fbpx
Wikipedia

Dividend discount model

In financial economics, the dividend discount model (DDM) is a method of valuing the price of a company's capital stock or business value based on the fact that their corresponding value is worth the sum of all of its future dividend payments, discounted back to their present value.[1] In other words, DDM is used to value stocks based on the net present value of the future dividends. The constant-growth form of the DDM is sometimes referred to as the Gordon growth model (GGM), after Myron J. Gordon of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, the University of Rochester, and the University of Toronto, who published it along with Eli Shapiro in 1956 and made reference to it in 1959.[2][3] Their work borrowed heavily from the theoretical and mathematical ideas found in John Burr Williams 1938 book "The Theory of Investment Value," which put forth the dividend discount model 18 years before Gordon and Shapiro.

When dividends are assumed to grow at a constant rate, the variables are: is the current stock price. is the constant growth rate in perpetuity expected for the dividends. is the constant cost of equity capital for that company. is the value of dividends at the end of the first period.

Derivation of equation edit

The model uses the fact that the current value of the dividend payment   at (discrete) time   is  , and so the current value of all the future dividend payments, which is the current price  , is the sum of the infinite series

 

This summation can be rewritten as

 

where

 

The series in parentheses is the geometric series with common ratio   so it sums to   if  . Thus,

 

Substituting the value for   leads to

 ,

which is simplified by multiplying by  , so that

 

Income plus capital gains equals total return edit

The DDM equation can also be understood to state simply that a stock's total return equals the sum of its income and capital gains.

  is rearranged to give  

So the dividend yield   plus the growth   equals cost of equity  .

Consider the dividend growth rate in the DDM model as a proxy for the growth of earnings and by extension the stock price and capital gains. Consider the DDM's cost of equity capital as a proxy for the investor's required total return.[4]

 

Growth cannot exceed cost of equity edit

From the first equation, one might notice that   cannot be negative. When growth is expected to exceed the cost of equity in the short run, then usually a two-stage DDM is used:

 

Therefore,

 

where   denotes the short-run expected growth rate,   denotes the long-run growth rate, and   is the period (number of years), over which the short-run growth rate is applied.

Even when g is very close to r, P approaches infinity, so the model becomes meaningless.

Some properties of the model edit

a) When the growth g is zero, the dividend is capitalized.

 .

b) This equation is also used to estimate the cost of capital by solving for  .

 

c) which is equivalent to the formula of the Gordon Growth Model (or Yield-plus-growth Model):

  =  

where “ ” stands for the present stock value, “ ” stands for expected dividend per share one year from the present time, “g” stands for rate of growth of dividends, and “k” represents the required return rate for the equity investor.

Problems with the constant-growth form of the model edit

The following shortcomings have been noted;[citation needed] see also Discounted cash flow § Shortcomings.

  1. The presumption of a steady and perpetual growth rate less than the cost of capital may not be reasonable.
  2. If the stock does not currently pay a dividend, like many growth stocks, more general versions of the discounted dividend model must be used to value the stock. One common technique is to assume that the Modigliani-Miller hypothesis of dividend irrelevance is true, and therefore replace the stock's dividend D with E earnings per share. However, this requires the use of earnings growth rather than dividend growth, which might be different. This approach is especially useful for computing the residual value of future periods.
  3. The stock price resulting from the Gordon model is sensitive to the growth rate   chosen; see Sustainable growth rate § From a financial perspective

Related methods edit

The dividend discount model is closely related to both discounted earnings and discounted cashflow models. In either of the latter two, the value of a company is based on how much money is made by the company. For example, if a company consistently paid out 50% of earnings as dividends, then the discounted dividends would be worth 50% of the discounted earnings. Also, in the dividend discount model, a company that is not expected to pay dividends ever in the future is worth nothing, as the owners of the asset ultimately never receive any cash.

