fbpx
Wikipedia

Social class in Tibet

There were three main feudal social groups in Tibet prior to 1959, namely ordinary laypeople (mi ser in Tibetan), lay nobility (sger pa), and monks.[1] The ordinary layperson could be further classified as a peasant farmer (shing-pa)[citation needed] or nomadic pastoralist (trokpa).[citation needed] to influence politics and religious domination, entering into monkhood and military was required.

Thubten Gyatso, the 13th Dalai Lama photographed in Calcutta in 1910

The Tsangpa Dynasty (1565-1642) and Ganden Phodrang (1642-1950) law codes distinguished three social divisions: high, medium and low. Each in turn was divided into three classes, to give nine classes in all. Social status was a formal classification, mostly hereditary and had legal consequences: for example the compensation to be paid for the killing of a member of these classes varied from 5 (for the lowest) to 200 'sung' for the second highest, the members of the noble families.

Nobles, government officials and monks of pure conduct were in the high division, only – probably – the Dalai Lama was in the very highest position. The middle division contained a large portion of the population and ranged from minor government officials, to taxpayer and landholding peasants, to landless peasants. Social mobility was possible in the middle division.[2] The lower division contained ragyabpa of different types: e.g. blacksmiths and butchers. The very lowest class contained executioners, and (in the Tsang code) bachelors and hermaphrodites.[3]

Anthropologists have presented different taxonomies for the middle social division, in part because they studied specific regions of Tibet and the terms were not universal.[4][5][6][7] Both Melvyn Goldstein and Geoff Childs however classified the population into three main types:[8][9]

In the middle group, the taxpaying families could be quite wealthy.[10] Depending upon the district, each category had different responsibilities in terms of tax and labor.[11] Membership to each of these classes was primarily hereditary; the linkage between subjects and their estate and overlord was similarly transmitted through parallel descent. The taxpayer class, although numerically smallest among the three subclasses, occupied a superior position in terms of political and economic status.

The question of whether serfdom prevailed in traditional Tibetan society is controversial; Heidi Fjeld [no] argues for a moderate position, recognizing that serfdom existed but was not universal in Tibet.

The Higher Division edit

The highest of the high class was empty, or only contained possibly the Dalai Lama[3]

The Nobility edit

The middle class of the high division – the highest attainable in practice – was headed by the hereditary nobility. Yabshi were thought to be descendants of the Dalai Lamas, depon were descendants of the ancient royal families, midak were on a slightly lower level.[12]

There were "a small group of about 30 higher status families" and "120 to 170 lower or 'common' aristocratic families".[13]

High Government and Monk Officials edit

High government officials were appointed from the aristocracy. Monk officials were usually drawn from Lhasa middle classes, the families of existing monk officials, or were the second sons of the aristocracy. They were usually monks in name only, one night spent in a monastery being sufficient to qualify as a monk for this purpose.[14]

The Middle Division edit

Taxpayer families edit

The treba (also tralpa or khral-pa) taxpayers lived in "corporate family units" that hereditarily owned estates leased from their district authority, complete with land titles. In Goldstein's review of the Gyantse district he found that a taxpayer family typically owned from 20 acres (81,000 m2) to 300 acres (1.2 km2) of land each. Their primary civil responsibility was to pay taxes (tre-ba and khral-pa means "taxpayer"), and to supply corvée services that included both human and animal labor to their district authority.[9] They had a comfortable standard of living. They also frequently practiced polyandry in marriage and other practices to maintain a single marriage per generation and avoid parceling land holdings.

Householders edit

The householder class (du-jung, dud-chung-ba[9] duiqoin, duiqion, düchung, dudchhung, duigoin or dujung) comprised peasants who held only small plots of land that were legally and literally "individual" possessions. This was different from the taxpayer families who owned land as a familial corporation. Land inheritance rules for the householders were quite different from taxpayer family rules, in that there was no certainty as to whether a plot of land would be inherited by his son. The district authority — either governmental, monastic, or aristocratic — was the ultimate landowner and decided inheritance. Compared to the taxpayer families the householders, however, had lighter tax obligations and only human labor corvée obligations to their district authorities. These obligations, unlike the taxpayer family obligations, fell only on the individual and not on his family.

