fbpx
Wikipedia

Involuntary unemployment

Involuntary unemployment occurs when a person is unemployed despite being willing to work at the prevailing wage. It is distinguished from voluntary unemployment, where a person chooses not to work because their reservation wage is higher than the prevailing wage. In an economy with involuntary unemployment, there is a surplus of labor at the current real wage.[1] This occurs when there is some force that prevents the real wage rate from decreasing to the real wage rate that would equilibrate supply and demand (such as a minimum wage above the market-clearing wage). Structural unemployment is also involuntary.

Economists have several theories explaining the possibility of involuntary unemployment including implicit contract theory, disequilibrium theory, staggered wage setting, and efficiency wages.[1]

The officially measured unemployment rate is the ratio of involuntary unemployment to the sum of involuntary unemployment and employment (the denominator of this ratio being the total labor force).

Explanations edit

 
In the Shapiro-Stiglitz model workers are paid at a level where they do not shirk. This prevents wages from dropping to market clearing levels. Full employment cannot be achieved because workers would slack off if they were not threatened with the possibility of unemployment. The curve for the no-shirking condition (labeled NSC) goes to infinity at full employment.

Models based on implicit contract theory, like that of Costas Azariadis,[2] are based on the hypothesis that labor contracts make it difficult for employers to cut wages. Employers often resort to layoffs rather than implement wage reductions. Azariadis showed that given risk-averse workers and risk-neutral employers, contracts with the possibility of layoff would be the optimal outcome.[3]

Efficiency wage models suggest that employers pay their workers above market-clearing wages in order to enhance their productivity.[1] In efficiency wage models based on shirking, employers are worried that workers may shirk knowing that they can simply move to another job if they are caught. Employers make shirking costly by paying workers more than the wages they would receive elsewhere, incentivising them not to shirk.[1] When all firms behave this way, an equilibrium is reached where there are unemployed workers willing to work at prevailing wages.[4]

 
Chart representing Malinvaud's typology includes a region with Keynesian unemployment, where there is an excess supply of goods and labor, and a region of classical unemployment, where there is an excess supply of labor and excess demand for goods.[5]

Following earlier disequilibrium research including that of Robert Barro and Herschel Grossman, work by Edmond Malinvaud clarified the distinction between classical unemployment, where real wages are too high for markets to clear, and Keynesian unemployment, involuntary unemployment due to inadequate aggregate demand.[1] In Malinvaud's model, classical unemployment is remedied by cutting the real wage while Keynesian unemployment requires an exogenous stimulus in demand.[6] Unlike implicit contrary theory and efficiency wages, this line of research does not rely on a higher than market-clearing wage level. This type of involuntary unemployment is consistent with Keynes' definition while efficiency wages and implicit contract theory do not fit well with Keynes' focus on demand deficiency.[7]

Perspectives edit

For many economists, involuntary unemployment is a real-world phenomenon of central importance to economics. Many economic theories have been motivated by the desire to understand and control involuntary unemployment.[8] However, acceptance of the concept of involuntary unemployment is not universal among economists; some do not accept it as a real or coherent aspect of economic theory.[who?]

Shapiro and Stiglitz, developers of an influential shirking model, stated "To us, involuntary unemployment is a real and important phenomenon with grave social consequences that needs to be explained and understood."[9]

Mancur Olson argued that real world events like the Great Depression could not be understood without the concept of involuntary unemployment. He argued against economists who denied involuntary unemployment and put their theories ahead of "common sense and the observations and experiences of literally hundreds of millions of people... that there is also involuntary unemployment and that it is by no means an isolated or rare phenomenon".[10]

Other economists do not believe that true involuntary unemployment exists[11] or question its relevance to economic theory. Robert Lucas claims "...there is an involuntary element in all unemployment in the sense that no one chooses bad luck over good; there is also a voluntary element in all unemployment, in the sense that, however miserable one's current work options, one can always choose to accept them"[12] and "the unemployed worker at any time can always find some job at once".[12] Lucas dismissed the need for theorists to explain involuntary unemployment since it is "not a fact or a phenomenon which it is the task of theorists to explain. It is, on the contrary, a theoretical construct which Keynes introduced in the hope it would be helpful in discovering a correct explanation for a genuine phenomenon: large-scale fluctuations in measured, total unemployment."[13] Along those lines real business cycle and other models from Lucas's new classical school explain fluctuations in employment by shifts in labor supply driven by changes in workers' productivity and preferences for leisure.[1]

Involuntary unemployment is also conceptually problematic with search and matching theories of unemployment. In these models, unemployment is voluntary in the sense that a worker might choose to endure unemployment during a long search for a higher paying job than those immediately available; however, there is an involuntary element in the sense that a worker does not have control of the economic circumstances that force them to look for new work in the first place.[14]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b c d e f Taylor 2008.
  2. ^ Azariadis 1975.
  3. ^ De Vroey 2002, p. 384.
  4. ^ Shapiro & Stiglitz 1984.
  5. ^ Tsoulfidis 2010, p. 294.
  6. ^ De Vroey 2002, p. 383.
  7. ^ De Vroey 2002, p. 383-385.
  8. ^ McCombie 1987, p. 203.
  9. ^ Shapiro & Stiglitz 1985, p. 1217.
  10. ^ Olson 1982, p. 195.
  11. ^ Mayer 1997, p. 94.
  12. ^ a b Lucas 1978, p. 354.
  13. ^ Lucas 1978, p. 354-355.
  14. ^ Andolfatto 2008.

