fbpx
Wikipedia

Copyright term

The copyright term is the length of time copyright subsists in a work before it passes into the public domain. In most of the world, this length of time is the life of the author plus either 50 or 70 years.

Length of copyright edit

Copyright subsists for a variety of lengths in different jurisdictions. The length of the term can depend on several factors, including the type of work (e.g. musical composition or novel), whether the work has been published or not, and whether the work was created by an individual or a corporation. In most of the world, the default length of copyright is the life of the author plus either 50 or 70 years. In the United States, the term for most existing works is a fixed number of years after the date of creation or publication. In most countries (for example, the United States[1] and the United Kingdom[2]) copyright expires at the end of the calendar year in question.

The length and requirements for copyright duration are subject to change by legislation, and since the early 20th century there have been a number of adjustments made in various countries, which can make determining the copyright duration in a given country difficult. For example, the United States used to require copyrights to be renewed after 28 years to stay in force, and formerly required a copyright notice upon first publication to gain coverage. In Italy and France, there were post-wartime extensions that could increase the term by approximately six years in Italy and up to about 14 in France. Many countries have extended the length of their copyright terms (sometimes retroactively). International treaties, like the Berne Convention, establish minimum terms for copyrights, but these only apply to the signatory countries, and individual countries may grant longer terms than those set out in a treaty.[3]

Implications edit

Copyright term and the public domain edit

The extension of copyright term imposes tangible restrictions on the public domain. For instance, scholar Neil Netanel argued that Copyright Term Extension Act 1998 prevented the entering of works central to cultural heritage of the US into the public domain. He argued, culturally important dissemination, recasting, or incorporation into new expression is prevented due "to the copyright holder's veto". As examples he gave the adaption of the plot from novels such as The Great Gatsby and Peter Pan, the refashion of characters like Mickey Mouse, or the use of Tin Pan Alley songs like "Let's Do It (Let's Fall in Love)" for documentaries about the Great Depression.[4]

Copyright term and orphan works edit

For the millions of older copyrighted works of less enduring popularity, it is difficult, or impossible, to trace the copyright ownership and determine who holds the particular rights that would have to be licensed for the use of the work. The problem of such orphan works stems from the extension of copyright term and the lack of requirement for the copyright owner to renew or register their copyright.[4] In order to tackle this perceived problem some jurisdictions have revised their copyright laws to allow use of orphaned works, after diligent searches.[5]

Reception and discussion edit

Discussions about the optimal length of the copyright term (e.g. regarding the copyright's incentive for creative production[6]) is a significant part of public and scientific discourse and reception.[7][8][9][10][11][12]

One of the earlier and often cited positions is from the British politician Thomas Babington Macaulay who argued in an 1841 speech in the House of Commons that copyright is a monopoly and as such has generally negative effects on society.[13][14] Although Macaulay's speech is widely reported, the reaction to it in the House of Commons is hard to find – Ricketson reports that following Macaulay's claims that the heirs of certain authors would block publication of their works:

At this point, the debate in the House of Commons fell into farce because there were claims by other speakers that they had no doubts (based on their own personal knowledge) that Richardson and Boswell's descendants would still have done the right thing and allowed reprinting, however much they abhorred their ancestors' works![15]

It is also worth noting that Macaulay is arguing here against term extension, he is not arguing against copyright. This point is well made by Macaulay himself:

The advantages arising from a system of copyright are obvious. It is desirable that we should have a supply of good books: we cannot have such a supply unless men of letters are liberally remunerated; and the least objectionable way of remunerating them is by means of copyright.[16]

Liebowitz describes use of the term monopoly in relation to copyright as misleading, but "rhetorically effective";[17] while Towse writes that a more appropriate term is 'monopolistic competition'.[18]

In 2009, a paper by Rufus Pollock of University of Cambridge scientifically quantified the optimal copyright term length at 15 years, significantly shorter than any currently existing copyright term, via an economical model with empirically-estimable parameters.[10][19][20]

