fbpx
Wikipedia

Demand for money

In monetary economics, the demand for money is the desired holding of financial assets in the form of money: that is, cash or bank deposits rather than investments. It can refer to the demand for money narrowly defined as M1 (directly spendable holdings), or for money in the broader sense of M2 or M3.

Money in the sense of M1 is dominated as a store of value (even a temporary one) by interest-bearing assets. However, M1 is necessary to carry out transactions; in other words, it provides liquidity. This creates a trade-off between the liquidity advantage of holding money for near-future expenditure and the interest advantage of temporarily holding other assets. The demand for M1 is a result of this trade-off regarding the form in which a person's funds to be spent should be held. In macroeconomics motivations for holding one's wealth in the form of M1 can roughly be divided into the transaction motive and the precautionary motive. The demand for those parts of the broader money concept M2 that bear a non-trivial interest rate is based on the asset demand. These can be further subdivided into more microeconomically founded motivations for holding money.

Generally, the nominal demand for money increases with the level of nominal output (price level times real output) and decreases with the nominal interest rate. The real demand for money is defined as the nominal amount of money demanded divided by the price level. For a given money supply the locus of income-interest rate pairs at which money demand equals money supply is known as the LM curve.

The magnitude of the volatility of money demand has crucial implications for the optimal way in which a central bank should carry out monetary policy and its choice of a nominal anchor.

Conditions under which the LM curve is flat, so that increases in the money supply have no stimulatory effect (a liquidity trap), play an important role in Keynesian theory. This situation occurs when the demand for money is infinitely elastic with respect to the interest rate.

A typical money-demand function may be written as

where is the nominal amount of money demanded, P is the price level, R is the nominal interest rate, Y is real income, and L(.) is real money demand. An alternate name for is the liquidity preference function.

Motives for holding money

Transaction motive

The transactions motive for the demand for M1 (directly spendable money balances) results from the need for liquidity for day-to-day transactions in the near future. This need arises when income is received only occasionally (say once per month) in discrete amounts but expenditures occur continuously.

Quantity theory

The most basic "classical" transaction motive can be illustrated with reference to the Quantity Theory of Money.[1] According to the equation of exchange MV = PY, where M is the stock of money, V is its velocity (how many times a unit of money turns over during a period of time), P is the price level and Y is real income. Consequently, PY is nominal income or in other words the number of transactions carried out in an economy during a period of time. Rearranging the above identity and giving it a behavioral interpretation as a demand for money we have

 

or in terms of demand for real balances

 

Hence in this simple formulation demand for money is a function of prices and income, as long as its velocity is constant.

Inventory models

The amount of money demanded for transactions however is also likely to depend on the nominal interest rate. This arises due to the lack of synchronization in time between when purchases are desired and when factor payments (such as wages) are made. In other words, while workers may get paid only once a month they generally will wish to make purchases, and hence need money, over the course of the entire month.

The most well-known example of an economic model that is based on such considerations is the Baumol-Tobin model.[2] In this model an individual receives her income periodically, for example, only once per month, but wishes to make purchases continuously. The person could carry her entire income with her at all times and use it to make purchases. However, in this case she would be giving up the (nominal) interest rate that she can get by holding her income in the bank. The optimal strategy involves holding a portion of one's income in the bank and portion as liquid money. The money portion is continuously run down as the individual makes purchases and then she makes periodic (costly) trips to the bank to replenish the holdings of money. Under some simplifying assumptions the demand for money resulting from the Baumol-Tobin model is given by

 

where t is the cost of a trip to the bank, R is the nominal interest rate and P and Y are as before.

The key difference between this formulation and the one based on a simple version of Quantity Theory is that now the demand for real balances depends on both income (positively) or the desired level of transactions, and on the nominal interest rate (negatively).

Microfoundations for money demand

While the Baumol–Tobin model provides a microeconomic explanation for the form of the money demand function, it is generally too stylized to be included in modern macroeconomic models, particularly dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. As a result, most models of this type resort to simpler indirect methods which capture the spirit of the transactions motive. The two most commonly used methods are the cash-in-advance model (sometimes called the Clower constraint model) and the money-in-the-utility-function (MIU) model (as known as the Sidrauski model).[3]

In the cash-in-advance model agents are restricted to carrying out a volume of transactions equal to or less than their money holdings. In the MIU model, money directly enters agents' utility functions, capturing the 'liquidity services' provided by money.[4][5][6]

Precautionary demand

The precautionary demand for M1 is the holding of transaction funds for use if unexpected needs for immediate expenditure arise.