Landless peasants edit

Landless peasants (mi-bo) did not have heritable rights to land. They were still obligated to their 'owning' estate under their status as mi-ser. In contrast with the taxpayer families and householders, they had the freedom to go wherever they wanted and could engage in trade or crafts.[15] When farming, they might lease land from taxpayer families and as payment take on work for those families. Like the householders the landless peasants also used resources in their own individual capacity which were non-heritable.

The relative freedom of the mi-bo status was usually purchased by an annual fee to the estate to which the mi-bo belonged. The fee could be raised if the mi-bo prospered, and the lord could still exact special corvée labor, e.g. for a special event.

The status could be revoked at the will of the estate owner. The offspring of the mi-bo did not automatically inherit the status of 'mi-bo', they did inherit the status of 'mi-ser', and could be indentured to service in their earlier teens, or would have to pay their own mi-bo fee.[2]

The Lower Division edit

Ragyabpa edit

The ragyabpa feudal class were at bottom level, and they performed the 'unclean' work. This included fishermen, butchers, executioners, corpse disposers, blacksmiths, goldsmiths and prostitutes. Ragyabpa were also divided into three divisions: for instance a goldsmith was in the highest at third feudal class, and was not regarded as being as defiled as an executioner, who was in the lowest.

Nangzan – Household servants edit

According to Chinese government sources, Nangzan (also nangzen, nangzan, nangsen) were hereditary household servants comprising 5% of the population.[16][17]

Slavery edit

According to American sinologist A. Tom Grunfeld there were a few slaves in Tibet. Grunfeld quotes Sir Charles Bell, a British colonial official in the Chumbi Valley in the early 20th century and a Tibet scholar who wrote of slaves in the form of small children being stolen or bought from their parents, too poor to support them, to be brought up and kept or sold as slaves.[18] These children came mostly from south-eastern Tibet and the territories of the tribes that dwelt between Tibet and Assam.[19] Grunfeld omits Bell's elaboration that in 1905, there were "a dozen or two" of these, and that it was "a very mild form of slavery".[20] According to exile Tibetan writer Jamyang Norbu, later accounts from Westerners who visited Tibet and even long-term foreign residents such as Heinrich Harrer, Peter Aufschnaiter, Hugh Richardson and David Macdonald make no mention of any such practice, which suggests that the 13th Dalai Lama may have eliminated this practice altogether in his reforms.[20]

Notes edit

  1. ^ Snellgrove, Cultural History, pp. 257–259
  2. ^ a b Goldstein 1986
  3. ^ a b French p. 114
  4. ^ a b c Goldstein (May 1971) p.524
  5. ^ Samuel, Geoffrey (Feb., 1982) Tibet as a Stateless Society and Some Islamic Parallels The Journal of Asian Studies, Vol. 41, No. 2, pp. 215–229
  6. ^ Goldstein (1971) pp.64–65
  7. ^ Childs (2003) pp.441–442
  8. ^ a b c d Goldstein (1971) pp.65–66
  9. ^ a b c d e Childs (2003) pp.427–428
  10. ^ Goldstein (1971) p.67
  11. ^ Laird (2006) p. 319
  12. ^ French p. 113
  13. ^ Goldstein 1989, p. 6
  14. ^ Goldstein 1989, p. 6-9
  15. ^ Goldstein 1987
  16. ^ Learn Chinese
  17. ^ Tibet's Material Wealth
  18. ^ Grunfeld, The Making of Modern Tibet (1996) pg. 15.
  19. ^ Charles Bell, Tibet Past and Present, Motilal Banarsidass Publ., 1992, 376 pages, pp. xviii and 78–79: "Slavery was not unknown in the Chumbi Valley during our occupation, but proximity to British India had greatly lessened the numbers of the slaves, so that only a dozen or two remained. Across the frontier in Bhutan there were a great many. / Slaves were sometimes stolen, when small children, from their parents. Or the father and mother being too poor to support their child, would sell it to a man, who paid them sho-ring, 'price of mother's milk', brought up the child and kept it, or sold it, as a slave. These children come mostly from south-eastern Tibet and the territories of the wild tribes who dwell between Tibet and Assam. / Two slaves whom I saw both appeared to have come from this tribal territory. They had been stolen from their parents when five years old, and sold in Lhasa for about seven pounds each. [...] / Slaves received food and clothing from their masters on the same scale as servants, but no pay. [...] / The slavery in the Chumpi valley was of a very mild type. If a slave was not well treated, it was easy for him to escape into Sikkim and British India."
  20. ^ a b "Acme of Obscenity". Retrieved 2015-05-25.