In 2013 scholar Petra Moser concluded in a paper on the impact of the copyright extension on the British Copyright Act of 1814 that "longer copyrights raise the costs of accessing intellectual assets for consumers and other firms, which may discourage the diffusion of knowledge and decelerate the pace of cumulative innovation and learning-by-doing."[6]

In 2014 a Rock, Paper, Shotgun article about the existence of orphaned classic video games and the suggestion of letting them enter the public domain after 20 years raised a controversial public debate about copyright terms and the public domain[21][22][23] between game industry veterans John Walker, George Broussard, and Steve Gaynor.[24][25]

A paper published in March 2015 in the Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation analysed with a simulated model the relationship of scientific knowledge creation to copyright term length and concluded a decreased knowledge production on copyright term increases for the analysed context.[7]

As a curiosity, the work Peter Pan, or The Boy Who Wouldn't Grow Up is subject in the UK to a special clause in the Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988[26] that granted Great Ormond Street Hospital a right to royalty in perpetuity. J. M. Barrie had gifted the copyright to the work to the hospital in 1929. The different copyright terms in the various jurisdictions has led to some disputes involving derivative works created and/or sold elsewhere in the world.[27]

Charts edit

Several charts have been made to help decipher the various copyright terms in the United States, such as:

  • Tom W. Bell's Trend of Maximum U.S. General Copyright Term (July 23, 2008)[28]
  • Clorox (diskussion)'s Vectorization of Tom Bell's graph, depicted above, which shows expansion of U.S. copyright law (November 27, 2008)[29]
  • Peter B. Hirtle's Copyright Term and the Public Domain in the United States (2015)[30]
  • Sunstein, Kann, Murphy & Timbers, LLP's Copyright Flowchart (2014)[31]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ 17 U.S.C. § 305
  2. ^ "Amendments of the UK Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988". The Duration of Copyright and Rights in Performances Regulations. 1995.
  3. ^ Nimmer, David (2003). Copyright: Sacred Text, Technology, and the DMCA. Kluwer Law International. p. 63. ISBN 978-90-411-8876-2. OCLC 50606064.
  4. ^ a b Netanel, Neil (2008). Copyright's paradox. Oxford University Press US. p. 200. ISBN 9780195137620.
  5. ^ [1] Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988, s44B
  6. ^ a b Li, Xing; MacGarvie, Megan; Moser, Petra (February 9, 2018). "Dead poets' property: how does copyright influence price?" (PDF). RAND Journal of Economics. 49 (1): 181–205. doi:10.1111/1756-2171.12223.
  7. ^ a b Haydari, Shahram; Smead, Rory (March 31, 2015). "Does Longer Copyright Protection Help or Hurt Scientific Knowledge Creation?". Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation. 18 (2): 23. doi:10.18564/jasss.2720. The prevailing trend in most simulations was that increasing the copyright term resulted decreased knowledge production.
  8. ^ "Copyright and wrong: Why the rules on copyright need to return to their roots". The Economist. April 8, 2010. The notion that lengthening copyright increases creativity is questionable, however. Authors and artists do not generally consult the statute books before deciding whether or not to pick up pen or paintbrush. And overlong copyrights often limit, rather than encourage, a work's dissemination, impact and influence.
  9. ^ Posner, Richard (September 30, 2012). "Do patent and copyright law restrict competition and creativity excessively?". The Becker-Posner Blog. University of Chicago Law School. I am concerned that both patent and copyright protection, though particularly the former, may be excessive.
  10. ^ a b Watt, Richard (September 26, 2014). Handbook on the Economics of Copyright: A Guide for Students and Teachers. Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN 9781849808538. Retrieved January 11, 2015.
  11. ^ Masnick, Mike (February 13, 2013). "New Research: Extending Copyright Massively Increases Prices, Limits Dissemination Of Knowledge". TechDirt.
  12. ^ Matt Asay (February 18, 2013). "John Lennon's lesson for public-domain innovation - IP protection hurting, not helping, US and UK". The Register. Retrieved January 2, 2017. TechDirt highlights research showing that extending copyrights increases prices and limits dissemination of knowledge, while also pointing out that people who believe patents cause innovation are simply confusing correlation with causation. If anything, patents inhibit innovation.
