fbpx
Wikipedia

Complementary good

In economics, a complementary good is a good whose appeal increases with the popularity of its complement.[further explanation needed] Technically, it displays a negative cross elasticity of demand and that demand for it increases when the price of another good decreases.[1] If is a complement to , an increase in the price of will result in a negative movement along the demand curve of and cause the demand curve for to shift inward; less of each good will be demanded. Conversely, a decrease in the price of will result in a positive movement along the demand curve of and cause the demand curve of to shift outward; more of each good will be demanded. This is in contrast to a substitute good, whose demand decreases when its substitute's price decreases.[2]

Complementary goods exhibit a negative cross elasticity of demand: as the price of goods Y rises, the demand for good X falls.

When two goods are complements, they experience joint demand - the demand of one good is linked to the demand for another good. Therefore, if a higher quantity is demanded of one good, a higher quantity will also be demanded of the other, and vice versa. For example, the demand for razor blades may depend on the number of razors in use; this is why razors have sometimes been sold as loss leaders, to increase demand for the associated blades.[3] Another example is that sometimes a toothbrush is packaged free with toothpaste. The toothbrush is a complement to the toothpaste; the cost of producing a toothbrush may be higher than toothpaste, but its sales depends on the demand of toothpaste.

All non-complementary goods can be considered substitutes.[4] If and are rough complements in an everyday sense, then consumers are willing to pay more for each marginal unit of good as they accumulate more . The opposite is true for substitutes: the consumer is willing to pay less for each marginal unit of good "" as it accumulates more of good "".

Complementarity may be driven by psychological processes in which the consumption of one good (e.g., cola) stimulates demand for its complements (e.g., a cheeseburger). Consumption of a food or beverage activates a goal to consume its complements: foods that consumers believe would taste better together. Drinking cola increases consumers' willingness to pay for a cheeseburger. This effect appears to be contingent on consumer perceptions of these relationships rather than their sensory properties.[5]

Examples edit

 
Supply and demand of cars when the price of petrol decreases

An example of this would be the demand for cars and petrol. The supply and demand for cars is represented by the figure, with the initial demand  . Suppose that the initial price of cars is represented by   with a quantity demanded of  . If the price of petrol were to decrease by some amount, this would result in a higher quantity of cars demanded. This higher quantity demanded would cause the demand curve to shift rightward to a new position  . Assuming a constant supply curve   of cars, the new increased quantity demanded will be at   with a new increased price  . Other examples include automobiles and fuel, mobile phones and cellular service, printer and cartridge, among others.

Perfect complement edit

 
Indifference curve for perfect complements

A perfect complement is a good that must be consumed with another good. The indifference curve of a perfect complement exhibits a right angle, as illustrated by the figure.[6] Such preferences can be represented by a Leontief utility function.

Few goods behave as perfect complements.[6] One example is a left shoe and a right; shoes are naturally sold in pairs, and the ratio between sales of left and right shoes will never shift noticeably from 1:1.

The degree of complementarity, however, does not have to be mutual; it can be measured by the cross price elasticity of demand. In the case of video games, a specific video game (the complement good) has to be consumed with a video game console (the base good). It does not work the other way: a video game console does not have to be consumed with that game.

Example edit

In marketing, complementary goods give additional market power to the producer. It allows vendor lock-in by increasing switching costs. A few types of pricing strategy exist for a complementary good and its base good:

  • Pricing the base good at a relatively low price - this approach allows easy entry by consumers (e.g. low-price consumer printer vs. high-price cartridge)
  • Pricing the base good at a relatively high price to the complementary good - this approach creates a barrier to entry and exit (e.g., a costly car vs inexpensive gas)

Gross complements edit

Sometimes the complement-relationship between two goods is not intuitive and must be verified by inspecting the cross-elasticity of demand using market data.

Mosak's definition states "a good of   is a gross complement of   if   is negative, where   for   denotes the ordinary individual demand for a certain good." In fact, in Mosak's case,   is not a gross complement of   but   is a gross complement of  . The elasticity does not need to be symmetrical. Thus,   is a gross complement of   while   can simultaneously be a gross substitutes for  .[7]

Proof edit

The standard Hicks decomposition of the effect on the ordinary demand for a good   of a simple price change in a good  , utility level   and chosen bundle   is

 

If   is a gross substitute for  , the left-hand side of the equation and the first term of right-hand side are positive. By the symmetry of Mosak's perspective, evaluating the equation with respect to  , the first term of right-hand side stays the same while some extreme cases exist where   is large enough to make the whole right-hand-side negative. In this case,   is a gross complement of  . Overall,   and   are not symmetrical.


