fbpx
Wikipedia

Selfridge–Conway procedure

The Selfridge–Conway procedure is a discrete procedure that produces an envy-free cake-cutting for three partners.[1]: 13–14  It is named after John Selfridge and John Horton Conway. Selfridge discovered it in 1960, and told it to Richard Guy, who told many people, but Selfridge did not publish it. John Conway later discovered it independently, and also never published it.[2] This procedure was the first envy-free discrete procedure devised for three partners, and it paved the way for more advanced procedures for n partners (see envy-free cake-cutting).

A procedure is envy-free if each recipient believes that (according to their own measure) no other recipient has received a larger share. The maximal number of cuts in the procedure is five. The pieces are not always contiguous.

The Procedure edit

 
Selfridge–Conway division

Suppose we have three players P1, P2 and P3. Where the procedure gives a criterion for a decision it means that criterion gives an optimum choice for the player.

  1. P1 divides the cake into three pieces they consider of equal size.
  2. Let's call A the largest piece according to P2.
  3. P2 cuts off a bit of A to make it the same size as the second largest. Now A is divided into: the trimmed piece A1 and the trimmings A2. Leave the trimmings A2 to the side for now.
    • If P2 thinks that the two largest parts are equal (such that no trimming is needed), then each player chooses a part in this order: P3, P2 and finally P1.
  4. P3 chooses a piece among A1 and the two other pieces.
  5. P2 chooses a piece with the limitation that if P3 didn't choose A1, P2 must choose it.
  6. P1 chooses the last piece leaving just the trimmings A2 to be divided.

It remains to divide the trimmings A2. The trimmed piece A1 has been chosen by either P2 or P3; let's call the player who chose it PA and the other player PB.

  1. PB cuts A2 into three equal pieces.
  2. PA chooses a piece of A2 - we name it A21.
  3. P1 chooses a piece of A2 - we name it A22.
  4. PB chooses the last remaining piece of A2 - we name it A23.

Analysis edit

Let's see why the procedure is envy-free. It must be shown that each player believes that no other player received a larger share. Without loss of generality, we can write (see illustration above):

  • PA received: A1 + A21.
  • PB received: B + A23.
  • P1 received: C + A22.

In the following analysis "largest" means "largest according to that player":

  • PA received A1 + A21. For them, A1 ≥ B and A1 ≥ C. And they consider their choice A21 to be the largest piece of A2. So no other player received a larger share: A1 + A21  ≥  B + A23, C + A22.
  • PB received B + A23. For them, B ≥ A1 and B ≥ C since they chose B. Also, they are the one that cut A2 in 3 pieces, so for them all those pieces are equal.
  • P1 received C + A22. For them, C ≥ A1 and C = B.
    • P1 believes that PB didn't receive a larger share. In other words: C + A22  ≥ B + A23. Remember that P1 chose their piece of A2 before PB, thus A22  ≥ A23 in their view.
    • P1 believes that PA didn't receive a larger share. In other words: C + A22  ≥ A1 + A21. Remember that for P1, C is equal to A since they cut the cake in the first round. Also, A = A1 + A2 = A1 + (A21 + A22 + A23); therefore C  ≥ A1 + A21. (Even if PA took the whole A2 and P1 did not receive A22, P1 would not envy PA.)

Generalizations edit

Note that if all we want is an envy-free division for a part of the cake (i.e. we allow free disposal), then we only need to use the first part of the Selfridge–Conway procedure, i.e.:

  • P1 divides the cake into three equal pieces;
  • P2 trims at most one piece such that the two largest pieces are equal;
  • P3 takes a piece, then P2, then P1.

This guarantees that there is no envy.

This procedure can be generalized to 4 partners in the following way:[3]

  • P1 divides the cake into 5 equal pieces;
  • P2 trims at most 2 pieces, such that the 3 largest pieces are equal;
  • P3 trims at most 1 piece, such that the 2 largest pieces are equal;
  • P4 takes a piece, then P3, then P2, then P1.

This guarantees that there is no envy.

By induction, the procedure can be generalized to n partners, the first one dividing the cake to   equal pieces and the other partners follow by trimming. The resulting division is envy-free.

We can apply the same procedure again on the remainders. By doing so an infinite number of times, we get an envy-free division of the entire cake.[4] A refinement of this infinite procedure yields a finite envy-free division procedure: the Brams–Taylor procedure.