References edit

  1. ^ Investopedia – Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model
  2. ^ Gordon, M.J and Eli Shapiro (1956) "Capital Equipment Analysis: The Required Rate of Profit," Management Science, 3,(1) (October 1956) 102-110. Reprinted in Management of Corporate Capital, Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press of, 1959.
  3. ^ Gordon, Myron J. (1959). "Dividends, Earnings and Stock Prices". Review of Economics and Statistics. The MIT Press. 41 (2): 99–105. doi:10.2307/1927792. JSTOR 1927792.
  4. ^ . Archived from the original on 2019-03-22. Retrieved 2011-12-28.

Further reading edit

  • Gordon, Myron J. (1962). The Investment, Financing, and Valuation of the Corporation. Homewood, IL: R. D. Irwin.
  • (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2013-06-12.

External links edit

  • Alternative derivations of the Gordon Model and its place in the context of other DCF-based shortcuts

dividend, discount, model, financial, economics, dividend, discount, model, method, valuing, price, company, capital, stock, business, value, based, fact, that, their, corresponding, value, worth, future, dividend, payments, discounted, back, their, present, v. In financial economics the dividend discount model DDM is a method of valuing the price of a company s capital stock or business value based on the fact that their corresponding value is worth the sum of all of its future dividend payments discounted back to their present value 1 In other words DDM is used to value stocks based on the net present value of the future dividends The constant growth form of the DDM is sometimes referred to as the Gordon growth model GGM after Myron J Gordon of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology the University of Rochester and the University of Toronto who published it along with Eli Shapiro in 1956 and made reference to it in 1959 2 3 Their work borrowed heavily from the theoretical and mathematical ideas found in John Burr Williams 1938 book The Theory of Investment Value which put forth the dividend discount model 18 years before Gordon and Shapiro When dividends are assumed to grow at a constant rate the variables are P displaystyle P is the current stock price g displaystyle g is the constant growth rate in perpetuity expected for the dividends r displaystyle r is the constant cost of equity capital for that company D 1 displaystyle D 1 is the value of dividends at the end of the first period P D 1 r g displaystyle P frac D 1 r g Contents 1 Derivation of equation 2 Income plus capital gains equals total return 3 Growth cannot exceed cost of equity 4 Some properties of the model 5 Problems with the constant growth form of the model 6 Related methods 7 References 8 Further reading 9 External linksDerivation of equation editThe model uses the fact that the current value of the dividend payment D 0 1 g t displaystyle D 0 1 g t nbsp at discrete time t displaystyle t nbsp is D 0 1 g t 1 r t displaystyle frac D 0 1 g t 1 r t nbsp and so the current value of all the future dividend payments which is the current price P displaystyle P nbsp is the sum of the infinite series P 0 t 1 D 0 1 g t 1 r t displaystyle P 0 sum t 1 infty D 0 frac 1 g t 1 r t nbsp This summation can be rewritten as P 0 D 0 r 1 r r 2 r 3 displaystyle P 0 D 0 r 1 r r 2 r 3 nbsp where r 1 g 1 r displaystyle r frac 1 g 1 r nbsp The series in parentheses is the geometric series with common ratio r displaystyle r nbsp so it sums to 1 1 r displaystyle frac 1 1 r nbsp if r lt 1 displaystyle mid r mid lt 1 nbsp Thus P 0 D 0 r 1 r displaystyle P 0 frac D 0 r 1 r nbsp Substituting the value for r displaystyle r nbsp leads to P 0 D 0 1 g 1 r 1 1 g 1 r displaystyle P 0 frac D 0 frac 1 g 1 r 1 frac 1 g 1 r nbsp which is simplified by multiplying by 1 r 1 r displaystyle frac 1 r 1 r nbsp so that P 0 D 0 1 g r g D 1 r g displaystyle P 0 frac D 0 1 g r g frac D 1 r g nbsp Income plus capital gains equals total return editThe DDM equation can also be understood to state simply that a stock s total return equals the sum of its income and capital gains D 1 r g P 0 displaystyle frac D 1 r g P 0 nbsp is rearranged to give D 1 P 0 g r displaystyle frac D 1 P 0 g r nbsp So the dividend yield D 1 P 0 displaystyle D 1 P 0 nbsp plus the growth g displaystyle g nbsp equals cost of equity r displaystyle r nbsp Consider the dividend growth rate in the DDM model as a proxy for the growth