References edit

  • Childs, Geoff. 2003. "Polyandry and population growth in a Historical Tibetan Society", History of the Family, 8:423–444.
  • French, Rebecca (2002) The Golden Yoke, ISBN 1-55939-171-5
  • Goldstein, Melvyn C. (1971) "Stratification, Polyandry, and Family Structure in Central Tibet", Southwestern Journal of Anthropology, 27(1): 64–74.
  • Goldstein, Melvyn C. (1971) Serfdom and Mobility: An Examination of the Institution of "Human Lease" in Traditional Tibetan Society The Journal of Asian Studies, Vol. 30, No. 3, (May, 1971), pp. 521–534
  • Goldstein, Melvyn C. (1987) "Tibetan History and Social & Political Structure". Retrieved 2008-07-03.
  • Goldstein, Melvyn C. A History of Modern Tibet, 1913–1951: The Demise of the Lamaist State (1989) University of California Press. ISBN 978-0-520-06140-8
    • Goldstein, Melvyn C. A History of Modern Tibet, 1913–1951: The Demise of the Lamaist State (1989), first Indian edition (1993) Munshiram Manoharlal Publishers, New Delhi, ISBN 81-215-0582-8 Pagination is identical to University of California edition.
  • Grunfeld, A. Tom (1996) The making of Modern Tibet, Revised Edition, Armonk, New York: M. E. Sharpe, xvi + 352 p. ISBN 1-56324-713-5
    • Grunfield's work, which generally mirrors the Chinese government viewpoint, has been severely criticized by Tibetan critics, see "Acme of Obscenity: Tom Grunfeld and The Making of Modern Tibet" by Jamyang Norbu, 18 August 2008,
  • Laird, Thomas (2006) The Story of Tibet ISBN 0-8021-1827-5
  • Snellgrove, David; Hugh Richardson (1968). A Cultural History of Tibet. London: George Weidenfeld & Nicolson Ltd. ISBN 0-297-76317-2.