Sources edit

  • Andolfatto, David (2008), "Search models of unemployment.", in Durlauf, Steven N.; Blume, Lawrence E. (eds.), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (Second ed.), Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 349–355, CiteSeerX 10.1.1.552.4934, doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1497, ISBN 978-0-333-78676-5, retrieved 21 April 2013
  • Azariadis, C. (1975). "Implicit contracts and underemployment equilibria". Journal of Political Economy. 83 (6): 1183–202. doi:10.1086/260388. S2CID 154745887.
  • De Vroey, Michel (2002). "Involuntary unemployment in Keynesian economics". In Snowdon, Brian; Vane, Howard (eds.). An Encyclopedia of Macroeconomics. Northampton, Massachusetts: Edward Elgar Publishing. pp. 381–385. ISBN 978-1-84542-180-9.
  • Lucas, Robert E. (May 1978), "Unemployment policy", American Economic Review, 68 (2): 353–357, JSTOR 1816720
  • Mayer, Thomas (1997), "What Remains of the Monetarist Counter-Revolution?", in Snowdon, Brian; Vane, Howard R. (eds.), Reflections on the Development of Modern Macroeconomics, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 55–102, ISBN 978-1-85898-342-4
  • McCombie, John S. (1987). "Keynes and the Nature of Involuntary Unemployment". Journal of Post Keynesian Economics. 10 (2): 202–215. doi:10.1080/01603477.1987.11489673. JSTOR 4538065.
  • Olson, Mancur (1982). The rise and decline of nations : economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press. ISBN 978-0300030792.
  • Shapiro, C.; Stiglitz, J. E. (1984). "Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device". The American Economic Review. 74 (3): 433–444. JSTOR 1804018.
  • Shapiro, Carl; Stiglitz, Josephy E. (December 1985), "Can Unemployment Be Involuntary? Reply", The American Economic Review, 75 (5): 1215–1217, JSTOR 1818667
  • Taylor, John B. (2008), "Involuntary Unemployment.", in Durlauf, Steven N.; Blume, Lawrence E. (eds.), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (Second ed.), Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 566–570, doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0850, ISBN 978-0-333-78676-5, retrieved 20 April 2013
  • Tsoulfidis, Lefteris (2010). Competing schools of economic thought. London: Springer. ISBN 978-3-540-92692-4.