Asset motive

The asset motive for the demand for broader monetary measures, M2 and M3, states that people demand money as a way to hold wealth. While it is still assumed that money in the sense of M1 is held in order to carry out transactions, this approach focuses on the potential return on various assets (including money broadly defined) as an additional motivation.

Speculative motive

John Maynard Keynes, in laying out speculative reasons for holding money, stressed the choice between money and bonds. If agents expect the future nominal interest rate (the return on bonds) to be lower than the current rate they will then reduce their holdings of money and increase their holdings of bonds. If the future interest rate falls, then the price of bonds will increase and the agents will have realized a capital gain on the bonds they purchased. This means that the demand for money in any period will depend on both the current nominal interest rate and the expected future interest rate (in addition to the standard transaction motives which depend on income).

The fact that the current demand for money can depend on expectations of the future interest rates has implications for volatility of money demand. If these expectations are formed, as in Keynes' view, by "animal spirits" they are likely to change erratically and cause money demand to be quite unstable.

Portfolio motive

The portfolio motive also focuses on demand for money over and above that required for carrying out transactions. The basic framework is due to James Tobin, who considered a situation where agents can hold their wealth in a form of a low risk/low return asset (here, money) or high risk/high return asset (bonds or equity). Agents will choose a mix of these two types of assets (their portfolio) based on the risk-expected return trade-off. For a given expected rate of return, more risk averse individuals will choose a greater share for money in their portfolio. Similarly, given a person's degree of risk aversion, a higher expected return (nominal interest rate plus expected capital gains on bonds) will cause agents to shift away from safe money and into risky assets. Like in the other motivations above, this creates a negative relationship between the nominal interest rate and the demand for money. However, what matters additionally in the Tobin model is the subjective rate of risk aversion, as well as the objective degree of risk of other assets, as, say, measured by the standard deviation of capital gains and losses resulting from holding bonds and/or equity.

Empirical estimations of money demand functions

Is money demand stable?

Friedman and Schwartz in their 1963 work A Monetary History of the United States argued that the demand for real balances was a function of income and the interest rate. For the time period they were studying this appeared to be true. However, shortly after the publication of the book, due to changes in financial markets and financial regulation money demand became more unstable. Various researchers showed that money demand became much more unstable after 1975. Ericsson, Hendry and Prestwich (1998) consider a model of money demand based on the various motives outlined above and test it with empirical data. The basic model turns out to work well for the period 1878 to 1975 and there doesn't appear to be much volatility in money demand, in a result analogous to that of Friedman and Schwartz. This is true even despite the fact that the two world wars during this time period could have led to changes in the velocity of money. However, when the same basic model is used on data spanning 1976 to 1993, it performs poorly. In particular, money demand appears not to be sensitive to interest rates and there appears to be much more exogenous volatility. The authors attribute the difference to technological innovations in the financial markets, financial deregulation, and the related issue of the changing menu of assets considered in the definition of money. Other researchers confirmed this finding with recent data and over a longer period. Money demand appears to be time varying which also depends on household's real balance effects.[7]

Laurence M. Ball suggests that the use of adapted aggregates, such as near monies, can produce a more stable demand function. He shows that using the return on near monies produced smaller deviations than previous models.[8]

Importance of money demand volatility for monetary policy

If the demand for money is stable then a monetary policy which consists of a monetary rule which targets the growth rate of some monetary aggregate (such as M1 or M2) can help to stabilize the economy or at least remove monetary policy as a source of macroeconomic volatility. Additionally, if the demand for money does not change unpredictably then money supply targeting is a reliable way of attaining a constant inflation rate. This can be most easily seen with the quantity theory of money equation given above. When that equation is converted into growth rates we have:

 

which says that the growth rate of money supply plus the growth rate of its velocity equals the inflation rate plus the growth rate of real output. If money demand is stable then velocity is constant and  . Additionally, in the long run real output grows at a constant rate equal to the sum of the rates of growth of population, technological know-how, and technology in place, and as such is exogenous. In this case the above equation can be solved for the inflation rate:

 

Here, given the long-run output growth rate, the only determinant of the inflation rate is the growth rate of the money supply. In this case inflation in the long run is a purely monetary phenomenon; a monetary policy which targets the money supply can stabilize the economy and ensure a non-variable inflation rate.