social, class, tibet, there, were, three, main, feudal, social, groups, tibet, prior, 1959, namely, ordinary, laypeople, tibetan, nobility, sger, monks, ordinary, layperson, could, further, classified, peasant, farmer, shing, citation, needed, nomadic, pastora. There were three main feudal social groups in Tibet prior to 1959 namely ordinary laypeople mi ser in Tibetan lay nobility sger pa and monks 1 The ordinary layperson could be further classified as a peasant farmer shing pa citation needed or nomadic pastoralist trokpa citation needed to influence politics and religious domination entering into monkhood and military was required Thubten Gyatso the 13th Dalai Lama photographed in Calcutta in 1910The Tsangpa Dynasty 1565 1642 and Ganden Phodrang 1642 1950 law codes distinguished three social divisions high medium and low Each in turn was divided into three classes to give nine classes in all Social status was a formal classification mostly hereditary and had legal consequences for example the compensation to be paid for the killing of a member of these classes varied from 5 for the lowest to 200 sung for the second highest the members of the noble families Nobles government officials and monks of pure conduct were in the high division only probably the Dalai Lama was in the very highest position The middle division contained a large portion of the population and ranged from minor government officials to taxpayer and landholding peasants to landless peasants Social mobility was possible in the middle division 2 The lower division contained ragyabpa of different types e g blacksmiths and butchers The very lowest class contained executioners and in the Tsang code bachelors and hermaphrodites 3 Anthropologists have presented different taxonomies for the middle social division in part because they studied specific regions of Tibet and the terms were not universal 4 5 6 7 Both Melvyn Goldstein and Geoff Childs however classified the population into three main types 8 9 taxpayer families tre ba 8 or khral pa 4 9 householders du jong 8 or dud chung ba 4 9 landless peasants mi bo 8 In the middle group the taxpaying families could be quite wealthy 10 Depending upon the district each category had different responsibilities in terms of tax and labor 11 Membership to each of these classes was primarily hereditary the linkage between subjects and their estate and overlord was similarly transmitted through parallel descent The taxpayer class although numerically smallest among the three subclasses occupied a superior position in terms of political and economic status The question of whether serfdom prevailed in traditional Tibetan society is controversial Heidi Fjeld no argues for a moderate position recognizing that serfdom existed but was not universal in Tibet Contents 1 The Higher Division 1 1 The Nobility 1 2 High Government and Monk Officials 2 The Middle Division 2 1 Taxpayer families 2 2 Householders 2 3 Landless peasants 3 The Lower Division 3 1 Ragyabpa 3 2 Nangzan Household servants 3 3 Slavery 4 Notes 5 ReferencesThe Higher Division editThe highest of the high class was empty or only contained possibly the Dalai Lama 3 The Nobility edit The middle class of the high division the highest attainable in practice was headed by the hereditary nobility Yabshi were thought to be descendants of the Dalai Lamas depon were descendants of the ancient royal families midak were on a slightly lower level 12 There were a small group of about 30 higher status families and 120 to 170 lower or common aristocratic families 13 High Government and Monk Officials edit High government officials were appointed from the aristocracy Monk officials were usually drawn from Lhasa middle classes the families of existing monk officials or were the second sons of the aristocracy They were usually monks in name only one night spent in a monastery being sufficient to qualify as a monk for this purpose 14 The Middle Division editTaxpayer families edit The treba also tralpa or khral pa taxpayers lived in corporate family units that hereditarily owned estates leased from their district authority complete with land titles In Goldstein s review of the Gyantse district he found that a taxpayer family typically owned from 20 acres 81 000 m2 to 300 acres 1 2 km2 of land each Their primary civil responsibility was to pay taxes tre ba and khral pa means taxpayer and to supply corvee services that included both human and animal labor to their district authority 9 They had a comfortable standard of living They also frequently practiced polyandry in marriage and other practices to maintain a single marriage per generation and avoid parceling land holdings Householders edit The householder class du jung dud chung ba 9 duiqoin duiqion duchung dudchhung duigoin or dujung comprised peasants who held only small plots of land that were legally and literally individual possessions This was different from the taxpayer families who owned land as a familial corporation Land inheritance rules for the householders were quite different from taxpayer family rules in that there was no certainty as to whether a plot of land would be inherited by his son The district authority either governmental monastic or aristocratic was the ultimate landowner and decided inheritance Compared to the taxpayer families the householders however had lighter tax obligations and only human labor corvee obligations to their district authorities These obligations unlike the taxpayer family obligations fell only on the individual and not on his family Landless peasants edit Landless peasants mi bo did not have heritable rights to land They were still obligated to their owning estate under their status as mi ser In contrast with the taxpayer families and householders they had the