaiah 2013 Karl Marx Thoroughly Revised Fifth Edition Princeton University Press pp 57 61 ISBN 978 0691156507 Marx Karl Grundrisse via Marxists Internet Archive Kay Hubert 18 October 1948 Karl Marx Life p 66 Engels Friedrich 2022 Frederick Engels Speech at the Grave of Karl Marx Marxists Internet Archive Marx Karl 1867 7 The Labour Process and the Process of Producing Surplus Value Capital Vol One The Production of Absolute Surplus Value via Marxists Internet Archive Marx Karl 1845 1 Feuerbach Opposition of the Materialist and Idealist Outlook The German Ideology via Marxists Internet Archive Lin Justin Yifu 1995 The Needham Puzzle Why the Industrial Revolution Did Not Originate in China PDF Economic Development and Cultural Change 43 2 269 292 doi 10 1086 452150 JSTOR 1154499 S2CID 35637470 The case of China shows that a trend is just a trend In 1400 China possessed many of the ingredients for dynamic technological growth and expansion of political and economic power They had printing presses gunpowder were familiar with distillation used vaccination for small pox and explored the coastal states of Africa The reasons for these advances not being capitalised on is explored by the Lin article Marx Karl 1999 48 Capital Critique of Political Economy Vol 3 Retrieved 5 December 2018 via Marxists Internet Archive Callinicos Alex 2011 The Revolutionary Ideas of Karl Marx Chicago Haymarket Books p 99 Karl Marx Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy The Metaphysics Research Lab Center for the Study of Language and Information CSLI Stanford University Retrieved 6 September 2018 Charles Taylor Critical Notice Canadian Journal of Philosophy 10 1980 p 330 Marx amp Engels 1968 p 660 Cohen p 134 Foster amp Clark 2008 Harman C A People s History of the World Bookmarks a b c Marx Karl 1848 The Communist Manifesto London Retrieved 12 March 2019 Dixon Norm Marx Engels and Lenin on the National Question Links International Journal of Socialist Renewal Retrieved 21 April 2018 V I Lenin O natsional nom voprose i natsional noy politike V I Lenin O nacionalnom voprose i nacionalnoj politike V I Lenin On the national question and national policy in Russian Retrieved 21 April 2018 Lenin n d Marx Karl 1848 Chapter I Bourgeois and Proletarians The Communist Manifesto London Retrieved 4 April 2019 via Marxists Internet Archive a b Marx Karl Critique of the Gotha Programme Retrieved 12 March 2019 via Marxists Internet Archive a b Marx Karl Critique of the Gotha Programme Retrieved 12 March 2019 via Marxists Internet Archive Stalin Joseph Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR Retrieved 12 March 2019 via Marxists Internet Archive Marx Karl 1845 Idealism and Materialism The German Ideology Retrieved 12 March 2019 Marx Karl 1848 Chapter II Proletarians and Communists The Communist Manifesto London Retrieved 12 March 2019 via Marxists Internet Archive Marx Karl 1999 Chapter 48 The Trinity Formula Capital Critique of Political Economy Vol 1 Retrieved 5 December 2018 via Marxists Internet Archive Engels cited approvingly by E P Thompson in The peculiarities of the English Socialist Register 1965 Letter from Marx to Editor of the Otecestvenniye Zapisky Retrieved 10 November 2018 via Marxists Internet Archive Letters Marx Engels Correspondence 1890 Retrieved 7 December 2011 via Marxists Internet Archive Letters Marx Engels Correspondence 1893 Retrieved 7 December 2011 via Marxists Internet Archive Kolakowski 1978 Popper 1957 Lilla Mark 25 May 1995 The Riddle of Walter Benjamin The New York Review of Books Sesardic Neven 1985 Marxian Utopia Centre for Research into Communist Economies pp 14 15 ISBN 0948027010 Engels 1946 Polanyi K 1944 The Great Transformation New York pp 44 49 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint location missing publisher link ibid p 41 Hann Chris 2018 Economic Anthropology Economic Anthropology The International Encyclopedia of Anthropology John Wiley amp Sons pp 1 16 doi 10 1002 9781118924396 wbiea2194 ISBN 9780470657225 Cohen 2000 Cohen G A 1978 Karl Marx s Theory of History Princeton Princeton University Press p x Habermas Jurgen Autumn 1975 Toward a Reconstruction of Historical Materialism PDF Theory and Society 2 3 287 300 doi 10 1007 BF00212739 S2CID 113407026 Retrieved 5 December 2018 Therborn Goran 1980 Science Class and Society on the formation of Sociology and Historical Materialism London Verso Books Hirst Paul Hindess Barry 1975 Pre Capitalist Modes of Production London Routledge amp Kegan Paul Jessop Bob 2001 Capitalism