  13. ^ "Opposing Copyright Extension" December 24, 2016, at the Wayback Machine. Extract from Macaulay, Thomas Babington (1967). Young, G. M. (ed.). Prose and Poetry. Harvard University Press.
  14. ^ Boyle, James (July 24, 2014). "Macaulay on Copyright" (blog). The Public Domain.
  15. ^ Ricketson, Sam (1992). "The copyright term". International Review of Intellectual Property and Competition Law. Springer (753): 767.
  16. ^ Macaulay, Thomas Babington (1860). Speeches of Lord Macaulay. Longman, Green, Longman and Roberts. p. 232.
  17. ^ Liebowitz, Stan (2015). "A critique of copyright criticism". George Mason Law Review. 22:4:943: 958.
  18. ^ Towse, Ruth (1999). "Copyright, risk and the artist: an economic approach to policy for artists". International Journal of Cultural Policy. 6:1:91: 105 (note 9).
  19. ^ Pollock, Rufus (October 1, 2007). (PDF). University of Cambridge. Archived from the original (PDF) on February 21, 2013. Retrieved January 11, 2015. The optimal level for copyright has been a matter for extensive debate over the last decade. Using a parsimonious theoretical model this paper contributes several new results of relevance to this debate. In particular we demonstrate that (a) optimal copyright is likely to fall as the production costs of 'originals' decline (for example as a result of digitization) (b) technological change which reduces costs of production may imply a decrease or a decrease in optimal levels of protection (this contrasts with a large number of commentators, particularly in the copyright industries, who have argued that such change necessitates increases in protection) (c) the optimal level of copyright will, in general, fall over time as the stock of work increases.
  20. ^ Pollock, Rufus (June 15, 2009). (PDF). University of Cambridge. Archived from the original (PDF) on January 12, 2013. Retrieved January 11, 2015. The optimal term of copyright has been a matter for extensive debate over the last decade. Based on a novel approach we derive an explicit formula which characterises the optimal term as a function of a few key and, most importantly, empirically-estimable parameters. Using existing data on recordings and books we obtain a point estimate of around 15 years for optimal copyright term with a 99% confidence interval extending up to 38 years. This is substantially shorter than any current copyright term and implies that existing terms are too long.
  21. ^ Walker, John (January 29, 2014). "GOG's Time Machine Sale Lets You CONTROL TIME ITSELF". Rock, Paper, Shotgun. Retrieved January 30, 2016. As someone who desperately pines for the PD model that drove creativity before the copyright industry malevolently took over the planet, it saddens my heart that a game two decades old isn't released into the world.
  22. ^ Walker, John (February 3, 2014). "Editorial: Why Games Should Enter The Public Domain". Rock, Paper, Shotgun. Retrieved January 30, 2016. ... games more than a couple of decades old aren't entering the public domain. Twenty years was a fairly arbitrary number, one that seems to make sense in the context of games' lives, but it could be twenty-five, thirty.
  23. ^ Robotron23 (February 4, 2014). "Why Games Should Be In the Public Domain". Slashdot.
  24. ^ Broussard, George [@georgeb3dr] (January 29, 2014). "@wickerwaka The whole thing, really. But especially that. Whoever allowed that to be printed should be fired" (Tweet). Retrieved January 7, 2019 – via Twitter. (referring to the Rock, Paper, Shotgun article, particularly its first sentence)
  25. ^ Gaynor, Steve (February 3, 2014). "Copyright, trademark & money in a creative industry". Gamasutra. There is some argument going on about for how long a copyright holder should be able to charge exclusively for their own work, before it enters the public domain. John Walker argues that perhaps a good cutoff would be 20 years before an 'idea' enters the public domain.
  26. ^ "Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988: Section 301: Schedule 6", legislation.gov.uk, The National Archives, 1988 c. 48 (s. 301)(sch. 6)
  27. ^ . Stanford Center for Internet and Society. Archived from the original on October 27, 2006. Retrieved May 8, 2010.
  28. ^ Bell, Tom W. (July 23, 2008). "Copyright Term Chart: Trend of Maximum U.S. General Copyright Term". TomWBell.com.
  29. ^ Clorox (diskussion) & Bell, Tom. W. (November 27, 2008). Vectorization of Tom Bell's graph, which shows expansion of U.S. copyright law.
  30. ^ Hirtle, Peter B. (January 1, 2015). . Cornell.edu. Archived from the original on February 26, 2015.
  31. ^ Sunstein, Kann, Murphy & Timbers LLP (2014). "Copyright Flowchart: Flowchart for determining when U.S. copyrights in fixed works expire". WINNING INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY®.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)