This analysis however breaks down if the demand for money is not stable – for example, if velocity in the above equation is not constant. In that case, shocks to money demand under money supply targeting will translate into changes in real and nominal interest rates and result in economic fluctuations. An alternative policy of targeting interest rates rather than the money supply can improve upon this outcome as the money supply is adjusted to shocks in money demand, keeping interest rates (and hence, economic activity) relatively constant.

The above discussion implies that the volatility of money demand matters for how monetary policy should be conducted. If most of the aggregate demand shocks which affect the economy come from the expenditure side, the IS curve, then a policy of targeting the money supply will be stabilizing, relative to a policy of targeting interest rates. However, if most of the aggregate demand shocks come from changes in money demand, which influences the LM curve, then a policy of targeting the money supply will be destabilizing.

See also

References

  1. ^ Friedman, Milton (2005). The Optimum Quantity of Money. Aldine Transaction. p. 308. ISBN 1412804779.
  2. ^ Baumol, William J. (1952). "The transactions demand for cash: an inventory theoretic approach". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 66 (4): 545–556. doi:10.2307/1882104. JSTOR 1882104. S2CID 154974605.
  3. ^ Walsh, Carl E. (1998). "Money in a General Equilibrium Framework". Monetary Theory and Policy. Cambridge: The MIT Press. pp. 41–92. ISBN 978-0-262-23199-2.
  4. ^ Benchimol, Jonathan; Fourçans, André (2012). "Money and Risk in a DSGE Framework : A Bayesian Application to the Eurozone". Journal of Macroeconomics. 34 (1): 95–111. doi:10.1016/j.jmacro.2011.10.003. S2CID 153669907.
  5. ^ Benchimol, Jonathan (2015). "Money in the production function: a new Keynesian DSGE perspective" (PDF). Southern Economic Journal. 82 (1): 152–184. doi:10.4284/0038-4038-2011.197. S2CID 13749518.
  6. ^ Benchimol, Jonathan (2016). "Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade" (PDF). Journal of Policy Modeling. 38 (1): 103–124. doi:10.1016/j.jpolmod.2015.12.007. S2CID 54847945.
  7. ^ Benchimol, Jonathan; Qureshi, Irfan (2020). "Time-varying money demand and real balance effects" (PDF). Economic Modelling. 87 (1): 197–211. doi:10.1016/j.econmod.2019.07.020.
  8. ^ Ball, Laurence (2012). "Short-run money demand". Journal of Monetary Economics. 59 (7): 622–633. doi:10.1016/j.jmoneco.2012.09.004. S2CID 614007.
  • Friedman, Milton (1956). "The Quantity Theory of Money: A Restatement," in Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, Chicago. Reprinted in The Optimum Quantity of Money (2005), pp. 51-67.
  • Goldfeld, Stephen M., and Daniel E. Sichel (1990). "The Demand for Money," in Handbook of Monetary Economics, v. 1, pp. 299–356. Elsevier.
  • Judd, John P., and John L. Scadding (1982). "The Search for a Stable Money Demand Function: A Survey of the Post-1973 Literature," Journal of Economic Literature, 20(3), p p. 993-1023.
  • Keynes, John Maynard (1923). A Tract on Monetary Reform. Macmillan. Reviews, 1924 & .
  • _____ (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Macmillan, ch. 15, "The Psychological and Business Incentives To Liquidity"[1]
  • Laidler, David E.W. (1993). The Demand for Money: Theories, Evidence, and Problems, 4th ed. Description.
  • Sriram, Subramanian S. (2001). "A Survey of Recent Empirical Money Demand Studies," IMF Staff Papers, 47(3). International Monetary Fund. pp. 334–65 (press +).
  • Tobin, James (1956). "The Interest-Elasticity of Transactions Demand For Cash," Review of Economics and Statistics, 38(3), pp. 241–247[permanent dead link] (press +). Reprinted in Tobin, Essays in Economics, v. 1, Macroeconomics, pp. 229- 242.
  • ____ (1958). "Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk," Review of Economic Studies 25(1), pp. 65–86 (press +).