of earnings and by extension the stock price and capital gains Consider the DDM s cost of equity capital as a proxy for the investor s required total return 4 Income Capital Gain Total Return displaystyle text Income text Capital Gain text Total Return nbsp Growth cannot exceed cost of equity editFrom the first equation one might notice that r g displaystyle r g nbsp cannot be negative When growth is expected to exceed the cost of equity in the short run then usually a two stage DDM is used P t 1 N D 0 1 g t 1 r t P N 1 r N displaystyle P sum t 1 N frac D 0 left 1 g right t left 1 r right t frac P N left 1 r right N nbsp Therefore P D 0 1 g r g 1 1 g N 1 r N D 0 1 g N 1 g 1 r N r g displaystyle P frac D 0 left 1 g right r g left 1 frac left 1 g right N left 1 r right N right frac D 0 left 1 g right N left 1 g infty right left 1 r right N left r g infty right nbsp where g displaystyle g nbsp denotes the short run expected growth rate g displaystyle g infty nbsp denotes the long run growth rate and N displaystyle N nbsp is the period number of years over which the short run growth rate is applied Even when g is very close to r P approaches infinity so the model becomes meaningless Some properties of the model edita When the growth g is zero the dividend is capitalized P 0 D 1 r displaystyle P 0 frac D 1 r nbsp b This equation is also used to estimate the cost of capital by solving for r displaystyle r nbsp r D 1 P 0 g displaystyle r frac D 1 P 0 g nbsp c which is equivalent to the formula of the Gordon Growth Model or Yield plus growth Model P 0 displaystyle P 0 nbsp D 1 k g displaystyle frac D 1 k g nbsp where P 0 displaystyle P 0 nbsp stands for the present stock value D 1 displaystyle D 1 nbsp stands for expected dividend per share one year from the present time g stands for rate of growth of dividends and k represents the required return rate for the equity investor Problems with the constant growth form of the model editThe following shortcomings have been noted citation needed see also Discounted cash flow Shortcomings The presumption of a steady and perpetual growth rate less than the cost of capital may not be reasonable If the stock does not currently pay a dividend like many growth stocks more general versions of the discounted dividend model must be used to value the stock One common technique is to assume that the Modigliani Miller hypothesis of dividend irrelevance is true and therefore replace the stock s dividend D with E earnings per share However this requires the use of earnings growth rather than dividend growth which might be different This approach is especially useful for computing the residual value of future periods The stock price resulting from the Gordon model is sensitive to the growth rate g displaystyle g nbsp chosen see Sustainable growth rate From a financial perspectiveRelated methods editThe dividend discount model is closely related to both discounted earnings and discounted cashflow models In either of the latter two the value of a company is based on how much money is made by the company For example if a company consistently paid out 50 of earnings as dividends then the discounted dividends would be worth 50 of the discounted earnings Also in the dividend discount model a company that is not expected to pay dividends ever in the future is worth nothing as the owners of the asset ultimately never receive any cash References edit Investopedia Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model Gordon M J and Eli Shapiro 1956 Capital Equipment Analysis The Required Rate of Profit Management Science 3 1 October 1956 102 110 Reprinted in Management of Corporate Capital Glencoe Ill Free Press of 1959 Gordon Myron J 1959 Dividends Earnings and Stock Prices Review of Economics and Statistics The MIT Press 41 2 99 105 doi 10 2307 1927792 JSTOR 1927792 Spreadsheet for variable inputs to Gordon Model Archived from the original on 2019 03 22 Retrieved 2011 12 28 Further reading editGordon Myron J 1962 The Investment Financing and Valuation of the Corporation Homewood IL R D Irwin Equity Discounted Cash Flow Models PDF Archived from the original PDF on 2013 06 12 External links editAlternative derivations of the Gordon Model and its place in the context of other DCF based shortcuts Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Dividend discount model amp oldid 1213703133, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.