copyright, term, copyright, term, length, time, copyright, subsists, work, before, passes, into, public, domain, most, world, this, length, time, life, author, plus, either, years, contents, length, copyright, implications, public, domain, orphan, works, recep. The copyright term is the length of time copyright subsists in a work before it passes into the public domain In most of the world this length of time is the life of the author plus either 50 or 70 years Contents 1 Length of copyright 2 Implications 2 1 Copyright term and the public domain 2 2 Copyright term and orphan works 3 Reception and discussion 4 Charts 5 See also 6 ReferencesLength of copyright editCopyright subsists for a variety of lengths in different jurisdictions The length of the term can depend on several factors including the type of work e g musical composition or novel whether the work has been published or not and whether the work was created by an individual or a corporation In most of the world the default length of copyright is the life of the author plus either 50 or 70 years In the United States the term for most existing works is a fixed number of years after the date of creation or publication In most countries for example the United States 1 and the United Kingdom 2 copyright expires at the end of the calendar year in question The length and requirements for copyright duration are subject to change by legislation and since the early 20th century there have been a number of adjustments made in various countries which can make determining the copyright duration in a given country difficult For example the United States used to require copyrights to be renewed after 28 years to stay in force and formerly required a copyright notice upon first publication to gain coverage In Italy and France there were post wartime extensions that could increase the term by approximately six years in Italy and up to about 14 in France Many countries have extended the length of their copyright terms sometimes retroactively International treaties like the Berne Convention establish minimum terms for copyrights but these only apply to the signatory countries and individual countries may grant longer terms than those set out in a treaty 3 Implications editCopyright term and the public domain edit The extension of copyright term imposes tangible restrictions on the public domain For instance scholar Neil Netanel argued that Copyright Term Extension Act 1998 prevented the entering of works central to cultural heritage of the US into the public domain He argued culturally important dissemination recasting or incorporation into new expression is prevented due to the copyright holder s veto As examples he gave the adaption of the plot from novels such as The Great Gatsby and Peter Pan the refashion of characters like Mickey Mouse or the use of Tin Pan Alley songs like Let s Do It Let s Fall in Love for documentaries about the Great Depression 4 Copyright term and orphan works edit For the millions of older copyrighted works of less enduring popularity it is difficult or impossible to trace the copyright ownership and determine who holds the particular rights that would have to be licensed for the use of the work The problem of such orphan works stems from the extension of copyright term and the lack of requirement for the copyright owner to renew or register their copyright 4 In order to tackle this perceived problem some jurisdictions have revised their copyright laws to allow use of orphaned works after diligent searches 5 Reception and discussion editDiscussions about the optimal length of the copyright term e g regarding the copyright s incentive for creative production 6 is a significant part of public and scientific discourse and reception 7 8 9 10 11 12 One of the earlier and often cited positions is from the British politician Thomas Babington Macaulay who argued in an 1841 speech in the House of Commons that copyright is a monopoly and as such has generally negative effects on society 13 14 Although Macaulay s speech is widely reported the reaction to it in the House of Commons is hard to find Ricketson reports that following Macaulay s claims that the heirs of certain authors would block publication of their works At this point the debate in the House of Commons fell into farce because there were claims by other speakers that they had no doubts based on their own personal knowledge that Richardson and Boswell s descendants would still have done the right thing and allowed reprinting however much they abhorred their ancestors works 15 It is also worth noting that Macaulay is arguing here against term extension he is not arguing against copyright This point is well made by Macaulay himself The advantages arising from a system of copyright are obvious It is desirable that we should have a supply of good books we cannot have such a supply