demand, money, monetary, economics, demand, money, desired, holding, financial, assets, form, money, that, cash, bank, deposits, rather, than, investments, refer, demand, money, narrowly, defined, directly, spendable, holdings, money, broader, sense, money, se. In monetary economics the demand for money is the desired holding of financial assets in the form of money that is cash or bank deposits rather than investments It can refer to the demand for money narrowly defined as M1 directly spendable holdings or for money in the broader sense of M2 or M3 Money in the sense of M1 is dominated as a store of value even a temporary one by interest bearing assets However M1 is necessary to carry out transactions in other words it provides liquidity This creates a trade off between the liquidity advantage of holding money for near future expenditure and the interest advantage of temporarily holding other assets The demand for M1 is a result of this trade off regarding the form in which a person s funds to be spent should be held In macroeconomics motivations for holding one s wealth in the form of M1 can roughly be divided into the transaction motive and the precautionary motive The demand for those parts of the broader money concept M2 that bear a non trivial interest rate is based on the asset demand These can be further subdivided into more microeconomically founded motivations for holding money Generally the nominal demand for money increases with the level of nominal output price level times real output and decreases with the nominal interest rate The real demand for money is defined as the nominal amount of money demanded divided by the price level For a given money supply the locus of income interest rate pairs at which money demand equals money supply is known as the LM curve The magnitude of the volatility of money demand has crucial implications for the optimal way in which a central bank should carry out monetary policy and its choice of a nominal anchor Conditions under which the LM curve is flat so that increases in the money supply have no stimulatory effect a liquidity trap play an important role in Keynesian theory This situation occurs when the demand for money is infinitely elastic with respect to the interest rate A typical money demand function may be written as M d P L R Y displaystyle M d P times L R Y where M d displaystyle M d is the nominal amount of money demanded P is the price level R is the nominal interest rate Y is real income and L is real money demand An alternate name for L R Y displaystyle L R Y is the liquidity preference function Contents 1 Motives for holding money 1 1 Transaction motive 1 1 1 Quantity theory 1 1 2 Inventory models 1 1 3 Microfoundations for money demand 1 2 Precautionary demand 1 3 Asset motive 1 3 1 Speculative motive 1 3 2 Portfolio motive 2 Empirical estimations of money demand functions 2 1 Is money demand stable 3 Importance of money demand volatility for monetary policy 4 See also 5 ReferencesMotives for holding money EditTransaction motive Edit Main article Transactions demand The transactions motive for the demand for M1 directly spendable money balances results from the need for liquidity for day to day transactions in the near future This need arises when income is received only occasionally say once per month in discrete amounts but expenditures occur continuously Quantity theory Edit The most basic classical transaction motive can be illustrated with reference to the Quantity Theory of Money 1 According to the equation of exchange MV PY where M is the stock of money V is its velocity how many times a unit of money turns over during a period of time P is the price level and Y is real income Consequently PY is nominal income or in other words the number of transactions carried out in an economy during a period of time Rearranging the above identity and giving it a behavioral interpretation as a demand for money we have M d P Y V displaystyle M d P frac Y V or in terms of demand for real balances M d P Y V displaystyle frac M d P frac Y V Hence in this simple formulation demand for money is a function of prices and income as long as its velocity is constant Inventory models Edit The amount of money demanded for transactions however is also likely to depend on the nominal interest rate This arises due to the lack of synchronization in time between when purchases are desired and when factor payments such as wages are made In other words while workers may get paid only once a month they generally will wish to make purchases and hence need money over the course of the entire month The most well known example of an economic model that is based on such considerations is the Baumol Tobin model 2 In this model an individual receives her income periodically for example only once per month but wishes to make purchases continuously The person could carry her entire income with her at all times and use it to make purchases However in this case she would be giving up the nominal interest rate that she can get by holding her income in the bank The optimal strategy involves holding a portion of one s income in the bank and portion as liquid money The money portion is continuously run down as the individual makes purchases and then she makes periodic costly trips to the bank to replenish the holdings of money Under some simplifying assumptions the demand for money resulting from the Baumol Tobin model is given by M d P t Y 2 R displaystyle frac M d P sqrt frac tY 2R where t is the cost of a trip to the bank