References edit

  1. ^ Robertson, Jack; Webb, William (1998). Cake-Cutting Algorithms: Be Fair If You Can. Natick, Massachusetts: A. K. Peters. ISBN 978-1-56881-076-8. LCCN 97041258. OL 2730675W.
  2. ^ Brams, Steven J.; Taylor, Alan D. (1996). Fair Division [From cake-cutting to dispute resolution]. pp. 116–120. ISBN 0521556449.
  3. ^ Brams, Steven J.; Taylor, Alan D. (1996). Fair Division [From cake-cutting to dispute resolution]. pp. 131–137. ISBN 0521556449.
  4. ^ Brams, Steven J.; Taylor, Alan D. (1996). Fair Division [From cake-cutting to dispute resolution]. p. 137. ISBN 0521556449.

selfridge, conway, procedure, discrete, procedure, that, produces, envy, free, cake, cutting, three, partners, named, after, john, selfridge, john, horton, conway, selfridge, discovered, 1960, told, richard, told, many, people, selfridge, publish, john, conway. The Selfridge Conway procedure is a discrete procedure that produces an envy free cake cutting for three partners 1 13 14 It is named after John Selfridge and John Horton Conway Selfridge discovered it in 1960 and told it to Richard Guy who told many people but Selfridge did not publish it John Conway later discovered it independently and also never published it 2 This procedure was the first envy free discrete procedure devised for three partners and it paved the way for more advanced procedures for n partners see envy free cake cutting A procedure is envy free if each recipient believes that according to their own measure no other recipient has received a larger share The maximal number of cuts in the procedure is five The pieces are not always contiguous Contents 1 The Procedure 2 Analysis 3 Generalizations 4 ReferencesThe Procedure edit nbsp Selfridge Conway divisionSuppose we have three players P1 P2 and P3 Where the procedure gives a criterion for a decision it means that criterion gives an optimum choice for the player P1 divides the cake into three pieces they consider of equal size Let s call A the largest piece according to P2 P2 cuts off a bit of A to make it the same size as the second largest Now A is divided into the trimmed piece A1 and the trimmings A2 Leave the trimmings A2 to the side for now If P2 thinks that the two largest parts are equal such that no trimming is needed then each player chooses a part in this order P3 P2 and finally P1 P3 chooses a piece among A1 and the two other pieces P2 chooses a piece with the limitation that if P3 didn t choose A1 P2 must choose it P1 chooses the last piece leaving just the trimmings A2 to be divided It remains to divide the trimmings A2 The trimmed piece A1 has been chosen by either P2 or P3 let s call the player who chose it PA and the other player PB PB cuts A2 into three equal pieces PA chooses a piece of A2 we name it A21 P1 chooses a piece of A2 we name it A22 PB chooses the last remaining piece of A2 we name it A23 Analysis editLet s see why the procedure is envy free It must be shown that each player believes that no other player received a larger share Without loss of generality we can write see illustration above PA received A1 A21 PB received B A23 P1 received C A22 In the following analysis largest means largest according to that player PA received A1 A21 For them A1 B and A1 C And they consider their choice A21 to be the largest piece of A2 So no other player received a larger share A1 A21 B A23 C A22 PB received B A23 For them B A1 and B C since they chose B Also they are the one that cut A2 in 3 pieces so for them all those pieces are equal P1 received C A22 For them C A1 and C B P1 believes that PB didn t receive a larger share In other words C A22 B A23 Remember that P1 chose their piece of A2 before PB thus A22 A23 in their view P1 believes that PA didn t receive a larger share In other words C A22 A1 A21 Remember that for P1 C is equal to A since they cut the cake in the first round Also A A1 A2 A1 A21 A22 A23 therefore C A1 A21 Even if PA took the whole A2 and P1 did not receive A22 P1 would not envy PA Generalizations editNote that if all we want is an envy free division for a part of the cake i e we allow free disposal then we only need to use the first part of the Selfridge Conway procedure i e P1 divides the cake into three equal pieces P2 trims at most one piece such that the two largest pieces are equal P3 takes a piece then P2 then P1 This guarantees that there is no envy This procedure can be generalized to 4 partners in the following way 3 P1 divides the cake into 5 equal pieces P2 trims at most 2 pieces such that the 3 largest pieces are equal P3 trims at most 1 piece such that the 2 largest pieces are equal P4 takes a piece then P3 then P2 then P1 This guarantees that there is no envy By induction the procedure can be generalized to n partners the first one dividing the cake to 2n 2 1 displaystyle 2 n 2 1 nbsp equal pieces and the other partners follow by trimming The resulting division is envy free We can apply the same procedure again on the remainders By doing so an infinite number of times we get an envy free division of the entire cake 4 A refinement of this infinite procedure yields a finite envy free division procedure the Brams Taylor procedure References edit Robertson Jack Webb William 1998 Cake Cutting Algorithms Be Fair If You Can Natick Massachusetts A K Peters ISBN 978 1 56881 076 8 LCCN 97041258 OL 2730675W Brams Steven J Taylor Alan D 1996 Fair Division From cake cutting to dispute resolution pp 116 120 ISBN 0521556449 Brams Steven J Taylor Alan D 1996 Fair Division From cake cutting to dispute resolution pp 131 137 ISBN 0521556449 Brams Steven J Taylor Alan D 1996 Fair Division From cake cutting to dispute resolution p 137 ISBN 0521556449 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Selfridge Conway procedure amp oldid 1215069396, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.