Effect of price change of complementary goods edit

References edit

  1. ^ Carbaugh, Robert (2006). Contemporary Economics: An Applications Approach. Cengage Learning. p. 35. ISBN 978-0-324-31461-8.
  2. ^ O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Pearson Prentice Hall. p. 88. ISBN 0-13-063085-3.
  3. ^ . Future Observatory. Archived from the original on 2013-04-04.
  4. ^ Newman, Peter (2016-11-30) [1987]. "Substitutes and Complements". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics: 1–7. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_1821-1. ISBN 978-1-349-95121-5. Retrieved 2022-05-26.
  5. ^ Huh, Young Eun; Vosgerau, Joachim; Morewedge, Carey K. (2016-03-14). "Selective Sensitization: Consuming a Food Activates a Goal to Consume its Complements". Journal of Marketing Research. 53 (6): 1034–1049. doi:10.1509/jmr.12.0240. ISSN 0022-2437. S2CID 4800997.
  6. ^ a b Mankiw, Gregory (2008). Principle of Economics. Cengage Learning. pp. 463–464. ISBN 978-0-324-58997-9.
  7. ^ Mosak, Jacob L. (1944). "General equilibrium theory in international trade" (PDF). Cowles Commission for Research in Economics, Monograph No. 7. Principia Press: 33.