R is the nominal interest rate and P and Y are as before The key difference between this formulation and the one based on a simple version of Quantity Theory is that now the demand for real balances depends on both income positively or the desired level of transactions and on the nominal interest rate negatively Microfoundations for money demand Edit While the Baumol Tobin model provides a microeconomic explanation for the form of the money demand function it is generally too stylized to be included in modern macroeconomic models particularly dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models As a result most models of this type resort to simpler indirect methods which capture the spirit of the transactions motive The two most commonly used methods are the cash in advance model sometimes called the Clower constraint model and the money in the utility function MIU model as known as the Sidrauski model 3 In the cash in advance model agents are restricted to carrying out a volume of transactions equal to or less than their money holdings In the MIU model money directly enters agents utility functions capturing the liquidity services provided by money 4 5 6 Precautionary demand Edit Main article Precautionary demand The precautionary demand for M1 is the holding of transaction funds for use if unexpected needs for immediate expenditure arise Asset motive Edit The asset motive for the demand for broader monetary measures M2 and M3 states that people demand money as a way to hold wealth While it is still assumed that money in the sense of M1 is held in order to carry out transactions this approach focuses on the potential return on various assets including money broadly defined as an additional motivation Speculative motive Edit Main article Speculative demand for money John Maynard Keynes in laying out speculative reasons for holding money stressed the choice between money and bonds If agents expect the future nominal interest rate the return on bonds to be lower than the current rate they will then reduce their holdings of money and increase their holdings of bonds If the future interest rate falls then the price of bonds will increase and the agents will have realized a capital gain on the bonds they purchased This means that the demand for money in any period will depend on both the current nominal interest rate and the expected future interest rate in addition to the standard transaction motives which depend on income The fact that the current demand for money can depend on expectations of the future interest rates has implications for volatility of money demand If these expectations are formed as in Keynes view by animal spirits they are likely to change erratically and cause money demand to be quite unstable Portfolio motive Edit The portfolio motive also focuses on demand for money over and above that required for carrying out transactions The basic framework is due to James Tobin who considered a situation where agents can hold their wealth in a form of a low risk low return asset here money or high risk high return asset bonds or equity Agents will choose a mix of these two types of assets their portfolio based on the risk expected return trade off For a given expected rate of return more risk averse individuals will choose a greater share for money in their portfolio Similarly given a person s degree of risk aversion a higher expected return nominal interest rate plus expected capital gains on bonds will cause agents to shift away from safe money and into risky assets Like in the other motivations above this creates a negative relationship between the nominal interest rate and the demand for money However what matters additionally in the Tobin model is the subjective rate of risk aversion as well as the objective degree of risk of other assets as say measured by the standard deviation of capital gains and losses resulting from holding bonds and or equity Empirical estimations of money demand functions EditIs money demand stable Edit Friedman and Schwartz in their 1963 work A Monetary History of the United States argued that the demand for real balances was a function of income and the interest rate For the time period they were studying this appeared to be true However shortly after the publication of the book due to changes in financial markets and financial regulation money demand became more unstable Various researchers showed that money demand became much more unstable after 1975 Ericsson Hendry and Prestwich 1998 consider a model of money demand based on the various motives outlined above and test it with empirical data The basic model turns out to work well for the period 1878 to 1975 and there doesn t appear to be much volatility in money demand in a result analogous to that of Friedman and Schwartz This is true even despite the fact that the two world wars during this time period could have led to changes in the velocity of money However when the same basic model is used on data spanning 1976 to 1993 it performs poorly In particular money demand appears not to be sensitive to interest rates and there appears to be much more exogenous volatility The authors attribute the difference to technological innovations in the financial markets financial deregulation and the related issue of the changing menu of assets considered in the definition of money Other researchers confirmed this finding with recent data and over a longer period Money demand appears to be time varying which also depends on household s real balance effects 7 