unless men of letters are liberally remunerated and the least objectionable way of remunerating them is by means of copyright 16 Liebowitz describes use of the term monopoly in relation to copyright as misleading but rhetorically effective 17 while Towse writes that a more appropriate term is monopolistic competition 18 In 2009 a paper by Rufus Pollock of University of Cambridge scientifically quantified the optimal copyright term length at 15 years significantly shorter than any currently existing copyright term via an economical model with empirically estimable parameters 10 19 20 In 2013 scholar Petra Moser concluded in a paper on the impact of the copyright extension on the British Copyright Act of 1814 that longer copyrights raise the costs of accessing intellectual assets for consumers and other firms which may discourage the diffusion of knowledge and decelerate the pace of cumulative innovation and learning by doing 6 In 2014 a Rock Paper Shotgun article about the existence of orphaned classic video games and the suggestion of letting them enter the public domain after 20 years raised a controversial public debate about copyright terms and the public domain 21 22 23 between game industry veterans John Walker George Broussard and Steve Gaynor 24 25 A paper published in March 2015 in the Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation analysed with a simulated model the relationship of scientific knowledge creation to copyright term length and concluded a decreased knowledge production on copyright term increases for the analysed context 7 As a curiosity the work Peter Pan or The Boy Who Wouldn t Grow Up is subject in the UK to a special clause in the Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988 26 that granted Great Ormond Street Hospital a right to royalty in perpetuity J M Barrie had gifted the copyright to the work to the hospital in 1929 The different copyright terms in the various jurisdictions has led to some disputes involving derivative works created and or sold elsewhere in the world 27 Charts editSeveral charts have been made to help decipher the various copyright terms in the United States such as Tom W Bell s Trend of Maximum U S General Copyright Term July 23 2008 28 Clorox diskussion s Vectorization of Tom Bell s graph depicted above which shows expansion of U S copyright law November 27 2008 29 Peter B Hirtle s Copyright Term and the Public Domain in the United States 2015 30 Sunstein Kann Murphy amp Timbers LLP s Copyright Flowchart 2014 31 See also editHistory of copyright law List of countries copyright length Perpetual copyright Rule of the shorter term Copyright Term Extension ActReferences edit 17 U S C 305 Amendments of the UK Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988 The Duration of Copyright and Rights in Performances Regulations 1995 Nimmer David 2003 Copyright Sacred Text Technology and the DMCA Kluwer Law International p 63 ISBN 978 90 411 8876 2 OCLC 50606064 a b Netanel Neil 2008 Copyright s paradox Oxford University Press US p 200 ISBN 9780195137620 1 Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988 s44B a b Li Xing MacGarvie Megan Moser Petra February 9 2018 Dead poets property how does copyright influence price PDF RAND Journal of Economics 49 1 181 205 doi 10 1111 1756 2171 12223 a b Haydari Shahram Smead Rory March 31 2015 Does Longer Copyright Protection Help or Hurt Scientific Knowledge Creation Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 18 2 23 doi 10 18564 jasss 2720 The prevailing trend in most simulations was that increasing the copyright term resulted decreased knowledge production Copyright and wrong Why the rules on copyright need to return to their roots The Economist April 8 2010 The notion that lengthening copyright increases creativity is questionable however Authors and artists do not generally consult the statute books before deciding whether or not to pick up pen or paintbrush And overlong copyrights often limit rather than encourage a work s dissemination impact and influence Posner Richard September 30 2012 Do patent and copyright law restrict competition and creativity excessively The Becker Posner Blog University of Chicago Law School I am concerned that both patent and copyright protection though particularly the former may be excessive a b Watt Richard September 26 2014 Handbook on the Economics of Copyright A Guide for Students and Teachers Edward Elgar Publishing ISBN 9781849808538 Retrieved January 11 2015 Masnick Mike February 13 2013 New Research Extending Copyright Massively Increases Prices Limits Dissemination Of Knowledge TechDirt Matt Asay February 18 2013 John Lennon s lesson for public domain innovation IP protection hurting not helping US and UK The Register Retrieved January 2 2017 TechDirt highlights research showing that extending copyrights increases prices and limits