the Regulation Approach and Critical Realism In Brown A Fleetwood S Roberts J eds Critical Realism and Marxism London Routledge a b Introduction Democracy against Capitalism Cambridge University Press 1995 pp 1 16 doi 10 1017 cbo9780511558344 001 ISBN 978 0 521 47096 4 Sources Edit Benjamin Walter Theses on the Philosophy of History Cohen G A 2000 1978 Karl Marx s Theory of History A Defence expanded ed Oxford Clarendon Press Engels Friedrich 1946 Foreword Ludwig Feuerbach and the End of Classical German Philosophy Moscow Progress Publishers Retrieved 21 April 2018 via Marxists Internet Archive Foster John Bellamy 1999 Marx s Ecology Materialism and Nature New York Monthly Review Press Foster John Bellamy Clark Brett 2008 Critique of Intelligent Design Materialism versus Creationism from Antiquity to the Present New York Monthly Review Press ISBN 978 1 58367 173 3 Fromm Erich 1961 Marx s Historical Materialism Marx s Concept of Man New York Frederick Ungar Publishing Retrieved 21 April 2018 via Marxists Internet Archive Kolakowski Leszek 1978 Main Currents of Marxism Its Origins Growth and Dissolution Lenin Vladimir Illyich n d Kriticheskie zametki po nacionalnomu voprosu Critical Remarks on the National Question Polnogo sobraniya sochinenij V I Lenina in Russian Vol 24 5th ed pp 113 150 Marx Karl 1977 Preface A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy By Marx Karl Dobb Maurice ed Translated by Ryazanskaya S W Moscow Progress Publishers Retrieved 21 April 2018 via Marxists Internet Archive 1993 Grundrisse Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy Translated by Nicolaus Martin London Penguin Books ISBN 978 0 14 044575 6 Marx Karl Engels Friedrich 1968 Selected Works in One Volume London Lawrence and Wishart Meek Ronald L 1976 Social Science and the Ignoble Savage Cambridge Studies in the History and Theory of Politics Cambridge England Cambridge University Press Nirenberg David 2013 Anti Judaism The Western Tradition New York W W Norton amp Company ISBN 978 0 393 34791 3 Popper Karl 1957 The Poverty of Historicism Seligman Edwin R A 1901 The Economic Interpretation of History Political Science Quarterly 16 4 612 640 doi 10 2307 2140420 JSTOR 2140420 Thompson E P 1965 The Peculiarities of the English Socialist Register 2 311 362 Retrieved 21 April 2018 Further reading EditThis further reading section may contain inappropriate or excessive suggestions that may not follow Wikipedia s guidelines Please ensure that only a reasonable number of balanced topical reliable and notable further reading suggestions are given removing less relevant or redundant publications with the same point of view where appropriate Consider utilising appropriate texts as inline sources or creating a separate bibliography article April 2018 Learn how and when to remove this template message Acton H B The Illusion of the Epoch Critical account which focusses on incoherencies in the thought of Marx Engels and Lenin Anderson Perry 1974 Lineages of the Absolutist State Aronowitz Stanley 1981 The Crisis in Historical Materialism American criticism of orthodox Marxism and argument for a more radical version of historical materialism that sticks closer to Marx by changing itself to keep up with changes in the historical situation Blackledge Paul 2006 Reflections on the Marxist Theory of History Blackledge Paul 2018 Vidal Matt Smith Tony Rotta Tomas Prew Paul eds Historical Materialism in Oxford Handbook on Karl Marx doi 10 1093 oxfordhb 9780190695545 001 0001 ISBN 9780190695545 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a journal ignored help Boudin Louis B 1907 The Theoretical System of Karl Marx Chicago Charles H Kerr Publishing Co Contains an early defence of the materialist conception of history against its critics of the day Childe V Gordon Man Makes Himself Free interpretation of Marx s idea Cohen Gerald Karl Marx s Theory of History A Defence Influential analytical Marxist interpretation Draper Hal Karl Marx s Theory of Revolution Captures the full subtlety of Marx s thought but at length in four volumes Fleischer Helmut Marxism and History Good reply to false interpretations of Marx s view of history Gandler Stefan 2015 Critical Marxism in Mexico Adolfo Sanchez Vazquez and Bolivar Echeverria Historical Materialism Book Series Vol 87 Leiden Netherlands Brill Academic Press ISBN 978 90 04 28468 5 ISSN 1570 1522 Giddens Anthony 1981 A Contemporary Critique of Historical Materialism Graham Loren R Science Philosophy and Human Behavior in the Soviet Union Sympathetically