Laurence M Ball suggests that the use of adapted aggregates such as near monies can produce a more stable demand function He shows that using the return on near monies produced smaller deviations than previous models 8 Importance of money demand volatility for monetary policy EditIf the demand for money is stable then a monetary policy which consists of a monetary rule which targets the growth rate of some monetary aggregate such as M1 or M2 can help to stabilize the economy or at least remove monetary policy as a source of macroeconomic volatility Additionally if the demand for money does not change unpredictably then money supply targeting is a reliable way of attaining a constant inflation rate This can be most easily seen with the quantity theory of money equation given above When that equation is converted into growth rates we have g m g v p g y displaystyle g m g v pi g y which says that the growth rate of money supply plus the growth rate of its velocity equals the inflation rate plus the growth rate of real output If money demand is stable then velocity is constant and g v 0 displaystyle g v 0 Additionally in the long run real output grows at a constant rate equal to the sum of the rates of growth of population technological know how and technology in place and as such is exogenous In this case the above equation can be solved for the inflation rate p g y g m displaystyle pi g y g m Here given the long run output growth rate the only determinant of the inflation rate is the growth rate of the money supply In this case inflation in the long run is a purely monetary phenomenon a monetary policy which targets the money supply can stabilize the economy and ensure a non variable inflation rate This analysis however breaks down if the demand for money is not stable for example if velocity in the above equation is not constant In that case shocks to money demand under money supply targeting will translate into changes in real and nominal interest rates and result in economic fluctuations An alternative policy of targeting interest rates rather than the money supply can improve upon this outcome as the money supply is adjusted to shocks in money demand keeping interest rates and hence economic activity relatively constant The above discussion implies that the volatility of money demand matters for how monetary policy should be conducted If most of the aggregate demand shocks which affect the economy come from the expenditure side the IS curve then a policy of targeting the money supply will be stabilizing relative to a policy of targeting interest rates However if most of the aggregate demand shocks come from changes in money demand which influences the LM curve then a policy of targeting the money supply will be destabilizing See also EditChartalism Diamond Dybvig model Money creation Money marketReferences Edit Friedman Milton 2005 The Optimum Quantity of Money Aldine Transaction p 308 ISBN 1412804779 Baumol William J 1952 The transactions demand for cash an inventory theoretic approach Quarterly Journal of Economics 66 4 545 556 doi 10 2307 1882104 JSTOR 1882104 S2CID 154974605 Walsh Carl E 1998 Money in a General Equilibrium Framework Monetary Theory and Policy Cambridge The MIT Press pp 41 92 ISBN 978 0 262 23199 2 Benchimol Jonathan Fourcans Andre 2012 Money and Risk in a DSGE Framework A Bayesian Application to the Eurozone Journal of Macroeconomics 34 1 95 111 doi 10 1016 j jmacro 2011 10 003 S2CID 153669907 Benchimol Jonathan 2015 Money in the production function a new Keynesian DSGE perspective PDF Southern Economic Journal 82 1 152 184 doi 10 4284 0038 4038 2011 197 S2CID 13749518 Benchimol Jonathan 2016 Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade PDF Journal of Policy Modeling 38 1 103 124 doi 10 1016 j jpolmod 2015 12 007 S2CID 54847945 Benchimol Jonathan Qureshi Irfan 2020 Time varying money demand and real balance effects PDF Economic Modelling 87 1 197 211 doi 10 1016 j econmod 2019 07 020 Ball Laurence 2012 Short run money demand Journal of Monetary Economics 59 7 622 633 doi 10 1016 j jmoneco 2012 09 004 S2CID 614007 Friedman Milton 1956 The Quantity Theory of Money A Restatement in Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money Chicago Reprinted in The Optimum Quantity of Money 2005 pp 51 67 Goldfeld Stephen M and Daniel E Sichel 1990 The Demand for Money in Handbook of Monetary Economics v 1 pp 299 356 Introduction Elsevier Judd John P and John L Scadding 1982 The Search for a Stable Money Demand Function A Survey of the Post 1973 Literature Journal of Economic Literature 20 3 p p 993 1023 Keynes John Maynard 1923 A Tract on Monetary Reform Macmillan Reviews 1924 amp 1996 1936 The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money Macmillan ch 15 The Psychological and Business Incentives To Liquidity 1 Laidler David E W 1993 The Demand for Money Theories Evidence and Problems 4th ed Description Sriram Subramanian S 2001 A Survey of Recent Empirical Money Demand Studies IMF Staff Papers 47 3 International Monetary Fund pp 334 65 press Tobin James 1956 The Interest Elasticity of Transactions Demand For Cash Review of Economics and Statistics 38 3 pp 241 247 permanent dead link press Reprinted in Tobin Essays in Economics v 1 Macroeconomics pp 229 242 1958 Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk Review of Economic Studies 25 1 pp 65 86 press Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Demand for money amp oldid 1124491093, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.