freedom to go wherever they wanted and could engage in trade or crafts 15 When farming they might lease land from taxpayer families and as payment take on work for those families Like the householders the landless peasants also used resources in their own individual capacity which were non heritable The relative freedom of the mi bo status was usually purchased by an annual fee to the estate to which the mi bo belonged The fee could be raised if the mi bo prospered and the lord could still exact special corvee labor e g for a special event The status could be revoked at the will of the estate owner The offspring of the mi bo did not automatically inherit the status of mi bo they did inherit the status of mi ser and could be indentured to service in their earlier teens or would have to pay their own mi bo fee 2 The Lower Division editRagyabpa edit The ragyabpa feudal class were at bottom level and they performed the unclean work This included fishermen butchers executioners corpse disposers blacksmiths goldsmiths and prostitutes Ragyabpa were also divided into three divisions for instance a goldsmith was in the highest at third feudal class and was not regarded as being as defiled as an executioner who was in the lowest Nangzan Household servants edit According to Chinese government sources Nangzan also nangzen nangzan nangsen were hereditary household servants comprising 5 of the population 16 17 Slavery edit According to American sinologist A Tom Grunfeld there were a few slaves in Tibet Grunfeld quotes Sir Charles Bell a British colonial official in the Chumbi Valley in the early 20th century and a Tibet scholar who wrote of slaves in the form of small children being stolen or bought from their parents too poor to support them to be brought up and kept or sold as slaves 18 These children came mostly from south eastern Tibet and the territories of the tribes that dwelt between Tibet and Assam 19 Grunfeld omits Bell s elaboration that in 1905 there were a dozen or two of these and that it was a very mild form of slavery 20 According to exile Tibetan writer Jamyang Norbu later accounts from Westerners who visited Tibet and even long term foreign residents such as Heinrich Harrer Peter Aufschnaiter Hugh Richardson and David Macdonald make no mention of any such practice which suggests that the 13th Dalai Lama may have eliminated this practice altogether in his reforms 20 Notes edit Snellgrove Cultural History pp 257 259 a b Goldstein 1986 a b French p 114 a b c Goldstein May 1971 p 524 Samuel Geoffrey Feb 1982 Tibet as a Stateless Society and Some Islamic Parallels The Journal of Asian Studies Vol 41 No 2 pp 215 229 Goldstein 1971 pp 64 65 Childs 2003 pp 441 442 a b c d Goldstein 1971 pp 65 66 a b c d e Childs 2003 pp 427 428 Goldstein 1971 p 67 Laird 2006 p 319 French p 113 Goldstein 1989 p 6 Goldstein 1989 p 6 9 Goldstein 1987 Learn Chinese Tibet s Material Wealth Grunfeld The Making of Modern Tibet 1996 pg 15 Charles Bell Tibet Past and Present Motilal Banarsidass Publ 1992 376 pages pp xviii and 78 79 Slavery was not unknown in the Chumbi Valley during our occupation but proximity to British India had greatly lessened the numbers of the slaves so that only a dozen or two remained Across the frontier in Bhutan there were a great many Slaves were sometimes stolen when small children from their parents Or the father and mother being too poor to support their child would sell it to a man who paid them sho ring price of mother s milk brought up the child and kept it or sold it as a slave These children come mostly from south eastern Tibet and the territories of the wild tribes who dwell between Tibet and Assam Two slaves whom I saw both appeared to have come from this tribal territory They had been stolen from their parents when five years old and sold in Lhasa for about seven pounds each Slaves received food and clothing from their masters on the same scale as servants but no pay The slavery in the Chumpi valley was of a very mild type If a slave was not well treated it was easy for him to escape into Sikkim and British India a b Acme of Obscenity Retrieved 2015 05 25 References editChilds Geoff 2003 Polyandry and population growth in a Historical Tibetan Society History of the Family 8 423 444 French Rebecca 2002 The Golden Yoke ISBN 1 55939 171 5 Goldstein Melvyn C 1971 Stratification Polyandry and Family Structure in Central Tibet Southwestern Journal of Anthropology 27 1 64 74 Goldstein Melvyn C 1971 Serfdom and Mobility An Examination of the Institution of Human Lease in Traditional Tibetan Society The Journal of Asian Studies Vol 30 No 3 May 1971 pp 521 534 Goldstein Melvyn C 1987 Tibetan History and Social amp Political Structure Retrieved 2008 07 03 Goldstein Melvyn C A History of Modern Tibet 1913 1951 The Demise of the Lamaist State 1989 University of California Press ISBN 978 0 520 06140 8 Goldstein Melvyn C A History of Modern Tibet 1913 1951 The Demise of the Lamaist State 1989 first Indian edition 1993 Munshiram Manoharlal Publishers New Delhi ISBN 81 215 0582 8 Pagination is identical to University of California edition Grunfeld A Tom 1996 The making of Modern Tibet Revised Edition Armonk New York M E Sharpe xvi 352 p ISBN 1 56324 713 5 Grunfield s work which generally mirrors the Chinese government viewpoint has been severely criticized by Tibetan critics see Acme of Obscenity Tom Grunfeld and The Making of Modern Tibet by Jamyang Norbu 18 August 2008 Laird Thomas 2006 The Story of Tibet ISBN 0 8021 1827 5 Snellgrove David Hugh Richardson 1968 A Cultural History of Tibet London George Weidenfeld amp Nicolson Ltd ISBN 0 297 76317 2 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Social class in Tibet amp oldid 1199234853, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.