involuntary, unemployment, occurs, when, person, unemployed, despite, being, willing, work, prevailing, wage, distinguished, from, voluntary, unemployment, where, person, chooses, work, because, their, reservation, wage, higher, than, prevailing, wage, economy. Involuntary unemployment occurs when a person is unemployed despite being willing to work at the prevailing wage It is distinguished from voluntary unemployment where a person chooses not to work because their reservation wage is higher than the prevailing wage In an economy with involuntary unemployment there is a surplus of labor at the current real wage 1 This occurs when there is some force that prevents the real wage rate from decreasing to the real wage rate that would equilibrate supply and demand such as a minimum wage above the market clearing wage Structural unemployment is also involuntary Economists have several theories explaining the possibility of involuntary unemployment including implicit contract theory disequilibrium theory staggered wage setting and efficiency wages 1 The officially measured unemployment rate is the ratio of involuntary unemployment to the sum of involuntary unemployment and employment the denominator of this ratio being the total labor force Contents 1 Explanations 2 Perspectives 3 See also 4 References 5 SourcesExplanations edit nbsp In the Shapiro Stiglitz model workers are paid at a level where they do not shirk This prevents wages from dropping to market clearing levels Full employment cannot be achieved because workers would slack off if they were not threatened with the possibility of unemployment The curve for the no shirking condition labeled NSC goes to infinity at full employment Models based on implicit contract theory like that of Costas Azariadis 2 are based on the hypothesis that labor contracts make it difficult for employers to cut wages Employers often resort to layoffs rather than implement wage reductions Azariadis showed that given risk averse workers and risk neutral employers contracts with the possibility of layoff would be the optimal outcome 3 Efficiency wage models suggest that employers pay their workers above market clearing wages in order to enhance their productivity 1 In efficiency wage models based on shirking employers are worried that workers may shirk knowing that they can simply move to another job if they are caught Employers make shirking costly by paying workers more than the wages they would receive elsewhere incentivising them not to shirk 1 When all firms behave this way an equilibrium is reached where there are unemployed workers willing to work at prevailing wages 4 nbsp Chart representing Malinvaud s typology includes a region with Keynesian unemployment where there is an excess supply of goods and labor and a region of classical unemployment where there is an excess supply of labor and excess demand for goods 5 Following earlier disequilibrium research including that of Robert Barro and Herschel Grossman work by Edmond Malinvaud clarified the distinction between classical unemployment where real wages are too high for markets to clear and Keynesian unemployment involuntary unemployment due to inadequate aggregate demand 1 In Malinvaud s model classical unemployment is remedied by cutting the real wage while Keynesian unemployment requires an exogenous stimulus in demand 6 Unlike implicit contrary theory and efficiency wages this line of research does not rely on a higher than market clearing wage level This type of involuntary unemployment is consistent with Keynes definition while efficiency wages and implicit contract theory do not fit well with Keynes focus on demand deficiency 7 Perspectives editSee also Shapiro Stiglitz theory For many economists involuntary unemployment is a real world phenomenon of central importance to economics Many economic theories have been motivated by the desire to understand and control involuntary unemployment 8 However acceptance of the concept of involuntary unemployment is not universal among economists some do not accept it as a real or coherent aspect of economic theory who Shapiro and Stiglitz developers of an influential shirking model stated To us involuntary unemployment is a real and important phenomenon with grave social consequences that needs to be explained and understood 9 Mancur Olson argued that real world events like the Great Depression could not be understood without the concept of involuntary unemployment He argued against economists who denied involuntary unemployment and put their theories ahead of common sense and the observations and experiences of literally hundreds of millions of people that there is also involuntary unemployment and that it is by no means an isolated or rare phenomenon 10 Other economists do not believe that true involuntary unemployment exists 11 or question its relevance to economic theory Robert Lucas claims there is an involuntary element in all unemployment in the sense that no one chooses bad luck over good there is also a voluntary element in all unemployment in the sense that however miserable one s current work options one can always choose to accept them 12 and the unemployed worker at any time can always find some job at once 12 Lucas dismissed the need for theorists to explain involuntary unemployment since it is not a fact or a phenomenon which it is the task of theorists to explain It is on the contrary a theoretical construct which Keynes introduced in the hope it would be helpful in discovering a correct explanation for a genuine phenomenon large scale fluctuations in measured total unemployment 13 Along those lines real business cycle and other models from Lucas s new classical school explain fluctuations in employment by shifts in labor supply driven by changes in workers productivity and preferences for leisure 1 Involuntary unemployment is also conceptually problematic with search and matching theories of unemployment In these models unemployment is voluntary in the sense that a worker might choose to endure unemployment during a long search for a higher paying job than those immediately available however there is an involuntary element in the sense that a worker does not have control of the economic circumstances that force them to look for new work in the first place 14 See also editIdentity social science Full employment Social rejection Unemployment Job guarantee Social stigma Social stressReferences edit a b c d e f Taylor 2008 Azariadis 1975 De Vroey 2002 p 384 Shapiro amp Stiglitz 1984 Tsoulfidis 2010 p 294 De Vroey 2002 p 383 De Vroey 2002 p 383 385 McCombie 1987 p 203 Shapiro amp Stiglitz 1985 p 1217 Olson 1982 p 195 Mayer 1997 p 94 a b Lucas 1978 p 354 Lucas 1978 p 354 355 Andolfatto 2008 Sources editLibrary resources about Involuntary unemployment Resources in your library Andolfatto David 2008 Search models of unemployment in Durlauf Steven N Blume Lawrence E eds The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics Second ed Palgrave Macmillan pp 349 355 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 552 4934 doi 10 1057 9780230226203 1497 ISBN 978 0 333 78676 5 retrieved 21 April 2013 Azariadis C 1975 Implicit contracts and underemployment equilibria Journal of Political Economy 83 6 1183 202 doi 10 1086 260388 S2CID 154745887 De Vroey Michel 2002 Involuntary unemployment in Keynesian economics In Snowdon Brian Vane Howard eds An Encyclopedia of Macroeconomics Northampton Massachusetts Edward Elgar Publishing pp 381 385 ISBN 978 1 84542 180 9 Lucas Robert E May 1978 Unemployment policy American Economic Review 68 2 353 357 JSTOR 1816720 Mayer Thomas 1997 What Remains of the Monetarist Counter Revolution in Snowdon Brian Vane Howard R eds Reflections on the Development of Modern Macroeconomics Cheltenham UK Edward Elgar Publishing pp 55 102 ISBN 978 1 85898 342 4 McCombie John S 1987 Keynes and the Nature of Involuntary Unemployment Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 10 2 202 215 doi 10 1080 01603477 1987 11489673 JSTOR 4538065 Olson Mancur 1982 The rise and decline of nations economic growth stagflation and social rigidities New Haven Yale University Press ISBN 978 0300030792 Shapiro C Stiglitz J E 1984 Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device The American Economic Review 74 3 433 444 JSTOR 1804018 Shapiro Carl Stiglitz Josephy E December 1985 Can Unemployment Be Involuntary Reply The American Economic Review 75 5 1215 1217 JSTOR 1818667 Taylor John B 2008 Involuntary Unemployment in Durlauf Steven N Blume Lawrence E eds The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics Second ed Palgrave Macmillan pp 566 570 doi 10 1057 9780230226203 0850 ISBN 978 0 333 78676 5 retrieved 20 April 2013 Tsoulfidis Lefteris 2010 Competing schools of economic thought London Springer ISBN 978 3 540 92692 4 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Involuntary unemployment amp oldid 1185318772, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.