dissemination of knowledge while also pointing out that people who believe patents cause innovation are simply confusing correlation with causation If anything patents inhibit innovation Opposing Copyright Extension Archived December 24 2016 at the Wayback Machine Extract from Macaulay Thomas Babington 1967 Young G M ed Prose and Poetry Harvard University Press Boyle James July 24 2014 Macaulay on Copyright blog The Public Domain Ricketson Sam 1992 The copyright term International Review of Intellectual Property and Competition Law Springer 753 767 Macaulay Thomas Babington 1860 Speeches of Lord Macaulay Longman Green Longman and Roberts p 232 Liebowitz Stan 2015 A critique of copyright criticism George Mason Law Review 22 4 943 958 Towse Ruth 1999 Copyright risk and the artist an economic approach to policy for artists International Journal of Cultural Policy 6 1 91 105 note 9 Pollock Rufus October 1 2007 Optimal Copyright over Time Technological Change and the Stock of Works PDF University of Cambridge Archived from the original PDF on February 21 2013 Retrieved January 11 2015 The optimal level for copyright has been a matter for extensive debate over the last decade Using a parsimonious theoretical model this paper contributes several new results of relevance to this debate In particular we demonstrate that a optimal copyright is likely to fall as the production costs of originals decline for example as a result of digitization b technological change which reduces costs of production may imply a decrease or a decrease in optimal levels of protection this contrasts with a large number of commentators particularly in the copyright industries who have argued that such change necessitates increases in protection c the optimal level of copyright will in general fall over time as the stock of work increases Pollock Rufus June 15 2009 Forever minus a day Calculating optimal copyright term PDF University of Cambridge Archived from the original PDF on January 12 2013 Retrieved January 11 2015 The optimal term of copyright has been a matter for extensive debate over the last decade Based on a novel approach we derive an explicit formula which characterises the optimal term as a function of a few key and most importantly empirically estimable parameters Using existing data on recordings and books we obtain a point estimate of around 15 years for optimal copyright term with a 99 confidence interval extending up to 38 years This is substantially shorter than any current copyright term and implies that existing terms are too long Walker John January 29 2014 GOG s Time Machine Sale Lets You CONTROL TIME ITSELF Rock Paper Shotgun Retrieved January 30 2016 As someone who desperately pines for the PD model that drove creativity before the copyright industry malevolently took over the planet it saddens my heart that a game two decades old isn t released into the world Walker John February 3 2014 Editorial Why Games Should Enter The Public Domain Rock Paper Shotgun Retrieved January 30 2016 games more than a couple of decades old aren t entering the public domain Twenty years was a fairly arbitrary number one that seems to make sense in the context of games lives but it could be twenty five thirty Robotron23 February 4 2014 Why Games Should Be In the Public Domain Slashdot Broussard George georgeb3dr January 29 2014 wickerwaka The whole thing really But especially that Whoever allowed that to be printed should be fired Tweet Retrieved January 7 2019 via Twitter referring to the Rock Paper Shotgun article particularly its first sentence Gaynor Steve February 3 2014 Copyright trademark amp money in a creative industry Gamasutra There is some argument going on about for how long a copyright holder should be able to charge exclusively for their own work before it enters the public domain John Walker argues that perhaps a good cutoff would be 20 years before an idea enters the public domain Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988 Section 301 Schedule 6 legislation gov uk The National Archives 1988 c 48 s 301 sch 6 Emily Somma v GOSH Peter Pan case Case Page Stanford Center for Internet and Society Archived from the original on October 27 2006 Retrieved May 8 2010 Bell Tom W July 23 2008 Copyright Term Chart Trend of Maximum U S General Copyright Term TomWBell com Clorox diskussion amp Bell Tom W November 27 2008 Vectorization of Tom Bell s graph which shows expansion of U S copyright law Hirtle Peter B January 1 2015 Copyright Term and the Public Domain in the United States Cornell edu Archived from the original on February 26 2015 Sunstein Kann Murphy amp Timbers LLP 2014 Copyright Flowchart Flowchart for determining when U S copyrights in fixed works expire WINNING INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Copyright term amp oldid 1165892144, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.