critical of dialectical materialism Habermas Jurgen January 1976 Communication and the Evolution of Society Argues historical materialism must be revised to include communicative action Harman Chris A People s History of the World Marxist view of history according to a leader of the International Socialist Tendency Harper J 1942 Materialism and Historical Materialism New Essays 6 2 Retrieved 21 April 2018 via Marxists Internet Archive Holt Justin P 2014 The Social Thought of Karl Marx Los Angeles SAGE Publications doi 10 4135 9781483349381 ISBN 978 1 4129 9784 3 Provides an introductory chapter on historical materialism Jakubowski Franz Ideology and Superstructure Attempts to provide an alternative to schematic interpretations of historical materialism Jordan Z A 1967 The Origins of Dialectical Materialism The Evolution of Dialectical Materialism A Philosophical and Sociological Analysis London Macmillan Retrieved 21 April 2018 via Marx Myths amp Legends Good survey Mandel Ernest Introduction to Marxism Emphasizes understanding the roots of class society and the state 1986 The Place of Marxism in History International Institute for Research and Education Retrieved 21 April 2018 via Marxists Internet Archive Modelled on Lenin s Three components of Marxism citation needed but with a section on the reception and diffusion of Marxism in the world Mao Zedong Four Essays on Philosophy Standard Maoist reading of Marx s materialism Marx Karl 1848 Manifesto of the Communist Party 1869 The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Napoleon 1887 Engels Friedrich ed Capital Critique of Political Economy Volume I The Process of Production of Capital Translated by Moore Samuel Aveling Edward Moscow Progress Publishers 1895 The Class Struggles in France 1848 1850 1932 Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844 1932 The German Ideology 1956 Engels Friedrich ed Capital Critique of Political Economy Volume II The Process of Circulation of Capital Translated by Lasker I 2nd ed Moscow Progress Publishers 1959 Capital Critique of Political Economy Volume III The Process of Capitalist Production as a Whole 1964 Hobsbawm E J ed Pre Capitalist Economic Formations Translated by Cohen Jack London Lawrence amp Wishart 1969 Theses on Feuerbach Marx Engels Selected Works Moscow Progress Publishers pp 13 15 Mehring Franz 1975 On Historical Materialism Translated by Archer Bob London New Park Press Retrieved 21 April 2018 via Marxists Internet Archive Classic statement by a contemporary and friend of Marx amp Engels Novack George 2002 Understanding History Marxist Essays Chippendale New South Wales Resistance Books ISBN 978 1 876646 23 3 Retrieved 21 April 2018 via Marxists Internet Archive Trotskyist interpretations of problems of history Nowak Leszek Property and Power Towards a Non Marxian Historical Materialism Attempts to develop a post Stalinist interpretation of Marx s project Rees John The Algebra of Revolution Classical Marxist account of the philosophy of Marx Engels Lenin Lukacs and Trotsky Rigby S H 1998 Marxism and History A Critical Introduction 2nd ed Manchester Manchester University Press ISBN 978 0 7190 5612 3 Shaw William H Marx s Theory of History Provides a short survey Spirkin Alexander 1990 Fundamentals of Philosophy Translated by Syrovatkin Sergei Moscow Progress Publishers ISBN 978 5 01 002582 3 Retrieved 15 January 2011 Stalin Joseph Dialectical and Historical Materialism Classic statement of Stalinist doctrine Suchting Wal Marx An Introduction Includes a good short introduction The Materialist Conception of History Education Bulletin No 1 1979 Retrieved 21 April 2018 Therborn Goran Science Class and Society Critical survey of the relationship between sociology and historical materialism Thompson E P The Poverty of Theory Polemic which ridicules theorists of history who do not actually study history Wetter Gustav A Dialectical Materialism a Historical and Systematic Survey of Philosophy in the Soviet Union Alternative survey Witt Hansen Johan Historical Materialism The Method The Theories Sees historical materialism as a methodology and Das Kapital as an application of the method Wood Allen W 2004 Karl Marx Arguments of the Philosophers 2nd ed Abingdon England Routledge ISBN 978 0 415 31697 2 Delves into misinterpretations of Marx including the substitution of Historical materialism by Lenin Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Historical materialism amp oldid 1176679613, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.