complementary, good, economics, complementary, good, good, whose, appeal, increases, with, popularity, complement, further, explanation, needed, technically, displays, negative, cross, elasticity, demand, that, demand, increases, when, price, another, good, de. In economics a complementary good is a good whose appeal increases with the popularity of its complement further explanation needed Technically it displays a negative cross elasticity of demand and that demand for it increases when the price of another good decreases 1 If A displaystyle A is a complement to B displaystyle B an increase in the price of A displaystyle A will result in a negative movement along the demand curve of A displaystyle A and cause the demand curve for B displaystyle B to shift inward less of each good will be demanded Conversely a decrease in the price of A displaystyle A will result in a positive movement along the demand curve of A displaystyle A and cause the demand curve of B displaystyle B to shift outward more of each good will be demanded This is in contrast to a substitute good whose demand decreases when its substitute s price decreases 2 Complementary goods exhibit a negative cross elasticity of demand as the price of goods Y rises the demand for good X falls When two goods are complements they experience joint demand the demand of one good is linked to the demand for another good Therefore if a higher quantity is demanded of one good a higher quantity will also be demanded of the other and vice versa For example the demand for razor blades may depend on the number of razors in use this is why razors have sometimes been sold as loss leaders to increase demand for the associated blades 3 Another example is that sometimes a toothbrush is packaged free with toothpaste The toothbrush is a complement to the toothpaste the cost of producing a toothbrush may be higher than toothpaste but its sales depends on the demand of toothpaste All non complementary goods can be considered substitutes 4 If x displaystyle x and y displaystyle y are rough complements in an everyday sense then consumers are willing to pay more for each marginal unit of good x displaystyle x as they accumulate more y displaystyle y The opposite is true for substitutes the consumer is willing to pay less for each marginal unit of good z displaystyle z as it accumulates more of good y displaystyle y Complementarity may be driven by psychological processes in which the consumption of one good e g cola stimulates demand for its complements e g a cheeseburger Consumption of a food or beverage activates a goal to consume its complements foods that consumers believe would taste better together Drinking cola increases consumers willingness to pay for a cheeseburger This effect appears to be contingent on consumer perceptions of these relationships rather than their sensory properties 5 Contents 1 Examples 2 Perfect complement 2 1 Example 3 Gross complements 3 1 Proof 4 Effect of price change of complementary goods 5 ReferencesExamples edit nbsp Supply and demand of cars when the price of petrol decreases An example of this would be the demand for cars and petrol The supply and demand for cars is represented by the figure with the initial demand D 1 displaystyle D 1 nbsp Suppose that the initial price of cars is represented by P 1 displaystyle P 1 nbsp with a quantity demanded of Q 1 displaystyle Q 1 nbsp If the price of petrol were to decrease by some amount this would result in a higher quantity of cars demanded This higher quantity demanded would cause the demand curve to shift rightward to a new position D 2 displaystyle D 2 nbsp Assuming a constant supply curve S displaystyle S nbsp of cars the new increased quantity demanded will be at Q 2 displaystyle Q 2 nbsp with a new increased price P 2 displaystyle P 2 nbsp Other examples include automobiles and fuel mobile phones and cellular service printer and cartridge among others Perfect complement edit nbsp Indifference curve for perfect complements A perfect complement is a good that must be consumed with another good The indifference curve of a perfect complement exhibits a right angle as illustrated by the figure 6 Such preferences can be represented by a Leontief utility function Few goods behave as perfect complements 6 One example is a left shoe and a right shoes are naturally sold in pairs and the ratio between sales of left and right shoes will never shift noticeably from 1 1 The degree of complementarity however does not have to be mutual it can be measured by the cross price elasticity of demand In the case of video games a specific video game the complement good has to be consumed with a video game console the base good It does not work the other way a video game console does not have to be consumed with that game Example edit In marketing complementary goods give additional market power to the producer It allows vendor lock in by increasing switching costs A few types of pricing strategy exist for a complementary good and its base good Pricing the base good at a relatively low price this approach allows easy entry by consumers e g low price consumer printer vs high price cartridge Pricing the base good at a relatively high price to the complementary good this approach creates a barrier to entry and exit e g a costly car vs inexpensive gas Gross complements editSometimes the complement relationship between two goods is not intuitive and must be verified by inspecting the cross elasticity of demand using market data Mosak s definition states a good of x displaystyle x nbsp is a gross complement of y displaystyle y nbsp if f x p w p y displaystyle frac partial f x p omega partial p y nbsp is negative where f i p w displaystyle f i p omega nbsp for i 1 2 n displaystyle i 1 2 ldots n nbsp denotes the ordinary individual demand for a certain good In fact in Mosak s case x displaystyle x nbsp is not a gross complement of y displaystyle y nbsp but y displaystyle y nbsp is a gross complement of x displaystyle x nbsp The elasticity does not need to be symmetrical Thus y displaystyle y nbsp is a gross complement of x displaystyle x nbsp while x displaystyle x nbsp can simultaneously be a gross substitutes for y displaystyle y nbsp 7 Proof edit The standard Hicks decomposition of the effect on the ordinary demand for a good x displaystyle x nbsp of a simple price change in a good y displaystyle y nbsp utility level t displaystyle tau nbsp and chosen bundle z x y displaystyle z x y dots nbsp is f x p w p y h x p t p y y f x p w w displaystyle frac partial f x p omega partial p y frac partial h x p tau partial p y y frac partial f x p omega partial omega nbsp If x displaystyle x nbsp is a gross substitute for y displaystyle y nbsp the left hand side of the equation and the first term of right hand side are positive By the symmetry of Mosak s perspective evaluating the equation with respect to x displaystyle x nbsp the first term of right hand side stays the same while some extreme cases exist where x displaystyle x nbsp is large enough to make the whole right hand side negative In this case y displaystyle y nbsp is a gross complement of x displaystyle x nbsp Overall x displaystyle x nbsp and y displaystyle y nbsp are not symmetrical Effect of price change of complementary goods editSubstitute goodReferences edit Carbaugh Robert 2006 Contemporary Economics An Applications Approach Cengage Learning p 35 ISBN 978 0 324 31461 8 O Sullivan Arthur Sheffrin Steven M 2003 Economics Principles in Action Upper Saddle River New Jersey Pearson Prentice Hall p 88 ISBN 0 13 063085 3 Customer in Marketing by David Mercer Future Observatory Archived from the original on 2013 04 04 Newman Peter 2016 11 30 1987 Substitutes and Complements The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics 1 7 doi 10 1057 978 1 349 95121 5 1821 1 ISBN 978 1 349 95121 5 Retrieved 2022 05 26 Huh Young Eun Vosgerau Joachim Morewedge Carey K 2016 03 14 Selective Sensitization Consuming a Food Activates a Goal to Consume its Complements Journal of Marketing Research 53 6 1034 1049 doi 10 1509 jmr 12 0240 ISSN 0022 2437 S2CID 4800997 a b Mankiw Gregory 2008 Principle of Economics Cengage Learning pp 463 464 ISBN 978 0 324 58997 9 Mosak Jacob L 1944 General equilibrium theory in international trade PDF Cowles Commission for Research in Economics Monograph No 7 Principia Press 33 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Complementary good amp oldid 1178676795, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.